메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 117, Issue 1, 2007, Pages 3-68

Contracting for cooperation in recovery

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 36249017253     PISSN: 00440094     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/20455783     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (11)

References (264)
  • 1
    • 36248963996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 507 S.E.2d 344, 347 (Va. 1998). In addition to the false certificates of compliance, Richmond claimed constructive fraud based on McDevitt's decision to seal the ends of the tubes with grout, giving the false impression that they had been filled. The Virginia Supreme Court held that these allegations were nothing more than allegations of negligent performance of contractual duties, and therefore nonactionable as constructive fraud. Id.
    • 507 S.E.2d 344, 347 (Va. 1998). In addition to the false certificates of compliance, Richmond claimed constructive fraud based on McDevitt's decision to seal the ends of the tubes with grout, giving the false impression that they had been filled. The Virginia Supreme Court held that these allegations were "nothing more than allegations of negligent performance of contractual duties," and therefore nonactionable as constructive fraud. Id.
  • 2
    • 36248983607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There may be other harms as well, such as making recovery more expensive. I consider the effectiveness of compensatory damages for these harms in infra Subsection I.B.2.
    • There may be other harms as well, such as making recovery more expensive. I consider the effectiveness of compensatory damages for these harms in infra Subsection I.B.2.
  • 3
    • 36248961516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is a very thin concept of cooperation. My technical use of the term is obviously different from more demanding or normatively laden concepts of cooperation. See, e.g, Michael E. Bratman, Shared Cooperative Activity, in FACES OF INTENTION: SELECTED ESSAYS ON INTENTION AND AGENCY 93, 103-05 1999
    • This is a very thin concept of cooperation. My technical use of the term is obviously different from more demanding or normatively laden concepts of cooperation. See, e.g., Michael E. Bratman, Shared Cooperative Activity, in FACES OF INTENTION: SELECTED ESSAYS ON INTENTION AND AGENCY 93, 103-05 (1999).
  • 4
    • 33845369004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The received wisdom should no longer be that compensatory damage measures are the only efficient remedies. See Richard RW. Brooks, The Efficient Performance Hypothesis, 116
    • The received wisdom should no longer be that compensatory damage measures are the only efficient remedies. See Richard RW. Brooks, The Efficient Performance Hypothesis, 116 YALE L.J. 568 (2006);
    • (2006) YALE L.J , vol.568
  • 5
    • 36249007341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE LJ. 271 (1979).
    • Alan Schwartz, The Case for Specific Performance, 89 YALE LJ. 271 (1979).
  • 6
    • 36249000492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Special transactional situations where the received wisdom does not apply are collected in Aaron S. Edlin & Alan Schwartz, Optimal Penalties in Contracts, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 33 (2003).
    • Special transactional situations where the received wisdom does not apply are collected in Aaron S. Edlin & Alan Schwartz, Optimal Penalties in Contracts, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 33 (2003).
  • 7
    • 36249026917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most significant recent decision is the Delaware Chancery Court's holding in ABRY Partners V, L.P. v. F&W Acquisition L.L.C. that when a seller intentionally misrepresents a fact embodied in a contract-that is, when a seller lies-public policy will not permit a contractual provision to limit the remedy of the buyer to a capped damage claim. 891 A.2d 1032, 1036 (Del. Ch. 2006);
    • The most significant recent decision is the Delaware Chancery Court's holding in ABRY Partners V, L.P. v. F&W Acquisition L.L.C. that "when a seller intentionally misrepresents a fact embodied in a contract-that is, when a seller lies-public policy will not permit a contractual provision to limit the remedy of the buyer to a capped damage claim." 891 A.2d 1032, 1036 (Del. Ch. 2006);
  • 9
    • 70350449490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Licensing Lies: Merger Clauses, the Parol Evidence Rule and Pre-Contractual Misrepresentations, 33
    • For recent scholarly discussions, see
    • For recent scholarly discussions, see Kevin Davis, Licensing Lies: Merger Clauses, the Parol Evidence Rule and Pre-Contractual Misrepresentations, 33 VAL. U. L. REV. 485 (1999) ;
    • (1999) VAL. U. L. REV , vol.485
    • Davis, K.1
  • 10
    • 36248948947 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Of Fine Lines, Blunt Instruments, and Half-Truths: Business Acquisition Agreements and the Right To Lie, 32 DEL. J. CORP. L
    • forthcoming
    • and Jeffrey M. Lipshaw, Of Fine Lines, Blunt Instruments, and Half-Truths: Business Acquisition Agreements and the Right To Lie, 32 DEL. J. CORP. L. (forthcoming 2007).
    • (2007)
    • Lipshaw, J.M.1
  • 12
    • 32544460867 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design, 115
    • Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Anticipating Litigation in Contract Design, 115 YALE L.J. 814, 857 (2006).
    • (2006) YALE L.J , vol.814 , pp. 857
    • Scott, R.E.1    Triantis, G.G.2
  • 13
    • 36248939064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an example of the neglect in a famous source, see L.L. Fuller & William R. Perdue, Jr., The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages (pt. 1), 46 YALE L.J. 52, 58 (1936) (If a contract represents a kind of private law, it is a law which usually says nothing at all about what shall be done when it is violated. A contract is in this respect like an imperfect statute which provides no penalties, and which leaves it to the courts to find a way to effectuate its purposes.).
    • For an example of the neglect in a famous source, see L.L. Fuller & William R. Perdue, Jr., The Reliance Interest in Contract Damages (pt. 1), 46 YALE L.J. 52, 58 (1936) ("If a contract represents a kind of private law, it is a law which usually says nothing at all about what shall be done when it is violated. A contract is in this respect like an imperfect statute which provides no penalties, and which leaves it to the courts to find a way to effectuate its purposes.").
  • 14
    • 33646586704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The conclusions of this Article are consistent with results in other areas of the law. See, e.g., Alex Raskolnikov, Crime and Punishment in Taxation: Deceit, Deterrence, and the SelfAdjusting Penalty, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 569 (2006) (analyzing sanctions for tax evasion and avoidance);
    • The conclusions of this Article are consistent with results in other areas of the law. See, e.g., Alex Raskolnikov, Crime and Punishment in Taxation: Deceit, Deterrence, and the SelfAdjusting Penalty, 106 COLUM. L. REV. 569 (2006) (analyzing sanctions for tax evasion and avoidance);
  • 15
    • 36248940111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ian C. Wiener, Note, Running Rampant: The Imposition of Sanctions and the Use of Force Against Fleeing Criminal Suspects, 80 GEO. L.J. 2175 (1992) (discussing optimal penalties for criminal flight).
    • Ian C. Wiener, Note, Running Rampant: The Imposition of Sanctions and the Use of Force Against Fleeing Criminal Suspects, 80 GEO. L.J. 2175 (1992) (discussing optimal penalties for criminal flight).
  • 16
    • 33846600262 scopus 로고
    • The Path of the Law, 10
    • Oliver Wendell Holmes, The Path of the Law, 10 HARV. L. REV. 457, 462 (1897),
    • (1897) HARV. L. REV , vol.457 , pp. 462
    • Wendell Holmes, O.1
  • 17
    • 36249005358 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • reprinted in 110 HARV. L. REV. 991, 995 (1997).
    • reprinted in 110 HARV. L. REV. 991, 995 (1997).
  • 18
    • 36248957987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., RICHARD POSNER, LAW, PRAGMATISM, AND DEMOCRACY 58 (2003) (Holmes pointed out that in a regime in which the sanction for breach of contract is merely an award of compensatory damages to the victim, the entire practical effect of signing a contract is that by doing so one obtains an option to break it.);
    • See, e.g., RICHARD POSNER, LAW, PRAGMATISM, AND DEMOCRACY 58 (2003) ("Holmes pointed out that in a regime in which the sanction for breach of contract is merely an award of compensatory damages to the victim, the entire practical effect of signing a contract is that by doing so one obtains an option to break it.");
  • 19
    • 12344329377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Avery Wiener Katz, The Option Element in Contraaing, 90 VA. L. REV. 2187, 2202 (2004) (In option terminology, we can restate Holmes's point by saying that the promisor holds a call option to buy her way out of the contract by paying a strike price equal to the value of court-awarded damages.);
    • Avery Wiener Katz, The Option Element in Contraaing, 90 VA. L. REV. 2187, 2202 (2004) ("In option terminology, we can restate Holmes's point by saying that the promisor holds a call option to buy her way out of the contract by paying a strike price equal to the value of court-awarded damages.");
  • 20
    • 8744279274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Embedded Options and the Case Against Compensation in Contract Law, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 1428, 1429 n.1 (2004) (It is well known that contract damages effectively give the promisor an option between performing the promise or breaching and paying damages. The classic statement is by Justice Holmes___);
    • Robert E. Scott & George G. Triantis, Embedded Options and the Case Against Compensation in Contract Law, 104 COLUM. L. REV. 1428, 1429 n.1 (2004) ("It is well known that contract damages effectively give the promisor an option between performing the promise or breaching and paying damages. The classic statement is by Justice Holmes___");
  • 21
    • 33846833905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Seanna Valentine Shiffrin, The Divergence of Contract and Promise, 120 HARV. L. REV. 708, 727 (2007) (Justice Holmes famously declared that a contract to perform should be understood not as a promise to perform full stop, but as a promise either to perform or to pay damages.).
    • Seanna Valentine Shiffrin, The Divergence of Contract and Promise, 120 HARV. L. REV. 708, 727 (2007) ("Justice Holmes famously declared that a contract to perform should be understood not as a promise to perform full stop, but as a promise either to perform or to pay damages.").
  • 22
    • 36248984984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • OLIVER W. HOLMES, THE COMMON LAW 302 (Boston, Little, Brown & Co. 1944) (1881) ;
    • OLIVER W. HOLMES, THE COMMON LAW 302 (Boston, Little, Brown & Co. 1944) (1881) ;
  • 23
    • 0034421255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Misreading Oliver Wendell Holmes on Efficient Breach and Tortious Interference, 68
    • see also
    • see also Joseph M. Perillo, Misreading Oliver Wendell Holmes on Efficient Breach and Tortious Interference, 68 FORDHAM L. REV. 1085, 1085-93 (2000).
    • (2000) FORDHAM L. REV , vol.1085 , pp. 1085-1093
    • Perillo, J.M.1
  • 24
    • 36248966368 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 686 P.2d 1158, 1166 (Cal. 1984), overruled by Freeman & Mills, Inc. v. Belcher Oil Co., 900 P.2d 669 (Cal. 199s).
    • 686 P.2d 1158, 1166 (Cal. 1984), overruled by Freeman & Mills, Inc. v. Belcher Oil Co., 900 P.2d 669 (Cal. 199s).
  • 26
    • 36248971547 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jules L. Coleman, Douglas D. Heckathorn & Steven M. Maser, A Bargaining Theory Approach to Default Provisions and Disclosure Rules in Contract Law, 12 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 639 (1989).
    • Jules L. Coleman, Douglas D. Heckathorn & Steven M. Maser, A Bargaining Theory Approach to Default Provisions and Disclosure Rules in Contract Law, 12 HARV. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 639 (1989).
  • 27
    • 36249025167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a description of the way that trust can play a role in assuring cooperation in recovery, see ANNETTE C. BAIER, Trust and Its Vulnerabilities, in MORAL PREJUDICES: ESSAYS ON ETHICS 130, 138-39 (1994).
    • For a description of the way that trust can play a role in assuring cooperation in recovery, see ANNETTE C. BAIER, Trust and Its Vulnerabilities, in MORAL PREJUDICES: ESSAYS ON ETHICS 130, 138-39 (1994).
  • 28
    • 0347722896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Verification Institutions in Financial Transactions, 87
    • For a helpful overview of such mechanisms, albeit with an emphasis more on securing ex ante reliability rather than ex post compensation, see
    • For a helpful overview of such mechanisms, albeit with an emphasis more on securing ex ante reliability rather than ex post compensation, see Ronald J. Mann, Verification Institutions in Financial Transactions, 87 GEO. L.J. 2225 (1999).
    • (1999) GEO. L.J , vol.2225
    • Mann, R.J.1
  • 29
    • 36248992243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the parties' ability to modify discovery procedures, see FED. R CIV. P. 29. For the possible use of alternative burdens of proof, see Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 856-78
    • For the parties' ability to modify discovery procedures, see FED. R CIV. P. 29. For the possible use of alternative burdens of proof, see Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 856-78.
  • 30
    • 36248972119 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AYRES & KLASS, supra note 6, at 165-68. This statement must be qualified by the alreadynoted reluctance of some courts to permit actions for fraud in the contractual setting. See infra Section III.B.
    • AYRES & KLASS, supra note 6, at 165-68. This statement must be qualified by the alreadynoted reluctance of some courts to permit actions for fraud in the contractual setting. See infra Section III.B.
  • 31
    • 36248966103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FED. R. CIV. P. 11(b)(1);
    • FED. R. CIV. P. 11(b)(1);
  • 32
    • 84858463896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see, e.g., CAL. CIV. PROC. CODE § 128.7 (West 2006);
    • see, e.g., CAL. CIV. PROC. CODE § 128.7 (West 2006);
  • 33
    • 36249007841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • III. SUP. CT. R. 137;
    • III. SUP. CT. R. 137;
  • 34
    • 36248963483 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • N.J. CT. R. 1:4-8 (West 2007);
    • N.J. CT. R. 1:4-8 (West 2007);
  • 35
    • 36248929237 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • TEX. R. CIV. PROC. ANN. 13 (Vernon 2003).
    • TEX. R. CIV. PROC. ANN. 13 (Vernon 2003).
  • 36
    • 33750506264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Chris William Sanchirico, Detection Avoidance, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1331, 1384-86 (2006) (observing the limited scope of criminal and procedural sanctions for detection avoidance).
    • But see Chris William Sanchirico, Detection Avoidance, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1331, 1384-86 (2006) (observing the limited scope of criminal and procedural sanctions for detection avoidance).
  • 37
    • 36248953611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A rule can be said to be quasi-mandatory when the parties have a limited ability to modify it, though not to contract out of it entirely. Thus Rule 29 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure and many state analogs allow the parties to stipulate to discovery procedures, though such stipulations are subject to court review to ensure no undue frustration of the administration of justice. See, e.g., Franklin v. White, 493 N.E.2d 161 (Ind. 1986); Garden State Plaza Corp. v. S.S. Kresge Co., 189 A.2d 448 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1963).
    • A rule can be said to be "quasi-mandatory" when the parties have a limited ability to modify it, though not to contract out of it entirely. Thus Rule 29 of the Federal Rules of Civil Procedure and many state analogs allow the parties to stipulate to discovery procedures, though such stipulations are subject to court review to ensure no undue frustration of the administration of justice. See, e.g., Franklin v. White, 493 N.E.2d 161 (Ind. 1986); Garden State Plaza Corp. v. S.S. Kresge Co., 189 A.2d 448 (N.J. Super. Ct. App. Div. 1963).
