메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 80, Issue 2, 2007, Pages 229-257

Introduction: Understanding East Asian cross-regionalism: An analytical framework

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 36048999410     PISSN: 0030851X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.5509/2007802229     Document Type: Editorial
Times cited : (33)

References (90)
  • 1
    • 85036974833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this special issue, we adopt a pragmatic definition of region as a contiguous territorial area having sufficiently clear internal cohesion and definitive external boundaries, which matches the characterization by the World Bank and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) of East Asia as comprising Northeast and Southeast Asia, but excluding the United States, any of the Latin American countries, Australia, New Zealand, and the Pacific Island states. See T.J. Pempel, Introduction: Emerging Webs of Regional Connectedness, in T.J. Pempel, ed., Remapping East Asia: The Construction of a Region (Ithaca NY, Cornell University Press, 2005), p. 4.
    • In this special issue, we adopt a pragmatic definition of region as a "contiguous territorial area having sufficiently clear internal cohesion and definitive external boundaries," which matches the characterization by the World Bank and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) of East Asia as comprising Northeast and Southeast Asia, but excluding the United States, any of the Latin American countries, Australia, New Zealand, and the Pacific Island states. See T.J. Pempel, "Introduction: Emerging Webs of Regional Connectedness," in T.J. Pempel, ed., Remapping East Asia: The Construction of a Region (Ithaca NY, Cornell University Press, 2005), p. 4.
  • 2
    • 85036988214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The World Trade Organization's (WTO) own nomenclature also has obscured, rather than clarified, the importance of cross-regionalism by loosely using the term Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) to cover all preferential trade deals within and beyond regions. To avoid such confusion, we make an explicit distinction between regional (RTAs) and cross-regional trade agreements (CRTAs). Whenever we refer to preferential trade agreements in general we use the neutral term FTA (or free trade agreement).
    • The World Trade Organization's (WTO) own nomenclature also has obscured, rather than clarified, the importance of cross-regionalism by loosely using the term "Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs)" to cover all preferential trade deals within and beyond regions. To avoid such confusion, we make an explicit distinction between regional (RTAs) and cross-regional trade agreements (CRTAs). Whenever we refer to preferential trade agreements in general we use the neutral term FTA (or free trade agreement).
  • 3
    • 0033423274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Wave of Regionalism
    • Edward Mansfield and Helen Milner, "The New Wave of Regionalism, International Organzation, vol. 53, no. 3 (1999), pp. 590-91.
    • (1999) International Organzation , vol.53 , Issue.3 , pp. 590-591
    • Mansfield, E.1    Milner, H.2
  • 4
    • 85036992857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The one exception is the United States-Israel FTA which preceded the North American Free Trade Agreement NAFTA, However, Israel has always been a key strategic priority for the United States deserving special treatment, and in all other instances CRTAs for Europe and North America came after their main regional blocs were firmly in place
    • The one exception is the United States-Israel FTA which preceded the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). However, Israel has always been a key strategic priority for the United States deserving special treatment, and in all other instances CRTAs for Europe and North America came after their main regional blocs were firmly in place.
  • 5
    • 85036998172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this way we offer an explanation of cross-regionalism that is distinct from the oft-noted motivations behind the selection of cross-regional partners: special security relations (US-Israel, former colonial ties (EU-South Africa, and natural resource diplomacy Japan and Gulf states, in negotiation
    • In this way we offer an explanation of cross-regionalism that is distinct from the oft-noted motivations behind the selection of cross-regional partners: special security relations (US-Israel), former colonial ties (EU-South Africa), and natural resource diplomacy (Japan and Gulf states, in negotiation).
  • 6
    • 33646023465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more detailed discussion of the reasons behind the proliferation of FTAs, see, WTO Discussion Paper no. 8 World Trade Organization, Geneva, Switzerland
    • For a more detailed discussion of the reasons behind the proliferation of FTAs, see Jo-Ann Crawford and Roberto V. Fiorentino, "The Changing Landscape of Regional Trade Agreements," WTO Discussion Paper no. 8 (World Trade Organization, Geneva, Switzerland, 2005), p. 16.