  • 38
    • 36249024069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There is an analog to promisor duties to cooperate in recovery: promisee duties not to falsely allege breach. Many of the arguments below would apply equally to such duties, though I do not consider them as such
    • There is an analog to promisor duties to cooperate in recovery: promisee duties not to falsely allege breach. Many of the arguments below would apply equally to such duties, though I do not consider them as such.
  • 39
    • 36248960423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Examples of noninfbrmational duties to cooperate include requirements that the promisor keep funds available to pay any first-order damage award, that the promisor remain within the reach of a jurisdiction, or that the promisor voluntarily pay damages for clear breach. Many of my conclusions apply to these duties as well, though the details of the argument and the remedies required are different. For example, as Richard Craswell pointed out to me, a contractual liquidity requirement might be most effective if its breach triggered accelerated first-order remedies, such as the rfght to demand adequate assurance
    • Examples of noninfbrmational duties to cooperate include requirements that the promisor keep funds available to pay any first-order damage award, that the promisor remain within the reach of a jurisdiction, or that the promisor voluntarily pay damages for clear breach. Many of my conclusions apply to these duties as well, though the details of the argument and the remedies required are different. For example, as Richard Craswell pointed out to me, a contractual liquidity requirement might be most effective if its breach triggered accelerated first-order remedies, such as the rfght to demand adequate assurance.
  • 40
    • 36249013075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I follow here the convention of using observability to refer to the parties' ability to detect some fact, and verifiability to refer to the ease with which that fact can be demonstrated in court
    • I follow here the convention of using "observability" to refer to the parties' ability to detect some fact, and "verifiability" to refer to the ease with which that fact can be demonstrated in court.
  • 41
    • 36248942387 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Exxon Corp. v. Dep't of Conservation & Natural Res., 859 So. 2d 1096 (Ala. 2002); Post-Judgment Order, Alabama v. Exxon Corp., No. 99-2368 (Ala. Cir. Ct. Mar. 29, 2004).
    • See Exxon Corp. v. Dep't of Conservation & Natural Res., 859 So. 2d 1096 (Ala. 2002); Post-Judgment Order, Alabama v. Exxon Corp., No. 99-2368 (Ala. Cir. Ct. Mar. 29, 2004).
  • 42
    • 36248976953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 859 So. 2d at 1100; Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 9
    • 859 So. 2d at 1100; Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 9.
  • 43
    • 36248983050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 21, 52-54.
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 21, 52-54.
  • 44
    • 36248954345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 19-22
    • Id. at 19-22.
  • 45
    • 36248940109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 21
    • Id. at 21.
  • 46
    • 36248939588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 21-22
    • Id. at 21-22.
  • 47
    • 36248938154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 20
    • Id. at 20.
  • 48
    • 84858463886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 21 (citations omitted, A similar description of the same dynamic can be found in the legislative history of a California bill that would have penalized recording companies for underpaying and misreporting royalties. The bill's sponsor, Senator Murray, explained: [T]his bill addresses the core issue that has allowed record companies to under-report royalty earnings without any penalty___ Under the current structure, there is no disincentive or penalty if record companies do not properly account royalties to artists; therefore, bad behavior is rewarded. Cal. Assem. Comm. on Arts, Entertainment, Sports, Tourism, and Internet Media, Bill Analysis, S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg, Reg. Sess, at 1-2 Cal. 2003, as amended May 12, 2003, statement of Sen. Murray, available at http
    • Id. at 21 (citations omitted). A similar description of the same dynamic can be found in the legislative history of a California bill that would have penalized recording companies for underpaying and misreporting royalties. The bill's sponsor, Senator Murray, explained: "[T]his bill addresses the core issue that has allowed record companies to under-report royalty earnings without any penalty___ Under the current structure, there is no disincentive or penalty if record companies do not properly account royalties to artists; therefore, bad behavior is rewarded." Cal. Assem. Comm. on Arts, Entertainment, Sports, Tourism, and Internet Media, Bill Analysis, S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg., Reg. Sess., at 1-2 (Cal. 2003) (as amended May 12, 2003) (statement of Sen. Murray), available at http:// info.sen.ca.gov/pub/03- 04/bill/sen/sb_1001-1050/sb_1034_cfa_20030630_102556_asm_comm.html.
  • 49
    • 36248946562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 32; see also Reis v. Peabody Coal Co., 997 S.W.2d 49, 68, 72 (Mo. Ct. App. 1999) (rejecting the fraud defendant's argument that the plaintiff incurred no actual damages because plaintiff had already recovered for breach of the royalty contract in arbitration).
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 32; see also Reis v. Peabody Coal Co., 997 S.W.2d 49, 68, 72 (Mo. Ct. App. 1999) (rejecting the fraud defendant's argument that the plaintiff incurred no actual damages because plaintiff had already recovered for breach of the royalty contract in arbitration).
  • 50
    • 36248944930 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 19-37, 62.
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 19-37, 62.
  • 51
    • 36249031800 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exxon Corp. v. Dep't of Conservation & Natural Res., No. 1031167 (Ala. filed Apr. 30, 2004).
    • Exxon Corp. v. Dep't of Conservation & Natural Res., No. 1031167 (Ala. filed Apr. 30, 2004).
  • 52
    • 84858464144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 350 cmt. b (1981).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 350 cmt. b (1981).
  • 53
    • 36248937036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Discouraging frivolous lawsuits is but one of the claimed advantages of fee shifting. See, e.g., W. Kent Davis, The International View of Attorney Fees in Civil Suits: Why Is the United States the Odd Man Out in How It Pays Its Lawyers?, 16 ARIZ. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 361, 399-430 (1999) (arguing that fee shifting can reduce the number of lawsuits and ensure access to litigation);
    • Discouraging frivolous lawsuits is but one of the claimed advantages of fee shifting. See, e.g., W. Kent Davis, The International View of Attorney Fees in Civil Suits: Why Is the United States the "Odd Man Out" in How It Pays Its Lawyers?, 16 ARIZ. J. INT'L & COMP. L. 361, 399-430 (1999) (arguing that fee shifting can reduce the number of lawsuits and ensure access to litigation);
  • 54
    • 0038938445 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amy Farmer & Paul Pecorino, A Reputation for Being a Nuisance: Frivolous Lawsuits and Fee Shifting in a Repeated Play Game, 18 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 147 (1998) (finding that fee shifting can reduce frivolous litigation costs, where lawyer reputation is relevant) ;
    • Amy Farmer & Paul Pecorino, A Reputation for Being a Nuisance: Frivolous Lawsuits and Fee Shifting in a Repeated Play Game, 18 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 147 (1998) (finding that fee shifting can reduce frivolous litigation costs, where lawyer reputation is relevant) ;
  • 55
    • 36249003254 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James W. Hughes & Edward A Snyder, Litigation and Settlement Under the English and American Rules: Theory and Evidence, 38 J.L. & ECON. 225 (1995) (finding that efficient settlement, costs, and successful plaintiff suits are more common under the English rule);
    • James W. Hughes & Edward A Snyder, Litigation and Settlement Under the English and American Rules: Theory and Evidence, 38 J.L. & ECON. 225 (1995) (finding that efficient settlement, costs, and successful plaintiff suits are more common under the English rule);
  • 56
    • 36249016699 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Walter Olson & David Bernstein, Loser-Pays: Where Next?, 55 MD. L. REV. 1161, 1161-63 (1996) (arguing that fee shifting can diminish speculative lawsuits, can decrease litigation costs, and is more fair) ;
    • Walter Olson & David Bernstein, Loser-Pays: Where Next?, 55 MD. L. REV. 1161, 1161-63 (1996) (arguing that fee shifting can diminish speculative lawsuits, can decrease litigation costs, and is more fair) ;
  • 57
    • 36248937601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John F. Vargo, The American Rule on Attorney Fee Albcation: The Injured Person's Access to Justice, 42 AM.U.L.REV. 1567, 1590-93 (1993) (describing common arguments against the American rule).
    • John F. Vargo, The American Rule on Attorney Fee Albcation: The Injured Person's Access to Justice, 42 AM.U.L.REV. 1567, 1590-93 (1993) (describing common arguments against the American rule).
  • 58
    • 36248958576 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The plausibility of recovery of attorney fees for obstructive breach is demonstrated by some contemporary reactions to California's experiment with punitive damages for obstruction of recovery in Seaman's Direct Buying Service, Inc. v. Standard Oil Co, 686 P. 2d 1158 Cal. 1984
    • The plausibility of recovery of attorney fees for obstructive breach is demonstrated by some contemporary reactions to California's experiment with punitive damages for obstruction of recovery in Seaman's Direct Buying Service, Inc. v. Standard Oil Co., 686 P. 2d 1158 (Cal. 1984).
  • 59
    • 84858458819 scopus 로고
    • Commercial Bad Faith: Attorney Fees-Not Tort Liability-Is the Remedy for "Stonewalling, " 21
    • See
    • See C. Delos Putz, Jr., & Nona Klippen, Commercial Bad Faith: Attorney Fees-Not Tort Liability-Is the Remedy for "Stonewalling, " 21 U.S.F. L. REV. 419, 499 (1987);
    • (1987) U.S.F. L. REV , vol.419 , pp. 499
    • Delos Putz Jr., C.1    Klippen, N.2
  • 60
    • 36248974562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dana Rae Landsdorf, Note, California's Detortification of Contract Law: Is the Seaman's Tort Dead?, 26 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 213, 238 (1992) (Contracting parties who deny-in bad faidi-the existence of a contract should be liable for all damages proximately caused and resulting from such conduct. For example, the breaching party should not only be liable for compensatory damages but also for the injured party's attorney's fees because the nonbreaching party does not expect to incur attorney's fees from the transaction.).
    • Dana Rae Landsdorf, Note, California's Detortification of Contract Law: Is the Seaman's Tort Dead?, 26 LOY. L.A. L. REV. 213, 238 (1992) ("Contracting parties who deny-in bad faidi-the existence of a contract should be liable for all damages proximately caused and resulting from such conduct. For example, the breaching party should not only be liable for compensatory damages but also for the injured party's attorney's fees because the nonbreaching party does not expect to incur attorney's fees from the transaction.").
  • 61
    • 36249014688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It might be thought that no court would award litigation costs without proof of first-order breach, the idea being that such recovery would give promisees a perverse incentive to sue. That thought overlooks the fact that compensatory litigation-cost damages for breach of an anti-obstruction clause should be limited to costs attributable to the defendant's obstructive behavior. Litigation-cost recovery for breach of the recordkeeping clause would not give Developer a free suit on the first-order breach. It would, however, support her expenditure of extra resources to determine whether there was a first-order breach- expenses that would be unnecessary but for Contractor's failure to keep the required records. Developer should be permitted to recover these costs whether or not she sues for the underlying breach, and if she does sue on the underlying breach, whether or not she prevails in that suit
    • It might be thought that no court would award litigation costs without proof of first-order breach, the idea being that such recovery would give promisees a perverse incentive to sue. That thought overlooks the fact that compensatory litigation-cost damages for breach of an anti-obstruction clause should be limited to costs attributable to the defendant's obstructive behavior. Litigation-cost recovery for breach of the recordkeeping clause would not give Developer a free suit on the first-order breach. It would, however, support her expenditure of extra resources to determine whether there was a first-order breach- expenses that would be unnecessary but for Contractor's failure to keep the required records. Developer should be permitted to recover these costs whether or not she sues for the underlying breach, and if she does sue on the underlying breach, whether or not she prevails in that suit.
  • 62
    • 84886342665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying note 29
    • See supra text accompanying note 29.
    • See supra
  • 63
    • 84858470607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356(1) (2006).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356(1) (2006).
  • 64
    • 84858470608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • $1,000 = (.1)($10,000).
    • $1,000 = (.1)($10,000).
  • 65
    • 84858463888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • $5,000 = (.5)($10,000).
    • $5,000 = (.5)($10,000).
  • 66
    • 84858464140 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356 cmt. b (2006);
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356 cmt. b (2006);
  • 67
    • 84858464142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CONTRACTS § 12.18, at 814-15 (4th ed. 2004).
    • see E. ALLAN FARNSWORTH, CONTRACTS § 12.18, at 814-15 (4th ed. 2004).
  • 68
    • 84858464139 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356 illus. 4 (2006);
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356 illus. 4 (2006);
  • 69
    • 84858463882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also id. § 356(1) (Damages for breach by either party may be liquidated in the agreement but only at an amount that is reasonable in the light of the anticipated or actual loss caused by the breach and the difficulties of proof of loss. (emphasis added)).
    • see also id. § 356(1) ("Damages for breach by either party may be liquidated in the agreement but only at an amount that is reasonable in the light of the anticipated or actual loss caused by the breach and the difficulties of proof of loss." (emphasis added)).
  • 70
    • 84858470604 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 24 WILLISTON ON CONTRACTS § 65:33 (4th ed. 2006).
    • 24 WILLISTON ON CONTRACTS § 65:33 (4th ed. 2006).
  • 71
    • 84858461995 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Specific performance also qualifies as extracompensatory under my definition, but timing issues prevent it from being effective against most sorts of obstruction. An injunction ordering subsequent performance cannot undo the damage caused by destroyed records, hidden or unreported first-order nonperformance, delay tactics, and most other forms of obstruction. One exception is contractual duties to permit audits. Thus 10 U.S.C. § 2313 (2000, which gives the Department of Defense the right to audit records of certain contractors, also gives it the power, enforceable by the district court, to subpoena those records. This is equivalent to a mandatory audit term supported by specific performance. California has recently legislated mandatory auditing rights in recording contracts, though without specifying the remedy for their breach. CAL. CIV. CODE § 2501 West Supp. 2007, At some point the California courts will have to decide what the appropriate rem
    • Specific performance also qualifies as extracompensatory under my definition, but timing issues prevent it from being effective against most sorts of obstruction. An injunction ordering subsequent performance cannot undo the damage caused by destroyed records, hidden or unreported first-order nonperformance, delay tactics, and most other forms of obstruction. One exception is contractual duties to permit audits. Thus 10 U.S.C. § 2313 (2000), which gives the Department of Defense the right to audit records of certain contractors, also gives it the power, enforceable by the district court, to subpoena those records. This is equivalent to a mandatory audit term supported by specific performance. California has recently legislated mandatory auditing rights in recording contracts, though without specifying the remedy for their breach. CAL. CIV. CODE § 2501 (West Supp. 2007). At some point the California courts will have to decide what the appropriate remedy is. My analysis suggests that it should be specific performance, an adverseiference, or some other extracompensatory measure.
  • 72
    • 0031512311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yet other remedial options are available where the promisor is a corporate entity and liability for first-order and obstructive breaches (or rewards for cooperation) can be assigned separately to the corporation and its agents. See Jennifer Arlen & Reinier Kraakman, Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 687 1997
    • Yet other remedial options are available where the promisor is a corporate entity and liability for first-order and obstructive breaches (or rewards for cooperation) can be assigned separately to the corporation and its agents. See Jennifer Arlen & Reinier Kraakman, Controlling Corporate Misconduct: An Analysis of Corporate Liability Regimes, 72 N.Y.U. L. REV. 687 (1997).
  • 73
    • 84976131981 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Such a solution is comparable to putting enforcement in the hands of a third party, note 14
    • Such a solution is comparable to putting enforcement in the hands of a third party. See supra text accompanying note 14.
    • See supra text accompanying
  • 74
    • 84858463881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I will follow Farnsworth and use terminate (where one could also say rescind or cancel) to refer to the nonbreaching party's right to end the contract. See FARNSWORTH, supra note 41, § 8.15 n.2.
    • I will follow Farnsworth and use "terminate" (where one could also say "rescind" or "cancel") to refer to the nonbreaching party's right to end the contract. See FARNSWORTH, supra note 41, § 8.15 n.2.
  • 75
    • 36248962026 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to California Senator Murray, a former entertainment lawyer, even though the obligation to accurately account for royalty earnings is a material part of the contract, most if not all recording artist contracts provide that a breach of the obligation to account for or pay royalties is not a material breach, leaving the artist with no real recourse except to setde the claim on perhaps a percentage of what is owed or else conduct protracted and expensive litigation at the possible expense of the artist's career. Cal. Assem. Comm. on Arts, Entertainment, Sports, Tourism, and Internet Media, Bill Analysis, S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg, Reg. Sess, at 1-2 Cal. 2003, third reading, paraphrasing Sen. Murray, available at http://info.sen.ca.gov/ pub/03-04/bilVsen/sb_1001-1050/sb_1034_cfa_20030514_100846_sen_floor.htm l
    • According to California Senator Murray, a former entertainment lawyer, even though the obligation to accurately account for royalty earnings is a material part of the contract, most if not all recording artist contracts provide that a breach of the obligation to account for or pay royalties is not a material breach, leaving the artist with no real recourse except to setde the claim on perhaps a percentage of what is owed or else conduct protracted and expensive litigation at the possible expense of the artist's career. Cal. Assem. Comm. on Arts, Entertainment, Sports, Tourism, and Internet Media, Bill Analysis, S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg., Reg. Sess., at 1-2 (Cal. 2003) (third reading) (paraphrasing Sen. Murray), available at http://info.sen.ca.gov/ pub/03-04/bilVsen/sb_1001-1050/sb_1034_cfa_20030514_100846_sen_floor.html.
  • 76
    • 36249017760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the power of labels to dictate terms, and how this plays out in terms of artists' ability to get accurate accountings or otherwise monitor label performance, see Wendy V. Bartholomew, Fiduciary Duty: Can It Help Calm the Fears of Underpaid Artists?, 6 VAND. J. ENT. L. & PRAC. 246 (2004);
    • For the power of labels to dictate terms, and how this plays out in terms of artists' ability to get accurate accountings or otherwise monitor label performance, see Wendy V. Bartholomew, Fiduciary Duty: Can It Help Calm the Fears of Underpaid Artists?, 6 VAND. J. ENT. L. & PRAC. 246 (2004);
  • 77
    • 36248980784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Corrina Cree Clover, Note, Accounting Accountability: Should Record Labels Have a Fiduciary Duty To Report Accurate Royalties to Recording Artists?, 23 LOY. LJL ENT. L. REV. 395 (2003).
    • and Corrina Cree Clover, Note, Accounting Accountability: Should Record Labels Have a Fiduciary Duty To Report Accurate Royalties to Recording Artists?, 23 LOY. LJL ENT. L. REV. 395 (2003).
  • 78
    • 39349094243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 41, § 8.16
    • FARNSWORTH, supra note 41, § 8.16.
    • supra
    • FARNSWORTH1
  • 79
    • 85050789971 scopus 로고
    • Property Rules and Liability Rules in Unconscionability and Related Doctrines, 60
    • Richard Craswell, Property Rules and Liability Rules in Unconscionability and Related Doctrines, 60 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 7 (1993).
    • (1993) U. CHI. L. REV , vol.1 , pp. 7
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 80
    • 36249031423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 7-8 (emphasis omitted).
    • Id. at 7-8 (emphasis omitted).
  • 81
    • 36249019671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a description of how courts and prosecutors use adverse inferences to discourage obstruction in the aiminal context, see Sanchirico, supra note 17, at 1378-82
    • For a description of how courts and prosecutors use adverse inferences to discourage obstruction in the aiminal context, see Sanchirico, supra note 17, at 1378-82.
  • 82
    • 36249028017 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 857-58 footnote omitted
    • Scott & Triantis, supra note 7, at 857-58 (footnote omitted).
  • 84
    • 36249011273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus Scott and Triantis identify only three ways by which the parties might clarify, reverse, or fine-tune the default allocation in their contract, The first approach is by direct allocation of burden; the second is by predesignating whom the plaintiff will be in the event of a dispute; and the third is by framing the substantive provisions governing, for example, the right to assign or terminate a contract. Id. at 866. I am suggesting a fourth: rather than direct allocation of the burden, conditional allocation. Scott and Triantis do describe an instance in which the court determined that a prima facie showing of bad faith shifted the burden of proof-though not at the behest of the contract. Id. at 876-77 (discussing Int'l Harvester Co. v. Calvin, 353 So. 2d 144 Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1977
    • Thus Scott and Triantis identify only three ways by which the parties might clarify, reverse, or fine-tune the default allocation in their contract.... The first approach is by direct allocation of burden; the second is by predesignating whom the plaintiff will be in the event of a dispute; and the third is by framing the substantive provisions governing, for example, the right to assign or terminate a contract. Id. at 866. I am suggesting a fourth: rather than direct allocation of the burden, conditional allocation. Scott and Triantis do describe an instance in which the court determined that a prima facie showing of bad faith shifted the burden of proof-though not at the behest of the contract. Id. at 876-77 (discussing Int'l Harvester Co. v. Calvin, 353 So. 2d 144 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 1977)).
  • 85
    • 84858470598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally 29 AM. JUR. 2D Evidence § 244 (1944 & Supp. 2006). The evidentiary rule requires proof of scienter: a conscious awareness of the existence of the dispute and that the act done will destroy evidence or access to evidence. Id. This is interesting in light of my argument in Sections III.B and IVA that scienter requirements add value to no-obstruct duties.
    • See generally 29 AM. JUR. 2D Evidence § 244 (1944 & Supp. 2006). The evidentiary rule requires proof of scienter: "a conscious awareness of the existence of the dispute and that the act done will destroy evidence or access to evidence." Id. This is interesting in light of my argument in Sections III.B and IVA that scienter requirements add value to no-obstruct duties.
  • 86
    • 0347031888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Punitive Damages and the Economic Theory of Penalties, 87
    • See, e.g
    • See, e.g., Keith N. Hylton, Punitive Damages and the Economic Theory of Penalties, 87 GEO. L.J. 421, 425-39 (1998).
    • (1998) GEO. L.J , vol.421 , pp. 425-439
    • Hylton, K.N.1
  • 87
    • 84858464137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ($10,000)(.5) = $5,000.
    • ($10,000)(.5) = $5,000.
  • 88
    • 84858470599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ($5,000)/(.2) = $25,000.
    • ($5,000)/(.2) = $25,000.
  • 89
    • 84858464138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In many jurisdictions, punitive damages may only be awarded where there is proof of actual loss. See 25 C.J.S. Damages § 197 (2002) (As a general rule, in order to recover exemplary or punitive damages, actual damages must be shown, or there must be a basis for the recovery of compensatory damages. (footnote omitted)); 1 JOHN J. KIRCHER & CHRISTINE M. WISEMAN, PUNITIVE DAMAGES: LAW AND PRACTICE § 5:21 (2d ed. Supp. 2003) (Abundant authority exists to support the proposition that a finding must be entered entitling the plaintiff to actual damages before that plaintiff will be allowed to recover punitive damages.). This rule is open to criticism.
    • In many jurisdictions, punitive damages may only be awarded where there is proof of actual loss. See 25 C.J.S. Damages § 197 (2002) ("As a general rule, in order to recover exemplary or punitive damages, actual damages must be shown, or there must be a basis for the recovery of compensatory damages." (footnote omitted)); 1 JOHN J. KIRCHER & CHRISTINE M. WISEMAN, PUNITIVE DAMAGES: LAW AND PRACTICE § 5:21 (2d ed. Supp. 2003) ("Abundant authority exists to support the proposition that a finding must be entered entitling the plaintiff to actual damages before that plaintiff will be allowed to recover punitive damages."). This rule is open to criticism.
  • 90
    • 84858461990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 908 cmt. c (1979) (Although ... the extent of the harm may be considered in determining their amount, it is not essential to the recovery of punitive damages that the plaintiff should have suffered any harm, either pecuniary or physical.);
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 908 cmt. c (1979) ("Although ... the extent of the harm may be considered in determining their amount, it is not essential to the recovery of punitive damages that the plaintiff should have suffered any harm, either pecuniary or physical.");
  • 91
    • 36248966362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jane Mallor & Barry Roberts, Punitive Damages: Toward a Principled Approach, 31 HASTINGS L.J. 639, 666-67 (1980) (arguing against the rule that punitive damages bear a reasonable relationship to actual harm). In jurisdictions that follow the first rule, the secondary harms of obstructive breach might satisfy the actual harm requirement. And the punitive damages in cases where there is proof of harm can be further increased to take account of the ex ante possibility that such proof was not going to be available.
    • Jane Mallor & Barry Roberts, Punitive Damages: Toward a Principled Approach, 31 HASTINGS L.J. 639, 666-67 (1980) (arguing against the rule that punitive damages bear a reasonable relationship to actual harm). In jurisdictions that follow the first rule, the secondary harms of obstructive breach might satisfy the actual harm requirement. And the punitive damages in cases where there is proof of harm can be further increased to take account of the ex ante possibility that such proof was not going to be available.
  • 92
    • 36248983046 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS S 355 (1981). For developments in the law of punitive damages for breach of contract, see William S. Dodge, The Case for Punitive Damages in Contracts, 48 DUKE L.J. 629, 636-51 (1999).
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS S 355 (1981). For developments in the law of punitive damages for breach of contract, see William S. Dodge, The Case for Punitive Damages in Contracts, 48 DUKE L.J. 629, 636-51 (1999).
  • 93
    • 84858461992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356(1) (1981). For descriptions of practical complexities and differences between jurisdictions, see Kenneth W. Clarkson, Roger LeRoy Miller & Timothy J. Muris, Liquidated Damages v. Penalties: Sense or Nonsense?, 1978 WIS. L. REV- 351) 352-57;
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 356(1) (1981). For descriptions of practical complexities and differences between jurisdictions, see Kenneth W. Clarkson, Roger LeRoy Miller & Timothy J. Muris, Liquidated Damages v. Penalties: Sense or Nonsense?, 1978 WIS. L. REV- 351) 352-57;
  • 94
    • 36248958574 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ian R. Macneil, Power of Contract and Agreed Remedies, 47 CORNELL L-Q. 495, 501-13 (1962);
    • Ian R. Macneil, Power of Contract and Agreed Remedies, 47 CORNELL L-Q. 495, 501-13 (1962);
  • 95
    • 36248937033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Eric L. Talley, Note, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195, 1200-05 (1994).
    • and Eric L. Talley, Note, Contract Renegotiation, Mechanism Design, and the Liquidated Damages Rule, 46 STAN. L. REV. 1195, 1200-05 (1994).
  • 96
    • 36248983043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Not all states follow these rules. South Carolina, for example, permits punitive damages for breach of contract accompanied by any act characterized by dishonesty in fact, unfair dealing, or the unlawful appropriation of another's property by design, a rule that might well cover many forms of obstructive behavior. Perry v. Green, 437 S.E.2d 150, 152 (S.C. Ct. App. 1993); see also Dodge, supra note 59, at 649-50 (describing similar rules in Idaho, Mississippi, and New Mexico). It is unclear whether the courts in these states treat such punitive damages as mandatory remedies or as defaults the parties could opt out of, much less whether courts would permit the parties to specify the bad acts that should trigger them.
    • Not all states follow these rules. South Carolina, for example, permits punitive damages for breach of contract accompanied by "any act characterized by dishonesty in fact, unfair dealing, or the unlawful appropriation of another's property by design," a rule that might well cover many forms of obstructive behavior. Perry v. Green, 437 S.E.2d 150, 152 (S.C. Ct. App. 1993); see also Dodge, supra note 59, at 649-50 (describing similar rules in Idaho, Mississippi, and New Mexico). It is unclear whether the courts in these states treat such punitive damages as mandatory remedies or as defaults the parties could opt out of, much less whether courts would permit the parties to specify the bad acts that should trigger them.
  • 97
    • 84888467546 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • text accompanying notes 123-128
    • See infra text accompanying notes 123-128.
    • See infra
  • 98
    • 36249018266 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The argument from freedom of contract is suggested by Daniel Friedmann in The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 23 (1989). Samuel Rea describes the difficulty the choice metric poses for economic explanations of the rule against penalties: The perplexing aspea of the penalties-liquidated damages distinction is that there is a conflict between the apparent, but express, intention of the parties and the subsequent action of the courts. Economists are inclined to believe that courts are contributing to inefficiency when they upset the agreed upon terms of a contract.
    • The argument from freedom of contract is suggested by Daniel Friedmann in The Efficient Breach Fallacy, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 1, 23 (1989). Samuel Rea describes the difficulty the choice metric poses for economic explanations of the rule against penalties: The perplexing aspea of the penalties-liquidated damages distinction is that there is a conflict between the apparent, but express, intention of the parties and the subsequent action of the courts. Economists are inclined to believe that courts are contributing to inefficiency when they upset the agreed upon terms of a contract.