    • (2005) The Changing Landscape of Regional Trade Agreements , pp. 16
    • Crawford, J.1    Fiorentino, R.V.2
  • 7
    • 85036964536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Scholars have explained this shortage of formal institutions in Asia in various ways ranging from relative disparity shift hypothesis (Grieco, network replacing institutions (Katzenstein and Shirashi, domestic preferences of regional powers (Haggard, the region's external reliance especially on the United States (Crone, to historical US lack of interest in regional mechanisms in Asia (Katzenstein and Hemmer, See Joseph Grieco, Systemic Sources of Variation in Regional Institutionalization in Western Europe, East Asia, and the Americas, in Edward D. Mansfield and Helen V. Milner, eds, The Political Economy of Regionalism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997);
    • Scholars have explained this shortage of formal institutions in Asia in various ways ranging from relative disparity shift hypothesis (Grieco); network replacing institutions (Katzenstein and Shirashi); domestic preferences of regional powers (Haggard); the region's external reliance especially on the United States (Crone); to historical US lack of interest in regional mechanisms in Asia (Katzenstein and Hemmer). See Joseph Grieco, "Systemic Sources of Variation in Regional Institutionalization in Western Europe, East Asia, and the Americas," in Edward D. Mansfield and Helen V. Milner, eds., The Political Economy of Regionalism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1997);
  • 8
    • 0003531097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peter Katzenstein and Takashi Shiraishi, eds, Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press
    • Peter Katzenstein and Takashi Shiraishi, eds., Network Power: Japan and Asia (Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press, 1997);
    • (1997) Network Power: Japan and Asia
  • 9
    • 0002823042 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regionalism in Asia and the Americas
    • Mansfield and Milner, eds
    • Stephan Haggard, "Regionalism in Asia and the Americas," in Mansfield and Milner, eds., The Political Economy of Regionalism;
    • The Political Economy of Regionalism
    • Haggard, S.1
  • 10
    • 0027832524 scopus 로고
    • Does Hegemony Matter?: The Reorganization of the Pacific Political Economy
    • Donald Crone, "Does Hegemony Matter?: The Reorganization of the Pacific Political Economy," World Politics, vol. 45 (1994), pp. 501-25;
    • (1994) World Politics , vol.45 , pp. 501-525
    • Crone, D.1
  • 11
    • 0036341160 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why is There No NATO in Asia? Comparative Identity, Regionalism, and the Origin of Multilateralism
    • and Peter Katzenstein and Christopher Hemmer, "Why is There No NATO in Asia? Comparative Identity, Regionalism, and the Origin of Multilateralism," International Organization, vol. 56, no. 3 (2002), pp. 575-607.
    • (2002) International Organization , vol.56 , Issue.3 , pp. 575-607
    • Katzenstein, P.1    Hemmer, C.2
  • 12
    • 85057668927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington DC: The Brookings Institution
    • Edward Lincoln, East Asian Economic Regionalism (Washington DC: The Brookings Institution, 2004), pp. 169-73.
    • (2004) East Asian Economic Regionalism , pp. 169-173
    • Lincoln, E.1
  • 13
    • 0034534411 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regionalism and Development after the Global Financial Crises
    • For example
    • For example, Paul Bowles, "Regionalism and Development after the Global Financial Crises," New Political Economy, vol. 5, no. 3 (2000), pp. 433-55;
    • (2000) New Political Economy , vol.5 , Issue.3 , pp. 433-455
    • Bowles, P.1
  • 14
    • 84937321603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Asian Crisis and the Adequacy of Regional Institutions
    • Michael Wesley, "The Asian Crisis and the Adequacy of Regional Institutions," Contemporary Southeast Asia, vol. 21, no. 1 (1999), pp. 54-73;
    • (1999) Contemporary Southeast Asia , vol.21 , Issue.1 , pp. 54-73
    • Wesley, M.1
  • 15
    • 0034381435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Japanese Policy and the East Asian Currency Crisis: Abject Defeat or Quiet Victory?
    • and Christopher W. Hughes, "Japanese Policy and the East Asian Currency Crisis: Abject Defeat or Quiet Victory?" Review of International Political Economy, vol. 7, no. 2 (2000), pp. 219-53.
    • (2000) Review of International Political Economy , vol.7 , Issue.2 , pp. 219-253
    • Hughes, C.W.1
  • 16
    • 0031447598 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The most prominent theoretical work on the domino theory of regionalism is by Richard E. Baldwin, The Causes of Regionalism, The World Economy, 20, no. 7 (1997), pp. 865-88.