  • 99
    • 36249032397 scopus 로고
    • Efficiency Implications of Penalties and Liquidated Damages, 13
    • Samuel A Rea, Jr., Efficiency Implications of Penalties and Liquidated Damages, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 147, 148 (1984);
    • (1984) J. LEGAL STUD , vol.147 , pp. 148
    • Rea Jr., S.A.1
  • 100
    • 36248996288 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Lake River Corp. v. Carborundum Co., 769 F.2d 1284, 1289 (7th Cir. 1985) (Posner, J.) ([T]he parties (always assuming they are fully competent) will, in deciding whether to include a penalty clause in their contract, weigh the gains against the costs... and will include the clause only if the benefits exceed those costs....);
    • see also Lake River Corp. v. Carborundum Co., 769 F.2d 1284, 1289 (7th Cir. 1985) (Posner, J.) ("[T]he parties (always assuming they are fully competent) will, in deciding whether to include a penalty clause in their contract, weigh the gains against the costs... and will include the clause only if the benefits exceed those costs....");
  • 101
    • 36248930864 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just Compensation Principle: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient Breach, 77 COLUM. L. REV. 554, 555 n.12 (1977) (describing how the penalty doctrine is anomalous in terms of the theoretical underpinnings of modern contract law).
    • Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Liquidated Damages, Penalties and the Just Compensation Principle: Some Notes on an Enforcement Model and a Theory of Efficient Breach, 77 COLUM. L. REV. 554, 555 n.12 (1977) (describing how the penalty doctrine is "anomalous in terms of the theoretical underpinnings of modern contract law").
  • 102
    • 36248954874 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thus Alan Schwartz argues, Courts do not have to prevent promisees from obtaining penalty clauses if promisees do not want penalty clauses. The ex ante rule is not merely unnecessary: judicial review produces mischief. Courts sometimes mistake compensatory damage measures for penalties, and so have found that particular liquidated damage clauses would inevitably overcompensate promisees when those clauses only protected the expectation. Thus, the ex ante branch of the liquidated damage rule should be abandoned
    • Thus Alan Schwartz argues : Courts do not have to prevent promisees from obtaining penalty clauses if promisees do not want penalty clauses. The ex ante rule is not merely unnecessary: judicial review produces mischief. Courts sometimes mistake compensatory damage measures for penalties, and so have found that particular liquidated damage clauses would inevitably overcompensate promisees when those clauses only protected the expectation. Thus, the ex ante branch of the liquidated damage rule should be abandoned.
  • 103
    • 36248979045 scopus 로고
    • The Myth That Promisees Prefer Supercompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100
    • Alan Schwartz, The Myth That Promisees Prefer Supercompensatory Remedies: An Analysis of Contracting for Damage Measures, 100 YALE L.J. 369, 370 (1990) ;
    • (1990) YALE L.J , vol.369 , pp. 370
    • Schwartz, A.1
  • 104
    • 36248950561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 578-93 (arguing that many penalty clauses are designed to compensate for damages or create efficient incentives that remain inscrutable to courts);
    • see also Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 578-93 (arguing that many penalty clauses are designed to compensate for damages or create efficient incentives that remain inscrutable to courts);
  • 105
    • 36248950563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra, at
    • Schwartz, supra, at 383-87.
    • Schwartz1
  • 106
    • 36248976436 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These developments are described in Edlin & Schwartz, supra note 4, at 43-52
    • These developments are described in Edlin & Schwartz, supra note 4, at 43-52.
  • 107
    • 36248937032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 554
    • See Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 554.
  • 108
    • 36248988380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Klinger v. Adams County Sch. Dist. No. 50, 130 P.3d 1027, 1034 (Colo. 2006, A] contract provision for liquidated damages is invalid as a penalty if it is unreasonably large for the expected loss from a breach of contract, Bragdon v. Twenty-Five Twelve Assoes. P'ship, 856 A.2d 1165, 1173 (D.C. 2004, Punitive damages will not lie for breach of contract, even if it is proven that the breach was willful, wanton, or malicious, Dist. Cablevision P'ship v. Bassin, 828 A.2d 714, 724 (D.C. 2003, Agreements to pay fixed sums plainly without reasonable relation to any probable damage which may follow a breach will not be enforced, TAL Fin. Corp. v. CSC Consulting, Inc, 844 N.E.2d 1085, 1093 (Mass. 2006, L] iquidated damages will not be enforced if the sum is 'grossly disproportionate to a reasonable estimate of actual damages' made at the time of contract formation, quoting Kelley v. Marx, 705 N.B. 2d 1114, 1116 Ma
    • See, e.g., Klinger v. Adams County Sch. Dist. No. 50, 130 P.3d 1027, 1034 (Colo. 2006) ("[A] contract provision for liquidated damages is invalid as a penalty if it is unreasonably large for the expected loss from a breach of contract.") ; Bragdon v. Twenty-Five Twelve Assoes. P'ship, 856 A.2d 1165, 1173 (D.C. 2004) ("Punitive damages will not lie for breach of contract, even if it is proven that the breach was willful, wanton, or malicious."); Dist. Cablevision P'ship v. Bassin, 828 A.2d 714, 724 (D.C. 2003) ("Agreements to pay fixed sums plainly without reasonable relation to any probable damage which may follow a breach will not be enforced."); TAL Fin. Corp. v. CSC Consulting, Inc., 844 N.E.2d 1085, 1093 (Mass. 2006) (" [L] iquidated damages will not be enforced if the sum is 'grossly disproportionate to a reasonable estimate of actual damages' made at the time of contract formation." (quoting Kelley v. Marx, 705 N.B. 2d 1114, 1116 (Mass. 1999)); Ins. Co. of the W. v. Gibson Tile Co., 134 P.3d 698, 703 (Nev. 2006) ("[T]he award of punitive damages cannot be based upon a cause of action sounding solely in contract."); Smith v. Grand Canyon Expeditions Co., 84 P.3d 1154, 1161 (Utah 2003) ("[P]unitive damages are recoverable only for torts, not for breach of contract.").
  • 109
    • 36248999297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AYRES &KLASS, supra note 6.
    • AYRES &KLASS, supra note 6.
  • 110
    • 36248977478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 5
    • See supra note 5.
  • 111
    • 36248987113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The three techniques I discuss are not the only ones available. Recording artists have tried and generally failed to impose on recording companies a fiduciary duty to account for royalty payments. See S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg., Reg. Sess. (Cal. 2003). Like fraud, breach of fiduciary duty can permit the recovery of punitive damages, effectively deterring obstructive behavior. A downside of fiduciary duties as compared to fraud liability is their lack of specificity. Rather than the relatively clear duty to be honest, there is a relatively amorphous duty of loyalty. See Deborah A. DeMott, Breach of Fiduciary Duty: On Justifiable Expectations of Loyalty and Their Consequences, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 925, 934-40 (2006);
    • The three techniques I discuss are not the only ones available. Recording artists have tried and generally failed to impose on recording companies a fiduciary duty to account for royalty payments. See S. 1034, 2002-2003 Leg., Reg. Sess. (Cal. 2003). Like fraud, breach of fiduciary duty can permit the recovery of punitive damages, effectively deterring obstructive behavior. A downside of fiduciary duties as compared to fraud liability is their lack of specificity. Rather than the relatively clear duty to be honest, there is a relatively amorphous duty of loyalty. See Deborah A. DeMott, Breach of Fiduciary Duty: On Justifiable Expectations of Loyalty and Their Consequences, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 925, 934-40 (2006);
  • 112
    • 0036814631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Critical Resource Theory of Fiduciary Duty, 55
    • D. Gordon Smith, The Critical Resource Theory of Fiduciary Duty, 55 VAND. L. REV. 1399, 1406-11 (2002).
    • (2002) VAND. L. REV , vol.1399 , pp. 1406-1411
    • Gordon Smith, D.1
  • 113
    • 36248943420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 686 P.2d 1158, 1167 (Cal. 1984).
    • 686 P.2d 1158, 1167 (Cal. 1984).
  • 114
    • 36248969120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id
    • Id.
  • 115
    • 36248984173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For surveys of the variety of lower-court interpretations of Seaman's, see, for example, Freeman & Mills, Inc. v. Belcher Oil Co., 900 Pad 669 (Cal. 1995);
    • For surveys of the variety of lower-court interpretations of Seaman's, see, for example, Freeman & Mills, Inc. v. Belcher Oil Co., 900 Pad 669 (Cal. 1995);
  • 116
    • 36248950560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Landsdorf, supra note 35, at 222-35
    • Landsdorf, supra note 35, at 222-35.
  • 117
    • 36249026110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The furthest extension of Seaman's by the lower courts appears to have been in Koehrer v. Superior Court, 226 Cal. Rptr. 820 (Ct. App. 1986), which extend[ed] Seaman's to bad faith attempt to deprive employee of contractual benefits. Freeman & Mills, 900 P.2d at 675.
    • The furthest extension of Seaman's by the lower courts appears to have been in Koehrer v. Superior Court, 226 Cal. Rptr. 820 (Ct. App. 1986), which "extend[ed] Seaman's to bad faith attempt to deprive employee of contractual benefits." Freeman & Mills, 900 P.2d at 675.
  • 118
    • 36249004234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Freeman & Mills, 900 P.2d at 676-77. Dodge argues that the real turning point was as early as 1988, when the California Supreme Court declined to extend Seaman's to employment contracts. Dodge, supra note 59, at 642 (discussing Foley v. Interactive Data Corp., 765 P.2d 373 (Cal. 1988)).
    • Freeman & Mills, 900 P.2d at 676-77. Dodge argues that the real turning point was as early as 1988, when the California Supreme Court declined to extend Seaman's to employment contracts. Dodge, supra note 59, at 642 (discussing Foley v. Interactive Data Corp., 765 P.2d 373 (Cal. 1988)).
  • 119
    • 36249028013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 686 P.2d at 1167; id. at 1174 (Bird, C.J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
    • 686 P.2d at 1167; id. at 1174 (Bird, C.J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
  • 120
    • 36249005345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Dodge, supra note 59, at 638 n.33;
    • See, e.g., Dodge, supra note 59, at 638 n.33;
  • 121
    • 36248930863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E. Allan Farnsworth, Developments in Contract Law During the 1980's: The Top Ten, 41 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 203, 205 (1990);
    • E. Allan Farnsworth, Developments in Contract Law During the 1980's: The Top Ten, 41 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 203, 205 (1990);
  • 122
    • 36249013070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Friedmann, supra note 63, at 19 n.62;
    • Friedmann, supra note 63, at 19 n.62;
  • 123
    • 0037228670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Curtis Bridgeman, Note, Corrective Justice in Contract Law: Is There a Case for Punitive Damages?, 56 VAND. L. REV. 237, 270-71 (2003).
    • Curtis Bridgeman, Note, Corrective Justice in Contract Law: Is There a Case for Punitive Damages?, 56 VAND. L. REV. 237, 270-71 (2003).
  • 124
    • 36249020242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Shiffrin, supra note 10, at 723 n.27 (recognizing the limited scope of Seaman's).
    • But see Shiffrin, supra note 10, at 723 n.27 (recognizing the limited scope of Seaman's).
  • 126
    • 36248960419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Old Am., Inc. v. Microtech Int'l, Inc., 872 F.2d 312, 314-15 (9th Cir. 1989) (Kozinski, J., concurring).
    • Old Am., Inc. v. Microtech Int'l, Inc., 872 F.2d 312, 314-15 (9th Cir. 1989) (Kozinski, J., concurring).
  • 127
    • 36248937030 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 686 P.2d at 1167
    • 686 P.2d at 1167.
  • 128
    • 36249005859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Michael Dorff is therefore wrong when, criticizing the application of punitive damages in Seaman's, he states that the consequences of denying the contract's existence would be virtually identical to the consequences of any other complete contract breach, and the parties would be expected to negotiate about the risks of a complete breach. Michael Dorff, Attaching Tort Claims to Contract Actions: An Economic Analysu of Contort, 28 SETON HALL L. REV. 390, 423 (1997).
    • Michael Dorff is therefore wrong when, criticizing the application of punitive damages in Seaman's, he states that "the consequences of denying the contract's existence would be virtually identical to the consequences of any other complete contract breach, and the parties would be expected to negotiate about the risks of a complete breach." Michael Dorff, Attaching Tort Claims to Contract Actions: An Economic Analysu of Contort, 28 SETON HALL L. REV. 390, 423 (1997).
  • 129
    • 36249011272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oki Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring).
    • Oki Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring).
  • 130
    • 36249007321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 73. Kozinski correcdy diagnosed this problem : [Seaman's] created a cause of action so nebulous in oudine and so unpredictable in application that it more resembles a brick thrown from a third story window than a rule of law. Seaman's gives nary a hint as to how to distinguish a bad faith denial that a contract exists, from a dispute over contract terms, from a permissible attempt to rescind a contract, or from a loosely worded disclaimer of continued contractual responsibility.
    • See supra note 73. Kozinski correcdy diagnosed this problem : [Seaman's] created a cause of action so nebulous in oudine and so unpredictable in application that it more resembles a brick thrown from a third story window than a rule of law. Seaman's gives nary a hint as to how to distinguish a bad faith denial that a contract exists, from a dispute over contract terms, from a permissible attempt to rescind a contract, or from a loosely worded disclaimer of continued contractual responsibility.
  • 131
    • 36248944924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Old Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring) (internal quotation marks omitted).
    • Old Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring) (internal quotation marks omitted).
  • 132
    • 36248931378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oki Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring) (Seaman's throws kerosene on the litigation bonfire by holding out the allure of punitive damages, a golden carrot that entices into court parties who might otherwise be inclined to resolve their differences.); Lynch & Freytag v. Cooper, 267 Cal. Rptr. 189, 195-96 (Ct. App. 1990) (suggesting that minor contract action was litigated overzealously due to the allure of punitive damages).
    • See Oki Am., 872 F.2d at 315 (Kozinski, J., concurring) ("Seaman's throws kerosene on the litigation bonfire by holding out the allure of punitive damages, a golden carrot that entices into court parties who might otherwise be inclined to resolve their differences."); Lynch & Freytag v. Cooper, 267 Cal. Rptr. 189, 195-96 (Ct. App. 1990) (suggesting that minor contract action was litigated overzealously due to the "allure of punitive damages").
  • 133
    • 33846119188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Samuel W. Buell, Novel Criminal Fraud, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1971, 1988-92 (2006) (collecting examples of similar observations about the law of fraud).
    • Cf. Samuel W. Buell, Novel Criminal Fraud, 81 N.Y.U. L. REV. 1971, 1988-92 (2006) (collecting examples of similar observations about the law of fraud).
  • 134
    • 36248998757 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 686 P.2d at 1167
    • 686 P.2d at 1167.