    • The most prominent theoretical work on the "domino theory of regionalism" is by Richard E. Baldwin, "The Causes of Regionalism," The World Economy, vol. 20, no. 7 (1997), pp. 865-88.
  • 18
    • 85036991676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although Europe has had preferential economic relations with former colonies through the Yaoundé and Lomé Conventions, these were not structured around FTAs, but rather entailed non-reciprocal trade concessions, aid and political dialogue. Ravenhill offers an excellent analysis of the reasons why the EU pushed for the negotiation of FTAs with African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries in the late 1990s. See John. Ravenhill, Back to the Nest? Europe's Relations with the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of Countries, in Vinod K. Aggarwal and Edward A. Fogarty, eds, EU Trade Strategies. Between Regionalism and Globalism New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2004
    • Although Europe has had preferential economic relations with former colonies through the Yaoundé and Lomé Conventions, these were not structured around FTAs, but rather entailed non-reciprocal trade concessions, aid and political dialogue. Ravenhill offers an excellent analysis of the reasons why the EU pushed for the negotiation of FTAs with African, Caribbean and Pacific (ACP) countries in the late 1990s. See John. Ravenhill, "Back to the Nest? Europe's Relations with the African, Caribbean and Pacific Group of Countries," in Vinod K. Aggarwal and Edward A. Fogarty, eds., EU Trade Strategies. Between Regionalism and Globalism (New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2004).
  • 19
    • 15044339047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Wave of Regionalism
    • See especially
    • See especially Mansfield and Milner, "The New Wave of Regionalism."
    • Mansfield1    Milner2
  • 20
    • 23744517120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beyond Network Power? The Dynamics of Formal Economic Integration in Northeast Asia
    • Vinod K Aggarwal and Min Gyo Koo, "Beyond Network Power? "The Dynamics of Formal Economic Integration in Northeast Asia," The Pacific Review, vol. 18, no. 2 (2005), pp. 189-216.
    • (2005) The Pacific Review , vol.18 , Issue.2 , pp. 189-216
    • Aggarwal, V.K.1    Gyo Koo, M.2
  • 21
    • 85036977012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Aggarwal and Koo's own words: pair of countries are geographically concentrated, if they are contiguous on land or within 400 nautical miles; otherwise, we view them as being geographically dispersed Beyond Network Power, p. 196
    • In Aggarwal and Koo's own words: "pair of countries are geographically concentrated, if they are contiguous on land or within 400 nautical miles; otherwise, we view them as being geographically dispersed" ("Beyond Network Power," p. 196).
  • 22
    • 33745575873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Between Regionalism and Globalism: European Union Interregional Trade Strategies
    • Aggarwal and Fogarty, eds
    • Vinod K. Aggarwal and Edward A. Fogarty, "Between Regionalism and Globalism: European Union Interregional Trade Strategies," in Aggarwal and Fogarty, eds., EU Trade Strategies: Between Regionalism and Globalism.
    • EU Trade Strategies: Between Regionalism and Globalism
    • Aggarwal, V.K.1    Fogarty, E.A.2
  • 23
    • 48949110882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Interregionalism: A New Phenomenon in International Relations
    • Heiner Hänggi, Ralf Roloff and Jürgen Rüland, eds, London: Routledge
    • Heiner Hänggi, Ralf Roloff and Jürgen Rüland, "Interregionalism: A New Phenomenon in International Relations," in Heiner Hänggi, Ralf Roloff and Jürgen Rüland, eds., Interregionalism and International Relations, (London: Routledge, 2006).
    • (2006) Interregionalism and International Relations
    • Hänggi, H.1    Roloff, R.2    Rüland, J.3
  • 24
    • 0002094185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is There a Case for Free Trade Areas?
    • See, Jeffrey J. Schott, ed, Washington DC: Institute for International Economics
    • See Paul Wormacott and Mark Lutz, "Is There a Case for Free Trade Areas?" in Jeffrey J. Schott, ed., Free Trade Areas and US Trade Policy (Washington DC: Institute for International Economics, 1989);
    • (1989) Free Trade Areas and US Trade Policy
    • Wormacott, P.1    Lutz, M.2
  • 25
    • 85036993400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Larry Summers, Regionalism and the World Trade System, Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Policy Implications of Trade and Curremy Zones, 1991;
    • Larry Summers, "Regionalism and the World Trade System," Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Policy Implications of Trade and Curremy Zones, 1991;
  • 26
    • 85036979472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paul Krugman, The Move to Free Trade Zones, Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Policy Implications of Trade and Currency Zones, 1991;
    • Paul Krugman, "The Move to Free Trade Zones," Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Policy Implications of Trade and Currency Zones, 1991;
  • 27
    • 0001829341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preferential Trading Areas and Multilateralism-Strangers, Friends, or Foes?