  • 135
    • 36248960959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, Seaman's recognized the parties' ability to shape the contours of their agreement and to include provisions for attorney fees and liquidated damages in the event of breach___[T]hey are free, within reasonable limits at least, to agree upon the standards by which application of the covenant [of good faith] is to be measured. 686 P.2d at 1167. While allowing that the availability of party choice counseled caution in applying tort remedies in the contract setting, the court did not discuss whether parties might opt-out of or contractually modify the Seaman's tort
    • In fact, Seaman's recognized the parties' ability "to shape the contours of their agreement and to include provisions for attorney fees and liquidated damages in the event of breach___[T]hey are free, within reasonable limits at least, to agree upon the standards by which application of the covenant [of good faith] is to be measured." 686 P.2d at 1167. While allowing that the availability of party choice counseled caution in applying tort remedies in the contract setting, the court did not discuss whether parties might opt-out of or contractually modify the Seaman's tort.
  • 136
    • 84858464131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSERAND KEETON ON TORTS § 105, at 728 (5th ed. 1984).
    • W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSERAND KEETON ON TORTS § 105, at 728 (5th ed. 1984).
  • 137
    • 36248992231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Morrill v. Becton, Dickinson & Co., 747 F.2d 1217, 1222 (8th Cir. 1984) (holding that evidence was insufficient to establish requisite scienter for some claimed misrepresentations as to sales figures connected to royalty payments).
    • See, e.g., Morrill v. Becton, Dickinson & Co., 747 F.2d 1217, 1222 (8th Cir. 1984) (holding that evidence was insufficient to establish requisite scienter for some claimed misrepresentations as to sales figures connected to royalty payments).
  • 138
    • 36249025163 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 1, 20-25, 62.
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 1, 20-25, 62.
  • 139
    • 36248971537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g, Morrill, 747 F.2d at 1220 (false royalty statements to inventor, Gregory v. Chem. Waste Mgmt, Inc, 38 F. Supp. 2d 598 (W.D. Tenn. 1996, false waste-disposal facility royalty statements, Reis v. Peabody Coal Co, 997 S.W.2d 49, 68, 72 (Mo. Ct. App. 1999, false royalty statements and misrepresentations as to compliance with most-favored-nation clause, Apple Records, Inc. v. Capitol Records, Inc, 137 A.D.2d 50, 56 (N.Y. App. Div. 1988, false royalty statements in recording contract, Oestreicher v. Am. Nat'l Stores, Inc, 225 S.E.2d 797 (N.C. 1976, false royalty sales statements, Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp, 573 N.W.2d 493 (S.D. 1997, false oil royalty statements, For another nonroyalty case, see Krantz v. Chateau Stores of Canada Ltd, 683 N.Y.S.2d 24 App. Div. 1998, false statement of annual profits used as basis for bonus
    • See, e.g., Morrill, 747 F.2d at 1220 (false royalty statements to inventor); Gregory v. Chem. Waste Mgmt., Inc., 38 F. Supp. 2d 598 (W.D. Tenn. 1996) (false waste-disposal facility royalty statements); Reis v. Peabody Coal Co., 997 S.W.2d 49, 68, 72 (Mo. Ct. App. 1999) (false royalty statements and misrepresentations as to compliance with most-favored-nation clause); Apple Records, Inc. v. Capitol Records, Inc., 137 A.D.2d 50, 56 (N.Y. App. Div. 1988) (false royalty statements in recording contract); Oestreicher v. Am. Nat'l Stores, Inc., 225 S.E.2d 797 (N.C. 1976) (false royalty sales statements) ; Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp., 573 N.W.2d 493 (S.D. 1997) (false oil royalty statements). For another nonroyalty case, see Krantz v. Chateau Stores of Canada Ltd., 683 N.Y.S.2d 24 (App. Div. 1998) (false statement of annual profits used as basis for bonus).
  • 140
    • 36249020233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richmond Metro. Auth. v. McDevitt St. Bovis, Inc., 507 S.E.2d 344 (Va. 1998).
    • Richmond Metro. Auth. v. McDevitt St. Bovis, Inc., 507 S.E.2d 344 (Va. 1998).
  • 141
    • 36249003241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 646 Fad 224, 225-27 (5th Cir. Unit A May 1981).
    • 646 Fad 224, 225-27 (5th Cir. Unit A May 1981).
  • 142
    • 36249013068 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 102 P.3d 268 (Cal. 2004).
    • 102 P.3d 268 (Cal. 2004).
  • 143
    • 36249026914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 271
    • Id. at 271.
  • 144
    • 36249018781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Robinson Helicopter Co. v. Dana Corp., 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d 682, 686 n.6 (Ct. App. 2003).
    • See Robinson Helicopter Co. v. Dana Corp., 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d 682, 686 n.6
  • 146
    • 36249019103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an even better example, see the discussion of the RIO and RIO2 contracts in the Conclusion.
    • For an even better example, see the discussion of the RIO and RIO2 contracts in the Conclusion.
  • 147
    • 84858463866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 550 (1997).
    • See RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF TORTS § 550 (1997).
  • 148
    • 36248979037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I have been able to locate only one case applying fraudulent suppression based on a contractual duty to disclose. Gregory v. Chemical Waste Management, Inc, 38 F. Supp. 2d 598 (WD. Tenn. 1996, held that there was a duty to disclose where the contract warranted that the defendant's representations do not and will not include any untrue statement of material fact or fail to include any material fact, all to the end that such statements are not misleading. Id. at 612 emphasis omitted, The court concluded that the defendant breached the resultant duty to disclose when it did not reveal a change in its manner of calculating royalty payments. Id. The fraud claim in that case, however, was also supported by affirmative misrepresentations in the royalty statements. Id at 611-12. The reason there are not more examples of fraudulent concealment based on contractual duties to disclose is not difficult to discern: the vast majority of cases and commentar
    • I have been able to locate only one case applying fraudulent suppression based on a contractual duty to disclose. Gregory v. Chemical Waste Management, Inc., 38 F. Supp. 2d 598 (WD. Tenn. 1996), held that there was a duty to disclose where the contract warranted that the defendant's representations "do not and will not include any untrue statement of material fact or fail to include any material fact, all to the end that such statements are not misleading." Id. at 612 (emphasis omitted). The court concluded that the defendant breached the resultant duty to disclose when it did not reveal a change in its manner of calculating royalty payments. Id. The fraud claim in that case, however, was also supported by affirmative misrepresentations in the royalty statements. Id at 611-12. The reason there are not more examples of fraudulent concealment based on contractual duties to disclose is not difficult to discern: the vast majority of cases and commentary on fraud by silence concern fraud in the inducement, before a contract exists.
  • 149
    • 84858461987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 37 AM. JUR. 2D Fraud and Deceit § 204 (2006);
    • See, e.g., 37 AM. JUR. 2D Fraud and Deceit § 204 (2006);
  • 150
    • 0042864176 scopus 로고
    • The Structure of a General Theory of Nondbclosure, 41
    • Christopher T. Wonnell, The Structure of a General Theory of Nondbclosure, 41 CASE W. RES. L. REV. 329 (1991).
    • (1991) CASE W. RES. L. REV , vol.329
    • Wonnell, C.T.1
  • 151
    • 84858464130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF ECONOMIC TORTS AND RELATED WRONGS § 8 (Preliminary Draft No. 2, 2006).
    • See RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF ECONOMIC TORTS AND RELATED WRONGS § 8 (Preliminary Draft No. 2, 2006).
  • 152
    • 36248934567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robinson Helicopter, 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 684.
    • Robinson Helicopter, 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 684.
  • 153
    • 36248963086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Justice Traynor explained in the seminal case, [t]he history of the doctrine of strict liability in tort indicates that it was designed, not to undermine the warranty provisions of the sales act or of the Uniform Commercial Code but, rather, to govern the distinct problem of physical injuries. Seely v. White Motor Co., 403 P.2d 145, 149 (Cal. 1965) (Traynor, C.J.).
    • As Justice Traynor explained in the seminal case, "[t]he history of the doctrine of strict liability in tort indicates that it was designed, not to undermine the warranty provisions of the sales act or of the Uniform Commercial Code but, rather, to govern the distinct problem of physical injuries." Seely v. White Motor Co., 403 P.2d 145, 149 (Cal. 1965) (Traynor, C.J.).
  • 154
    • 36249031415 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HTP, Ltd. v. Lineas Aereas Costarricenses, S.A, 685 So. 2d 1238, 1239 (Fla. 1996). The leading case adopting this approach is Huron Tool & Engineering Co. v. Precision Consulting Services, Inc., 532 N.W.2d 541, 544-45 (Mich. Ct. App. 1995). See also Dinsmore Instrument Co. v. Bombardier, Inc., 999 F. Supp. 968, 971-72 (E.D. Mich. 1998); Valleyside Dairy Farms, Inc. v. A.O. Smith Corp., 944 F. Supp. 612, 616-17 (WD. Mich. 1995); Kaloti Enters., Inc. v. Kellogg Sales Co., 699 N.W.2d 205, 219-21 (Wis. 2005).
    • HTP, Ltd. v. Lineas Aereas Costarricenses, S.A, 685 So. 2d 1238, 1239 (Fla. 1996). The leading case adopting this approach is Huron Tool & Engineering Co. v. Precision Consulting Services, Inc., 532 N.W.2d 541, 544-45 (Mich. Ct. App. 1995). See also Dinsmore Instrument Co. v. Bombardier, Inc., 999 F. Supp. 968, 971-72 (E.D. Mich. 1998); Valleyside Dairy Farms, Inc. v. A.O. Smith Corp., 944 F. Supp. 612, 616-17 (WD. Mich. 1995); Kaloti Enters., Inc. v. Kellogg Sales Co., 699 N.W.2d 205, 219-21 (Wis. 2005).
  • 155
    • 84901285847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deception, Economic Loss and Mass-Market Consumers: Consumer Protection Statutes as Persuasive Authority in the Common Law of Fraud, 48
    • For academic discussions, see
    • For academic discussions, see Jean Braucher, Deception, Economic Loss and Mass-Market Consumers: Consumer Protection Statutes as Persuasive Authority in the Common Law of Fraud, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 829 (2006);
    • (2006) ARIZ. L. REV , vol.829
    • Braucher, J.1
  • 156
    • 0033262060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bucking the "Trend": The Uniform Commercial Code, the Economic Loss Doctrine, and Common Law Causes of Action for Fraud and Misrepresentation, 84
    • Steven C. Tourek, Thomas H. Byrd & Charles J. Schoenwetter, Bucking the "Trend": The Uniform Commercial Code, the Economic Loss Doctrine, and Common Law Causes of Action for Fraud and Misrepresentation, 84 IOWA L. REV. 875 (1999);
    • (1999) IOWA L. REV , vol.875
    • Tourek, S.C.1    Byrd, T.H.2    Schoenwetter, C.J.3
  • 157
    • 36248950029 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • R Joseph Barton, Note, Drowning in a Sea of Contract: Application of the Economic Loss Rule to Fraud and Negligent Mbrepresentation Claims, 41 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1789 (2000).
    • R Joseph Barton, Note, Drowning in a Sea of Contract: Application of the Economic Loss Rule to Fraud and Negligent Mbrepresentation Claims, 41 WM. & MARY L. REV. 1789 (2000).
  • 158
    • 36248972968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 695; see Tourek et al., supra note 103, at 895-912;
    • 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 695; see Tourek et al., supra note 103, at 895-912;
  • 159
    • 36248974057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barton, supra note 103, at 1802-12
    • Barton, supra note 103, at 1802-12.
  • 160
    • 36248955937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some courts have taken the further step of applying the economic loss rule to foreclose tort claims against the defendant who fraudulendy induces the contract by representations about the character and quality of the goods or services sold. Dan B. Dobbs, An Introduction to Non-Statutory Economic Loss Claims, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 713, 729 (2006).
    • Some courts have taken the further step of applying the economic loss rule to "foreclose tort claims against the defendant who fraudulendy induces the contract by representations about the character and quality of the goods or services sold." Dan B. Dobbs, An Introduction to Non-Statutory Economic Loss Claims, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 713, 729 (2006).
  • 161
    • 36249013060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Robinson Helicopter, 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 697.
    • See, e.g., Robinson Helicopter, 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 697.
  • 162
    • 36248975113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Huron Tool, 532 N.W.2d at 545.
    • Huron Tool, 532 N.W.2d at 545.
  • 163
    • 36248968542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 697; see also Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp., 573 N.W.2d 493, 510 (S.D. 1997) (Amundson, J., dissenting in part) (arguing that there is no fraud liability where the contract impliedly create[d] the obligation to make true factual representations).
    • 129 Cal. Rptr. 2d at 697; see also Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp., 573 N.W.2d 493, 510 (S.D. 1997) (Amundson, J., dissenting in part) (arguing that there is no fraud liability where the contract "impliedly create[d] the obligation to make true factual representations").
  • 164
    • 36249006391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Grynberg, 573 N.W.2d at 501 (majority opinion) (holding that false royalty statements, though required by contract, violated a separate obligation to refrain from invading the property of others by fraud).
    • But see Grynberg, 573 N.W.2d at 501 (majority opinion) (holding that false royalty statements, though required by contract, violated a separate obligation to refrain from invading the property of others by fraud).
  • 166
    • 36249021348 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • at 276 (emphasis added). Other factors emphasized by the California Supreme Court likely to distinguish Robinson Helicopter from future cases include the impact of Dana's breach on public safety and the fact that the improper clutches put Robinson out of compliance with FAA regulations
    • at
    • Id. at 276 (emphasis added). Other factors emphasized by the California Supreme Court likely to distinguish Robinson Helicopter from future cases include the impact of Dana's breach on public safety and the fact that the improper clutches put Robinson out of compliance with FAA regulations. See id. at 274 n.7.
    • See id , Issue.7 , pp. 274
  • 167
    • 36248979036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Saratoga Fishing Co. v. J.M. Martinac & Co, 520 U.S. 875, 880 (1997, see also, e.g, Clark v. Rowe, 701 N.E.2d 624, 626 (Mass. 1998, When the economic loss rule has been applied, the parties usually were in a position to bargain freely concerning the allocation of risk, Spring Motors Distribs, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co, 489 A.2d 660, 672 (N.J. 1985, Contract principles, are generally more appropriate for determining claims for consequential damage that the parties have, or could have, addressed in their agreement, Grynberg v. Questar Pipeline Co, 70 P.3d 1, 11 Utah 2003, Whether the doctrine is asserted in terms of economic loss or independent duty, the underlying reasoning remains the same: tort law should govern the duties and liabilities imposed by legislatures and courts upon non-consenting members of society, and contract law should govern the bargained-for duties and liabilities of persons who exercise freedom of contract
    • Saratoga Fishing Co. v. J.M. Martinac & Co., 520 U.S. 875, 880 (1997); see also, e.g., Clark v. Rowe, 701 N.E.2d 624, 626 (Mass. 1998) ("When the economic loss rule has been applied, the parties usually were in a position to bargain freely concerning the allocation of risk ....); Spring Motors Distribs., Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 489 A.2d 660, 672 (N.J. 1985) ("Contract principles... are generally more appropriate for determining claims for consequential damage that the parties have, or could have, addressed in their agreement."); Grynberg v. Questar Pipeline Co., 70 P.3d 1, 11 (Utah 2003) ("Whether the doctrine is asserted in terms of economic loss or independent duty, the underlying reasoning remains the same: tort law should govern the duties and liabilities imposed by legislatures and courts upon non-consenting members of society, and contract law should govern the bargained-for duties and liabilities of persons who exercise freedom of contract.");
  • 168
    • 84858463846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF ECONOMIC TORTS AND RELATED WRONGS § 8 cmt. b (Preliminary Draft No. 2, 2006) (noting that rationales for the economic loss rule include [e]ncourag[ing] private ordering and preserving the priority of contract law).
    • RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF ECONOMIC TORTS AND RELATED WRONGS § 8 cmt. b (Preliminary Draft No. 2, 2006) (noting that rationales for the economic loss rule include "[e]ncourag[ing] private ordering" and "preserving the priority of contract law").
  • 169
    • 36249015812 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The above analysis is significandy different from other arguments for excluding fraud from the economic loss rule. For instance, Tourek, Boyd, and Schoenwetter maintain that the rule should not apply to fraud because, among other things, [a]s a practical matter, it is difficult to see how a party can effectively anticipate and therefore negotiate the allocation of risks for every type of misrepresentation and every form of deceit that may be perpetrated by the other party to an agreement. Tourek et al., supra note 103, at 916;
    • The above analysis is significandy different from other arguments for excluding fraud from the economic loss rule. For instance, Tourek, Boyd, and Schoenwetter maintain that the rule should not apply to fraud because, among other things, "[a]s a practical matter, it is difficult to see how a party can effectively anticipate and therefore negotiate the allocation of risks for every type of misrepresentation and every form of deceit that may be perpetrated by the other party to an agreement." Tourek et al., supra note 103, at 916;
  • 170
    • 36249003700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Stoughton Trailers, Inc. v. Henkel Corp., 965 F. Supp. 1227, 1236 (W.D. Wis. 1997) (A party to a contract cannot rationally calculate the possibility that the other party will deliberately misrepresent terms critical to that contract.);
    • see also Stoughton Trailers, Inc. v. Henkel Corp., 965 F. Supp. 1227, 1236 (W.D. Wis. 1997) ("A party to a contract cannot rationally calculate the possibility that the other party will deliberately misrepresent terms critical to that contract.");
  • 171
    • 36248965549 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dobbs, supra note 104, at 731 (Where the parties have not agreed to subject a given risk or dispute to the contract's terms, to apply the economic loss rule is not to honor the contract but rather to impose a contract limitation where none was intended ....). My argument is exactly the opposite: when it comes to contractually required representations, the parties might anticipate and prefer allocating the risk of misrepresentation in accordance with the law of fraud, but the expansive reading of the economic loss rule prevents them from doing so.
    • Dobbs, supra note 104, at 731 ("Where the parties have not agreed to subject a given risk or dispute to the contract's terms, to apply the economic loss rule is not to honor the contract but rather to impose a contract limitation where none was intended ...."). My argument is exactly the opposite: when it comes to contractually required representations, the parties might anticipate and prefer allocating the risk of misrepresentation in accordance with the law of fraud, but the expansive reading of the economic loss rule prevents them from doing so.
  • 172
    • 36249015262 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HTP, Ltd. v. Lineas Aereas Costarricenses S.A, 685 So. 2d 1238 (Fla. 1996) ; Huron Tool & Eng'g Co. v. Precision Consulting Servs., Inc., 532 N.W.2d 541 (Mich. Ct. App. 1995); Kaloti Enters., Inc. v. Kellogg Sales Co., 699 N.W.2d 205 (Wis. 2005); see also AKA Distrib. Co. v. Whirlpool Corp., 137 F.3d 1083 (8th Cir. 1998) (applying Minnesota law); Cooper Power Sys., Inc. v. Union Carbide Chems. & Plastics Co., 123 F.3d 675 (7th Cir. 1997) (applying Wisconsin law).
    • See HTP, Ltd. v. Lineas Aereas Costarricenses S.A, 685 So. 2d 1238 (Fla. 1996) ; Huron Tool & Eng'g Co. v. Precision Consulting Servs., Inc., 532 N.W.2d 541 (Mich. Ct. App. 1995); Kaloti Enters., Inc. v. Kellogg Sales Co., 699 N.W.2d 205 (Wis. 2005); see also AKA Distrib. Co. v. Whirlpool Corp., 137 F.3d 1083 (8th Cir. 1998) (applying Minnesota law); Cooper Power Sys., Inc. v. Union Carbide Chems. & Plastics Co., 123 F.3d 675 (7th Cir. 1997) (applying Wisconsin law).
  • 173
    • 36248956525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a summary overview, see Dorff, supra note 80, at 407-11
    • For a summary overview, see Dorff, supra note 80, at 407-11.
  • 174
    • 29744431970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For other examples of how these doctrines have been applied to concealment of breach cases, see Catherine Paskoff Chang, Note, Two Wrongs Can Make Two Rights: Why Courts Should Allow Tortious Recovery for Intentional Concealment of Contract Breach, 39 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 47, 66-72 (2005).
    • For other examples of how these doctrines have been applied to concealment of breach cases, see Catherine Paskoff Chang, Note, Two Wrongs Can Make Two Rights: Why Courts Should Allow Tortious Recovery for Intentional Concealment of Contract Breach, 39 COLUM. J.L. & SOC. PROBS. 47, 66-72 (2005).
  • 175
    • 36248931375 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Not all courts exclude liability from the contract setting. See, e.g, Morrill v. Becton, Dickinson & Co, 747 F.2d 1217, 1222 (8th Cir. 1984, U]nder Missouri law, liability in tort may co-exist with liability in contract arising out of the same events, Life Ins. Co. v. Murray Inv. Co, 646 F.2d 224, 228 (5th Cir. Unit A May 1981, U]nder Texas law, if the act complained of constitutes both a breach of contract and a willful tort, exemplary damages are recoverable, And the tendency to exclude tort is of relatively recent origin. See WILLIAM LLOYD PROSSER, The Borderland of Tort and Contract, in SELECTED TOPICS ON THE LAW OF TORTS 380 1954, Prosser himself was in favor of a broad overlap between tort and contract: When the ghosts of case and assumpsit walk hand in hand at midnight, it is sometimes a convenient and comforting thing to have a borderland in which
    • Not all courts exclude liability from the contract setting. See, e.g., Morrill v. Becton, Dickinson & Co., 747 F.2d 1217, 1222 (8th Cir. 1984) ("[U]nder Missouri law, liability in tort may co-exist with liability in contract arising out of the same events.") ; Life Ins. Co. v. Murray Inv. Co., 646 F.2d 224, 228 (5th Cir. Unit A May 1981) ("[U]nder Texas law, if the act complained of constitutes both a breach of contract and a willful tort, exemplary damages are recoverable."). And the tendency to exclude tort is of relatively recent origin. See WILLIAM LLOYD PROSSER, The Borderland of Tort and Contract, in SELECTED TOPICS ON THE LAW OF TORTS 380 (1954). Prosser himself was in favor of a broad overlap between tort and contract: "When the ghosts of case and assumpsit walk hand in hand at midnight, it is sometimes a convenient and comforting thing to have a borderland in which they may lose themselves." Id at 452.
  • 176
    • 36248958565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 507 S.E.2d at 347; see also Americana Petroleum Corp. v. Northville Indus. Corp., 606 N.Y.S.2d 906, 908 (App. Div. 1994) ([I]n order to state a cause of action sounding in fraud, the plaintiff must allege a breach of duty which is collateral or extraneous to the contract between the parties.).
    • 507 S.E.2d at 347; see also Americana Petroleum Corp. v. Northville Indus. Corp., 606 N.Y.S.2d 906, 908 (App. Div. 1994) ("[I]n order to state a cause of action sounding in fraud, the plaintiff must allege a breach of duty which is collateral or extraneous to the contract between the parties.").
  • 177
    • 36248941835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cimino v. FirsTier Bank, 530 N.W.2d 606, 613 (Neb. 1995).
    • Cimino v. FirsTier Bank, 530 N.W.2d 606, 613 (Neb. 1995).
  • 178
    • 36248991707 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Textron Fin. Corp. v. Nationwide Mut. Ins. Co., 684 N.E.2d 1261, 1271 (Ohio Ct. App. 1996) (emphasis omitted); see also Chachere v. Drake, 941 S.W.2d 193, 197 (Tex. App. 1996) (The mere availability of a tort-based theory of recovery is not sufficient; actual damages sustained from an independent tort must be proven before punitive damages are available.).
    • Textron Fin. Corp. v. Nationwide Mut. Ins. Co., 684 N.E.2d 1261, 1271 (Ohio Ct. App. 1996) (emphasis omitted); see also Chachere v. Drake, 941 S.W.2d 193, 197 (Tex. App. 1996) ("The mere availability of a tort-based theory of recovery is not sufficient; actual damages sustained from an independent tort must be proven before punitive damages are available.").
  • 179
    • 36248954865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • AYRES & KLASS, supra note 6, at 59-82
    • AYRES & KLASS, supra note 6, at 59-82.
  • 180
    • 36248955934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sony Music Entm't Inc. v. Robison, No. 01 Civ. 6415, 2002 WL 272406, at *2 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 26, 2002). Representatives of the Beatles have recently made similar allegations against Capitol Records. See Apple Corps Ltd. v. Capitol Records, Inc., No. 05-604385, slip op. at 4-5 (N.Y. Sup. Ct., Aug. 23, 2006).
    • Sony Music Entm't Inc. v. Robison, No. 01 Civ. 6415, 2002 WL 272406, at *2 (S.D.N.Y. Feb. 26, 2002). Representatives of the Beatles have recently made similar allegations against Capitol Records. See Apple Corps Ltd. v. Capitol Records, Inc., No. 05-604385, slip op. at 4-5 (N.Y. Sup. Ct., Aug. 23, 2006).
  • 181
    • 36249003236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sony Music, 2002 WL 272406, at *2. The district court dismissed the claim based on a line of cases of dubious authority that suggest promissory fraud is not actionable in New York. See Ian Ayres & Gregory Klass, Prombsory Fraud, N.Y. ST. B. ASS'N J., May 2006, at 26,27.
    • Sony Music, 2002 WL 272406, at *2. The district court dismissed the claim based on a line of cases of dubious authority that suggest promissory fraud is not actionable in New York. See Ian Ayres & Gregory Klass, Prombsory Fraud, N.Y. ST. B. ASS'N J., May 2006, at 26,27.
  • 182
    • 36248971043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 901 So. 2d 1 6-9 (Ala. 2004).
    • 901 So. 2d 1 6-9 (Ala. 2004).
  • 183
    • 36248935959 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 891 A.d 1032, 1036 (Del. Ch. 2006); see also id. at 1056-62 (discussing authorities);
    • 891 A.d 1032, 1036 (Del. Ch. 2006); see also id. at 1056-62 (discussing authorities);
  • 184
    • 84858463843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 195(1) (2006) (A term exempting a party from tort liability for harm caused intentionally or recklessly is unenforceable on grounds of public policy.) ;
    • RESTATEMENT (SECOND) OF CONTRACTS § 195(1) (2006) ("A term exempting a party from tort liability for harm caused intentionally or recklessly is unenforceable on grounds of public policy.") ;
  • 185
    • 36248995086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Davis, supra note 5, at 488-92, 513-20 summarizing relevant holdings
    • Davis, supra note 5, at 488-92, 513-20 (summarizing relevant holdings).
  • 186
    • 36248970495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • With each royalty payment it sent to the State, Exxon effectively represented that (i) it was paying royalty from gross when it in fact was not, (ii) its gross was less than it in fact was, (iii) it was paying the State for all gas produced when it in fact was not and/or (iv) it owed the State less than it in fact did. Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 26. The trial court's theory of fraud was unfortunately expansive in several other directions as well. For one thing, the court permitted a finding of fraudulent suppression based on the fact that Exxon withheld or provided only partial royalty reports.
    • "With each royalty payment it sent to the State, Exxon effectively represented that (i) it was paying royalty from gross when it in fact was not, (ii) its gross was less than it in fact was, (iii) it was paying the State for all gas produced when it in fact was not and/or (iv) it owed the State less than it in fact did." Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 26. The trial court's theory of fraud was unfortunately expansive in several other directions as well. For one thing, the court permitted a finding of fraudulent suppression based on the fact that Exxon withheld or provided only partial royalty reports.
  • 187
    • 36248996283 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 27;
    • Id. at 27;
  • 188
    • 36248972964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp., 573 N.W.2d 493, 498-99 (S.D. 1997) (royalty reports not itemized and withheld were contrary to contract). Unlike the case where a breaching promisor is contractually required to report breach and remains silent, here the absence of required reports or information should have put Alabama on notice that there might be a first-order breach. Elsewhere the trial court appears to endorse a broader action for bad faith breach: Alabama law surely does not permit a business party such as Exxon to breach a contract as it sees fit without fear of punitive damages.
    • see also Grynberg v. Citation Oil & Gas Corp., 573 N.W.2d 493, 498-99 (S.D. 1997) (royalty reports not itemized and withheld were contrary to contract). Unlike the case where a breaching promisor is contractually required to report breach and remains silent, here the absence of required reports or information should have put Alabama on notice that there might be a first-order breach. Elsewhere the trial court appears to endorse a broader action for bad faith breach: "Alabama law surely does not permit a business party such as Exxon to breach a contract as it sees fit without fear of punitive damages."
  • 189
    • 36248951490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 23.
    • Post-Judgment Order, supra note 22, at 23.
  • 190
    • 36249006390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Rea, supra note 63, at 159 ([T]he parties to a contract are unlikely to agree ex ante to damages that exceed the expected loss.);
    • See, e.g., Rea, supra note 63, at 159 ("[T]he parties to a contract are unlikely to agree ex ante to damages that exceed the expected loss.");
  • 191
    • 36249026906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 370 ([P]romisees do not want contractual damage measures that would grant more than their lost expectation.).
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 370 ("[P]romisees do not want contractual damage measures that would grant more than their lost expectation.").
  • 192
    • 0009037768 scopus 로고
    • Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61
    • For more detailed versions, see
    • For more detailed versions, see Richard Craswell, Contract Remedies, Renegotiation, and the Theory of Efficient Breach, 61 S. CAL. L. REV. 629 (1988);
    • (1988) S. CAL. L. REV , vol.629
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 193
    • 36248984963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 151-63;
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 151-63;
  • 194
    • 36249029085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 372-83;
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 372-83;
  • 195
    • 36249000380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Talley, supra note 60, at 1212-18
    • and Talley, supra note 60, at 1212-18.
  • 196
    • 36248966931 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The core argument presented here omits some considerations, such as the use of penalties as signals, their employment as strategic barriers to entry, and their effect on price and selection, as well as economic arguments that, in special circumstances, extracompensatory remedies can promote efficient investment. For a detailed overview of the literature, see Edlin & Schwartz, supra note 4
    • The core argument presented here omits some considerations, such as the use of penalties as signals, their employment as strategic barriers to entry, and their effect on price and selection, as well as economic arguments that, in special circumstances, extracompensatory remedies can promote efficient investment. For a detailed overview of the literature, see Edlin & Schwartz, supra note 4.
  • 197
    • 36249024622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 117-18 (6th ed. 2003);
    • See RICHARD A. POSNER, ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF LAW 117-18 (6th ed. 2003);
  • 198
    • 36248963987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Talley, supra note 60, at 1218-41
    • Talley, supra note 60, at 1218-41.
  • 199
    • 36248944480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Clarkson et al., supra note 60, at 360-62;
    • But see Clarkson et al., supra note 60, at 360-62;
  • 200
    • 36248966354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note 59, at, arguing that renegotiation is possible
    • Dodge, supra note 59, at 632-33, 666-76 (arguing that renegotiation is possible) ;
    • supra
    • Dodge1
  • 201
    • 36249001011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 587
    • Goetz & Scott, supra note 63, at 587.
  • 202
    • 36249023541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This moral hazard problem is emphasized by Clarkson et al, supra note 60, at 368-72
    • This moral hazard problem is emphasized by Clarkson et al., supra note 60, at 368-72.
  • 203
    • 36248966933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Craswell, supra note 124, at 646-53, 656-61;
    • See also Craswell, supra note 124, at 646-53, 656-61;
  • 204
    • 36248985512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 155
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 155.
  • 205
    • 36249029083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Craswell, supra note 124, at 642-45;
    • See Craswell, supra note 124, at 642-45;
  • 206
    • 0009905372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Deterrence and Damages: The Multiplier Principle and Its Alternatives, 97
    • Richard Craswell, Deterrence and Damages: The Multiplier Principle and Its Alternatives, 97 MICH. L. REV. 2185, 2230 (1999);
    • (1999) MICH. L. REV , vol.2185 , pp. 2230
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 207
    • 36249026098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 152-54;
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 152-54;
  • 208
    • 36248937592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 392
    • Schwartz, supra note 64, at 392.
  • 209
    • 36248992763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Samuel Rea summarizes the arguments as follows: Penalty clauses are costly because they (1) induce excessive precautions by the promisor, 2) induce deficient precautions by the promisee, 3) overinsure the promisee, and (4) expose the promisor to additional risk. Rea, supra note 63, at 156
    • Samuel Rea summarizes the arguments as follows: "Penalty clauses are costly because they (1) induce excessive precautions by the promisor, (2) induce deficient precautions by the promisee, (3) overinsure the promisee, and (4) expose the promisor to additional risk." Rea, supra note 63, at 156.
  • 210
    • 36248942374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Sanchirico, supra note 17, at 1352-60
    • See Sanchirico, supra note 17, at 1352-60.
  • 211
    • 0000036639 scopus 로고
    • Opportunbtic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65
    • For a detailed analysis of the concept of opportunistic breach, see
    • For a detailed analysis of the concept of opportunistic breach, see Timothy J. Muris, Opportunbtic Behavior and the Law of Contracts, 65 MINN. L. REV. 521, 521-26 (1981).
    • (1981) MINN. L. REV , vol.521 , pp. 521-526
    • Muris, T.J.1
  • 212
    • 36248966097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089, 1139 n.118 (1981) ([Opportunistic behavior only redistributes portions of an already allocated contractual pie.);
    • See also Charles J. Goetz & Robert E. Scott, Principles of Relational Contracts, 67 VA. L. REV. 1089, 1139 n.118 (1981) ("[Opportunistic behavior only redistributes portions of an already allocated contractual pie.");
  • 213
    • 36248984160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Barry Perlstein, Crossing the Contract-Tort Boundary: An Economic Argument for the Imposition of Extracompensatory Damages for Opportunistic Breach of Contract, 58 BROOK. L. REV. 877, 880 (1992) (The opportunistic actor creates more value for himself, but only by taking an equivalent amount or more from others.).
    • Barry Perlstein, Crossing the Contract-Tort Boundary: An Economic Argument for the Imposition of Extracompensatory Damages for Opportunistic Breach of Contract, 58 BROOK. L. REV. 877, 880 (1992) ("The opportunistic actor creates more value for himself, but only by taking an equivalent amount or more from others.").
  • 214
    • 36249010737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mutis, supra note 130, at 524
    • Mutis, supra note 130, at 524.
  • 215
    • 36249028000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • POSNER, supra note 125, at 118;
    • POSNER, supra note 125, at 118;
  • 216
    • 36248966352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Dodge, supra note 59, at 654-62 (arguing that punitive damages for opportunistic breach result in greater efficiency);
    • see also Dodge, supra note 59, at 654-62 (arguing that punitive damages for opportunistic breach result in greater efficiency);
  • 217
    • 36248991154 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard A Posner, CommonLaw Economic Torts: An Economic and Legal Analysb, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 735, 745-47 (2006) (discussing when punitive damages for breach are appropriate).
    • Richard A Posner, CommonLaw Economic Torts: An Economic and Legal Analysb, 48 ARIZ. L. REV. 735, 745-47 (2006) (discussing when punitive damages for breach are appropriate).
  • 218
    • 36249011809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Several academics have suggested permitting penalty clauses for opportunistic breach only, though they have proposed different tests for distinguishing opportunistic from efficient breach. See Dodge, supra note 59, at 633 n.14 (listing authors who support punitive damages for opportunistic breach). To the extent that obstructive breaches are very likely to be opportunistic, my suggestion is consonant with these recommendations.
    • Several academics have suggested permitting penalty clauses for opportunistic breach only, though they have proposed different tests for distinguishing opportunistic from efficient breach. See Dodge, supra note 59, at 633 n.14 (listing authors who support punitive damages for opportunistic breach). To the extent that obstructive breaches are very likely to be opportunistic, my suggestion is consonant with these recommendations.
  • 219
    • 36249011264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Efforts to avoid obstruction are wasted when they cost the promisor more than they benefit the promisee by providing her needed assurance that she will recover for a first-order breach, At the time of formation, neither party wants a term that will result in such inefficient behavior, which decreases the total value of the transaction that the parties have to divide between themselves. In other words, the promisor is likely to pass some or all of the costs of wasted effort on to the promisee in the form of a higher price
    • Efforts to avoid obstruction are wasted when they cost the promisor more than they benefit the promisee (by providing her needed assurance that she will recover for a first-order breach). At the time of formation, neither party wants a term that will result in such inefficient behavior, which decreases the total value of the transaction that the parties have to divide between themselves. In other words, the promisor is likely to pass some or all of the costs of wasted effort on to the promisee in the form of a higher price.
  • 220
    • 36248966354 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See note 59, at, recommending punitive damages for willful, as opposed to involuntary, breach
    • See Dodge, supra note 59, at 651-98 (recommending punitive damages for willful, as opposed to involuntary, breach).
    • supra , pp. 651-698
    • Dodge1
  • 221
    • 36248962016 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is another way of putting the familiar observation that extracompensatory remedies can be a cost-effective means of communicating a high probability of performance. See POSNER, supra note 125, at 128;
    • This is another way of putting the familiar observation that extracompensatory remedies can be a cost-effective means of communicating a high probability of performance. See POSNER, supra note 125, at 128;
  • 222
    • 36248938142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 156-57
    • Rea, supra note 63, at 156-57.
  • 223
    • 36248942373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 17, at 1352-82. One difference between my category of obstruction of recovery and Sanchirico's detection avoidance is that Sanchirico is mainly interested in criminal and regulatory sanctions. As a result, he focuses on how to prevent attempts to avoid punitive
    • Sanchirico, supra note 17, at 1352-82. One difference between my category of obstruction of recovery and Sanchirico's detection avoidance is that Sanchirico is mainly interested in criminal and regulatory sanctions. As a result, he focuses on how to prevent attempts to avoid punitive first-order sanctions, a problem with a slightly different structure than trying to prevent attempts to avoid compensatory damages.
    • first-order sanctions, a problem with a slightly different structure than trying to prevent attempts to avoid compensatory damages
    • Sanchirico1
  • 224
    • 36248991706 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1337;
    • Id. at 1337;
  • 226
    • 36248966090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The and so on leads Sanchirico to make another, more ambitious claim: Sanctioning activity X encourages another activity X+i in the form of effort exerted to avoid detection of Xby those who still choose to engage in X. Stating the principle in these general terms makes clear that it is recursive. Because the formula applies to any activity X, we are free to substitute detection avoidance itself for X, whereby it begets an X+1 equal to effort exerted to avoid detection of detection avoidance. Indeed, nothing stops us from returning to the formula with detection avoidance of detection avoidance, substituting this for X, and generating, as X+1, effort exerted to avoid detection of detection avoidance of detection avoidance. And we may continue like this ad infinitum, repeatedly inputting the last application's output. Id. at 1368
    • The "and so on" leads Sanchirico to make another, more ambitious claim: Sanctioning activity X encourages another activity X+i in the form of effort exerted to avoid detection of Xby those who still choose to engage in X. Stating the principle in these general terms makes clear that it is recursive. Because the formula applies to any activity X, we are free to substitute "detection avoidance" itself for X, whereby it begets an X+1 equal to effort exerted to avoid detection of detection avoidance. Indeed, nothing stops us from returning to the formula with "detection avoidance of detection avoidance," substituting this for X, and generating, as X+1, effort exerted to avoid detection of detection avoidance of detection avoidance. And we may continue like this ad infinitum, repeatedly inputting the last application's output. Id. at 1368.
  • 227
    • 36248972098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I do not think the recursivity claim is essential to Sanchirico's argument as a whole. In any case, it appears overstated. One typically says that a series is recursive only if its definition applies the same function to each member of the series to arrive at the next. But as Sanchirico recognizes, the incentives to engage in detection avoidance vary from one level to the next. Id. at 1369. A wrongdoer's reasons to engage in Z+1-level detection avoidance depend not only on the penalty for X-level detection avoidance, but also on the out-of-pocket cost of X+1-level detection avoidance, its chances of success, and its probability of detection. The latter factors vary stochastically from one level to the next, depending on the context. There is no a priori reason to think that there will not be some level of detection avoidance where the next higher level will, as a factual matter, be so difficult that it will not be worth the cost perhaps even without a higher-order p
    • I do not think the recursivity claim is essential to Sanchirico's argument as a whole. In any case, it appears overstated. One typically says that a series is "recursive" only if its definition applies the same function to each member of the series to arrive at the next. But as Sanchirico recognizes, the incentives to engage in detection avoidance vary from one level to the next. Id. at 1369. A wrongdoer's reasons to engage in Z+1-level detection avoidance depend not only on the penalty for X-level detection avoidance, but also on the out-of-pocket cost of X+1-level detection avoidance, its chances of success, and its probability of detection. The latter factors vary stochastically from one level to the next, depending on the context. There is no a priori reason to think that there will not be some level of detection avoidance where the next higher level will, as a factual matter, be so difficult that it will not be worth the cost (perhaps even without a higher-order penalty), putting an end to the regress.
  • 228
    • 36248944477 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the potential economic utility of damage multipliers, see Robert D. Cooter, Punitive Damages for Deterrence: When and How Much?, 40 ALA. L. REV. 1143 (1989) ;
    • On the potential economic utility of damage multipliers, see Robert D. Cooter, Punitive Damages for Deterrence: When and How Much?, 40 ALA. L. REV. 1143 (1989) ;
  • 229
    • 0346366197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysu, 111
    • and A. Mitchell Polinsky & Steven Shavell, Punitive Damages: An Economic Analysu, 111 HARV. L. REV. 869 (1998).
    • (1998) HARV. L. REV , vol.869
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 230
    • 36248948395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For some of the complications in establishing the proper multiplier and alternative approaches, see Craswell, supra note 127;
    • For some of the complications in establishing the proper multiplier and alternative approaches, see Craswell, supra note 127;
  • 231
    • 25144505223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Should Tort Damages Be Multiplied?, 21
    • and Keith N. Hylton & Thomas J. Miceli, Should Tort Damages Be Multiplied?, 21 J.L. ECON. & ORG. 388 (2005).
    • (2005) J.L. ECON. & ORG , vol.388
    • Hylton, K.N.1    Miceli, T.J.2
  • 232
    • 36248973516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The statement that multiplied compensatory damages give the promisor the right incentive to perform glosses over a number of complexities in the attempt to use a single remedy to induce both sides to behave efficiently throughout the entire transaction. See generally Craswell, supra note 124;
    • The statement that multiplied compensatory damages give the promisor the right incentive to perform glosses over a number of complexities in the attempt to use a single remedy to induce both sides to behave efficiently throughout the entire transaction. See generally Craswell, supra note 124;
  • 233
    • 22544452705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In That Case, What Is the Question? Economics and the Demands of Contract Theory, 112
    • Richard Craswell, In That Case, What Is the Question? Economics and the Demands of Contract Theory, 112 YALE L.J. 903, 907-10 (2003).
    • (2003) YALE L.J , vol.903 , pp. 907-910
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 234
    • 36248946551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In practice, most multipliers are not simply dynamic or static, but somewhere in between, depending on how fine-grained or fact-dependent they are. The idea of a perfectly dynamic multiplier is a theoretical fiction, useful in my analysis, but not to be mistaken as a description of how any multiplier actually works. Richard Craswell reports: [M]ost legal systems do not use multipliers that are calculated case by case. Instead, they use multipliers set at the same level for all defendants, or fines set at the same level for all defendants, or compensatory damages with no multipliers at all. Craswell, supra note 127, at 2198.
    • In practice, most multipliers are not simply dynamic or static, but somewhere in between, depending on how fine-grained or fact-dependent they are. The idea of a "perfectly" dynamic multiplier is a theoretical fiction, useful in my analysis, but not to be mistaken as a description of how any multiplier actually works. Richard Craswell reports: "[M]ost legal systems do not use multipliers that are calculated case by case. Instead, they use multipliers set at the same level for all defendants, or fines set at the same level for all defendants, or compensatory damages with no multipliers at all." Craswell, supra note 127, at 2198.
  • 235
    • 36248991152 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craswell's article provides the most comprehensive examination of the relative merits of static and dynamic multipliers. Other proponents of multipliers often ignore the issue. Polinsky and Shavell, who are relatively optimistic about the ability of factfinders to calculate the probability of enforcement, still recognize the danger of error and recommend that the legislature ... set damages multipliers for separate categories of wrongful conduct, based on rough assessments of the different chances of escaping liability in the various settings. Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 893.
    • Craswell's article provides the most comprehensive examination of the relative merits of static and dynamic multipliers. Other proponents of multipliers often ignore the issue. Polinsky and Shavell, who are relatively optimistic about the ability of factfinders to calculate the probability of enforcement, still recognize the danger of error and recommend that "the legislature ... set damages multipliers for separate categories of wrongful conduct, based on rough assessments of the different chances of escaping liability in the various settings." Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 893.
  • 236
    • 36249015259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This point is a variation on Robert Cooter's observation that when lawmakers can identify socially desirable behavior, but are prone to error in assessing the cost of deviations from it, then sanctions are preferable to prices. Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1524 1984, The multiplier option shows that the relevant difficulty can include not only assessing the costs of deviation, but also assessing the probability of enforcement
    • This point is a variation on Robert Cooter's observation that when "lawmakers can identify socially desirable behavior, but are prone to error in assessing the cost of deviations from it, then sanctions are preferable to prices." Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1524 (1984). The multiplier option shows that the relevant difficulty can include not only "assessing the costs of deviation," but also assessing the probability of enforcement.
  • 237
    • 36248943953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Craswell, supra note 127, at 2193-94
    • Craswell, supra note 127, at 2193-94.
  • 238
    • 36249014682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Alan Schwartz has identified a related problem with static multipliers: because the probability that the promisee will sue is endogenous, a function of the damage measure itself, the parties will find it difficult to agree on the right multiplier. Schwartz, supra note 64, at 399-401
    • Alan Schwartz has identified a related problem with static multipliers: because the probability that the promisee will sue is endogenous, a function of the damage measure itself, the parties will find it difficult to agree on the right multiplier. Schwartz, supra note 64, at 399-401.
  • 239
    • 36249013531 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • And Ian Weiner notices a similar effect in criminal law: Raising the sanction for the original crime may be counterproductive because it will increase the incentives for criminals to avoid arrest. Ian C. Wiener, Running Rampant: The Imposition of Sanctions and the Use of Force Against Fleeing Criminal Suspects, 80 GEO. L.J. 2175, 2182 (1992).
    • And Ian Weiner notices a similar effect in criminal law: "Raising the sanction for the original crime may be counterproductive because it will increase the incentives for criminals to avoid arrest." Ian C. Wiener, Running Rampant: The Imposition of Sanctions and the Use of Force Against Fleeing Criminal Suspects, 80 GEO. L.J. 2175, 2182 (1992).
  • 240
    • 36249018261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jennifer Arlen has observed that variable fines for corporate wrongdoing could, in theory, achieve similar benefits in the criminal context. Jennifer Arlen, The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 833, 849 (1994). Like me, Alen thinks the costs of case-by-case calculations of the probability of enforcement place this solution beyond the realm of realistic alternatives. Id.
    • Jennifer Arlen has observed that variable fines for corporate wrongdoing could, in theory, achieve similar benefits in the criminal context. Jennifer Arlen, The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 833, 849 (1994). Like me, Alen thinks the costs of case-by-case calculations of the probability of enforcement "place this solution beyond the realm of realistic alternatives." Id.
  • 241
    • 36249024614 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A society of econometric superheroes could address imperfect verification of obstruction by adding to the generic first-order multiplier a generic obstruction multiplier. Damages for first-order breach would men be multiplied twice. The first multiplier would take account of the probability of enforcement of the first-order breach, given all that is known about the situation, while proof of obstruction would trigger a second multiplier, designed to account for the possibility that those obstructive tactics might have gone undetected or unproven. Mere mortals will find this a difficult solution. First, calculating the appropriate multiplier would be more complex than simply multiplying by the reciprocal of the probability that the obstructive behavior in question would go unverified. Such simple multipliers work only where nonverification results in no damage award. In a dynamic multiplier regime, no proof of obstructive behavior does not result in no award, but in an award that is too
    • A society of econometric superheroes could address imperfect verification of obstruction by adding to the generic first-order multiplier a generic obstruction multiplier. Damages for first-order breach would men be multiplied twice. The first multiplier would take account of the probability of enforcement of the first-order breach, given all that is known about the situation, while proof of obstruction would trigger a second multiplier, designed to account for the possibility that those obstructive tactics might have gone undetected or unproven. Mere mortals will find this a difficult solution. First, calculating the appropriate multiplier would be more complex than simply multiplying by the reciprocal of the probability that the obstructive behavior in question would go unverified. Such simple multipliers work only where nonverification results in no damage award. In a dynamic multiplier regime, no proof of obstructive behavior does not result in no award, but in an award that is too low. Second, the problem of quantification is even more intractable in the case of obstruction multipliers, which require the factfinder to evaluate the likelihood that bad behavior that is designed to be hidden but has been discovered and proven might not have been.
  • 242
    • 25144505223 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keith N. Hylton & Thomas J. Miceli, Should Tort Damages Be Multiplied?, 21 J.L. ECON. &ORG. 388, 403-11 (2005) (deriving generic multipliers from empirical studies of different categories of tort litigation).
    • See Keith N. Hylton & Thomas J. Miceli, Should Tort Damages Be Multiplied?, 21 J.L. ECON. &ORG. 388, 403-11 (2005) (deriving generic multipliers from empirical studies of different categories of tort litigation).
  • 243
    • 0032391326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shared Outrage and Erratic Awards: The Psychology of Punitive Damages, 16
    • See generally
    • See generally Daniel Kahneman et al, Shared Outrage and Erratic Awards: The Psychology of Punitive Damages, 16 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 49 (1998);
    • (1998) J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY , vol.49
    • Kahneman, D.1
  • 244
    • 0347574001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Assessing Punitive Damages (with Notes on Cognition and Valuation in Law), 107
    • Cass R Sunstein et al., Assessing Punitive Damages (with Notes on Cognition and Valuation in Law), 107 YALE L.J. 2071, 2111-12 (1998);
    • (1998) YALE L.J. 2071 , pp. 2111-2112
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 245
    • 0347662741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Social Costs of Punitive Damages Against Corporations in Environmental and Safety Torts, 87
    • W. Kip Viscusi, The Social Costs of Punitive Damages Against Corporations in Environmental and Safety Torts, 87 GEO. L.J. 285, 327-32 (1998).
    • (1998) GEO. L.J , vol.285 , pp. 327-332
    • Kip Viscusi, W.1
  • 246
    • 0347173865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see David Luban, A Flawed Case Against Punitive Damages, 87 GEO. L.J. 359, 369-70 (1998) (questioning Viscusi's analysis of juror biases).
    • But see David Luban, A Flawed Case Against Punitive Damages, 87 GEO. L.J. 359, 369-70 (1998) (questioning Viscusi's analysis of juror biases).
  • 247
    • 36248990049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 892
    • See Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 892.
  • 248
    • 36249002135 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Craswell, supra note 124, 664-65 (discussing risk aversion and the effect of multipliers on precaution decisions);
    • See Craswell, supra note 124, 664-65 (discussing risk aversion and the effect of multipliers on precaution decisions);
  • 249
    • 36248977988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 886-87 noting effect of riskaversion on optimal multipliers
    • Polinsky & Shavell, supra note 139, at 886-87 (noting effect of riskaversion on optimal multipliers).
  • 250
    • 36248954330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally MINORITY STAFF OF THE SPEC. INVESTIGATIONS DIV. OF THE H. COMM. ON GOV'T REFORM, HALLIBURTON'S PERFORMANCE UNDER THE RESTORE IRAQ. OIL 2 CONTRACT (2006).
    • See generally MINORITY STAFF OF THE SPEC. INVESTIGATIONS DIV. OF THE H. COMM. ON GOV'T REFORM, HALLIBURTON'S PERFORMANCE UNDER THE RESTORE IRAQ. OIL 2 CONTRACT (2006).
  • 251
    • 36248978530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13
    • Id. at 13.
  • 252
    • 36249016172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • James Glanz, Rebuilding of Iraqi Oil Pipeline as Disaster Waiting To Happen, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 25, 2006, at Ai. The Times quotes a senior Oil Ministry official, who said he began hearing rumors from Iraqis in the ministry in Baghdad that something had gone terribly wrong, but the company itself seemed determined not to clarify what had happened. 'We couldn't get a good status report,' Mr. Vogler said. 'We kept asking for it____We couldn't get one.' Id. The Army Corps of Engineers colonel in charge of the project told the Times that KBR provided him with optimistic assessments neariy to the end of the line ... and he was convinced that the project would be a success. Id.
    • James Glanz, Rebuilding of Iraqi Oil Pipeline as Disaster Waiting To Happen, N.Y. TIMES, Apr. 25, 2006, at Ai. The Times quotes a senior Oil Ministry official, who "said he began hearing rumors from Iraqis in the ministry in Baghdad that something had gone terribly wrong, but the company itself seemed determined not to clarify what had happened. 'We couldn't get a good status report,' Mr. Vogler said. 'We kept asking for it____We couldn't get one.'" Id. The Army Corps of Engineers colonel in charge of the project told the Times that "KBR provided him with optimistic assessments neariy to the end of the line ... and he was convinced that the project would be a success." Id.
  • 253
    • 84858465397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 2313a, c, 2007
    • 10 U.S.C. § 2313(a)-(c) (2007).
    • 10 U.S.C
  • 254
    • 84858470558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Section 2313 stipulates that it is not to be read to require government contractors to keep any records other than those they would otherwise maintain in the normal course of business. Id. § 2313(c)(3).
    • Section 2313 stipulates that it is not to be read to require government contractors to keep any records other than those they would otherwise maintain in the normal course of business. Id. § 2313(c)(3).
  • 255
    • 84858463821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • MINN. STAT. § 604.10(e) (2000);
    • MINN. STAT. § 604.10(e) (2000);
  • 256
    • 36249023540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Tourek et al, supra note 103, at 927-38 describing history of Minnesota statute
    • see also Tourek et al., supra note 103, at 927-38 (describing history of Minnesota statute).
  • 257
    • 0348137755 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Majoritarian vs. Minoritarian Defaults, 51
    • See generally
    • See generally Ian Ayres & Robert Gertner, Majoritarian vs. Minoritarian Defaults, 51 STAN. L. REV. 1591 (1999).
    • (1999) STAN. L. REV , vol.1591
    • Ayres, I.1    Gertner, R.2
  • 258
    • 36248940610 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., KIMEL, supra note 13, at 100-109 (arguing against specific performance remedy based on Mill's harm principle) ;
    • See, e.g., KIMEL, supra note 13, at 100-109 (arguing against specific performance remedy based on Mill's harm principle) ;
  • 259
    • 36248986051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ian R Macneil, supra note 60 (applying reliance theory to justify rule against penalty clauses);
    • Ian R Macneil, supra note 60 (applying reliance theory to justify rule against penalty clauses);
  • 260
    • 36248929221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ernest J. Weinrib, Punishment and Disgorgement as Contract Remedies, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 55, 84-102 (2003) (maintaining that principles of corrective justice argue against punitive damages for breach of contract).
    • Ernest J. Weinrib, Punishment and Disgorgement as Contract Remedies, 78 CHI.-KENT L. REV. 55, 84-102 (2003) (maintaining that principles of corrective justice argue against punitive damages for breach of contract).
  • 261
    • 0037228670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But see Curtis Bridgeman, Note, Corrective Justice in Contract Law: Is There a Case for Punitive Damages?, 56 VAND. L. REV. 237 (2003) (applying corrective justice considerations to argue for punitive damages in contract).
    • But see Curtis Bridgeman, Note, Corrective Justice in Contract Law: Is There a Case for Punitive Damages?, 56 VAND. L. REV. 237 (2003) (applying corrective justice considerations to argue for punitive damages in contract).
  • 262
    • 22744437696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Special mention should be made of Daniel Markovits's suggestion that punitive damages might be appropriate whenever a promisor refuses to pay the compensatory expectation damages that vindicating contractual collaboration requires. Daniel Markovits, Contract and Collaboration, 113 YALE L.J. 1417, 1510 (2004, What Markovits is describing here seems to be, in my terminology, a duty not to obstruct, perhaps akin to that created by Seaman's. But I believe that Markovits's argument entails that both the obligation and the remedy are mandatory, since both derive from the promisor's moral duty to treat the promisee as an end in herself. Cf. id. at 1505-08 arguing that the parties should not be allowed to contract for reliance or other sub-expectation damage measures
    • Special mention should be made of Daniel Markovits's suggestion that punitive damages might be appropriate whenever a promisor "refuses to pay the compensatory expectation damages that vindicating contractual collaboration requires." Daniel Markovits, Contract and Collaboration, 113 YALE L.J. 1417, 1510 (2004). What Markovits is describing here seems to be, in my terminology, a duty not to obstruct, perhaps akin to that created by Seaman's. But I believe that Markovits's argument entails that both the obligation and the remedy are mandatory, since both derive from the promisor's moral duty to treat the promisee as an end in herself. Cf. id. at 1505-08 (arguing that the parties should not be allowed to contract for reliance or other sub-expectation damage measures).
  • 263
    • 36248938516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I borrow this way of posing the question from Alan Klevorick: [T]he critical observation is that the explication of why some acts are crimes while others are not requires an inquiry into the legitimation of the transaction structure. It forces one to confront questions like: Why does the collectivity have the right to decide the terms on which particular transactions will take place under different circumstances? Why do some rights reside in the individual while others rest with the state? Alan Klevorick, The Economics of Crime, in 27 CRIMINAL JUSTICE: NOMOS 288, 303 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1985);
    • I borrow this way of posing the question from Alan Klevorick: [T]he critical observation is that the explication of why some acts are crimes while others are not requires an inquiry into the legitimation of the transaction structure. It forces one to confront questions like: Why does the collectivity have the right to decide the terms on which particular transactions will take place under different circumstances? Why do some rights reside in the individual while others rest with the state? Alan Klevorick, The Economics of Crime, in 27 CRIMINAL JUSTICE: NOMOS 288, 303 (J. Roland Pennock & John W. Chapman eds., 1985);
  • 264
    • 0041906857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Jules Coleman, Crimes and Transactions, 88 CAL. L. REV. 921, 924 (2000) ([S]omeone who violates the transaction structure has asserted an authority that he does not possess. The power to set the terms of legitimate transfer resides in the political sovereignty and not in ordinary folk. ).
    • see also Jules Coleman, Crimes and Transactions, 88 CAL. L. REV. 921, 924 (2000) ("[S]omeone who violates the transaction structure has asserted an authority that he does not possess. The power to set the terms of legitimate transfer resides in the political sovereignty and not in ordinary folk. ").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.