    • Jagdish Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya, eds, Washington DC: AEI Press
    • Jagdish Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya, "Preferential Trading Areas and Multilateralism-Strangers, Friends, or Foes?" in Jagdish Bhagwati and Arvind Panagariya, eds., The Economics of Preferential Trade Agreements (Washington DC: AEI Press, 1996).
    • (1996) The Economics of Preferential Trade Agreements
    • Bhagwati, J.1    Panagariya, A.2
  • 29
    • 36048949394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, see, World Bank, Development Research Department
    • For example, see Maurice Schiff, "Will the Real "Natural Trading Partner" Please Stand Up?" World Bank, Development Research Department, 1999.
    • (1999) Will the Real Natural Trading Partner
    • Schiff, M.1
  • 30
    • 85036967829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • APEC best exemplifies the notion of open regiongism - that is, a negotiated trade liberalization effort whose benefits are always extended to non-APEC members on the basis of most favoured nation status.
    • APEC best exemplifies the notion of "open regiongism" - that is, a negotiated trade liberalization effort whose benefits are always extended to non-APEC members on the basis of most favoured nation status.
  • 31
    • 10944233206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Embedded Mercantilism and Open Regionalism: The Crisis of a Regional Political Project
    • Kanishka Jayasuriya, "Embedded Mercantilism and Open Regionalism: The Crisis of a Regional Political Project," Third World Quarterly, vol. 24, no. 2 (2003), pp. 339-41.
    • (2003) Third World Quarterly , vol.24 , Issue.2 , pp. 339-341
    • Jayasuriya, K.1
  • 33
    • 22144481858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • At the time of writing (probably either late 2002 or early 2003, he remained skeptical about the conclusion of both the Japan-Mexico or South Korea-Chile agreements, for both Japan and South Korea remained fairly resistant to the idea of liberalizing their respective agriculture sectors. See John Ravenhill, The New Bilateralism, in the Asia Pacific, Third World Quarterly, 24, no. 2 2003, p. 314 and footnote 29
    • At the time of writing (probably either late 2002 or early 2003), he remained skeptical about the conclusion of both the Japan-Mexico or South Korea-Chile agreements, for both Japan and South Korea remained fairly resistant to the idea of liberalizing their respective agriculture sectors. See John Ravenhill, "The New Bilateralism, in the Asia Pacific," Third World Quarterly, vol. 24, no. 2 (2003), p. 314 and footnote 29.
  • 34
    • 0037227519 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Networking the Region? The Emergence and Impact of Asia-Pacific Bilateral Free Trade Agreement Projects
    • Christopher M. Dent, "Networking the Region? The Emergence and Impact of Asia-Pacific Bilateral Free Trade Agreement Projects," The Pacific Review, vol. 16, no. 1 (2003), pp. 1-28.
    • (2003) The Pacific Review , vol.16 , Issue.1 , pp. 1-28
    • Dent, C.M.1
  • 36
    • 33745549885 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Japan's New Regionalism; The Politics of Free Trade Talks with Mexico
    • Mireya Solís, "Japan's New Regionalism; The Politics of Free Trade Talks with Mexico," Journal of East Asian Studies, vol. 3 no. 3 (2003), pp. 377-404.
    • (2003) Journal of East Asian Studies , vol.3 , Issue.3 , pp. 377-404
    • Solís, M.1
  • 37
    • 29144467682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition and Bilateralism in Trade Policy: The Case of Japan's Free Trade Agreements
    • Mark Manger, "Competition and Bilateralism in Trade Policy: The Case of Japan's Free Trade Agreements," Review of International Political Economy, vol. 12, no.5 (2005), pp. 804-28.
    • (2005) Review of International Political Economy , vol.12 , Issue.5 , pp. 804-828
    • Manger, M.1
  • 38
    • 85036983893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From Multilateralism to Bilateralism? A Shift in South Korea's Trade Strategy
    • Aggarwal and Urata, eds
    • Min Gyo Koo, "From Multilateralism to Bilateralism? A Shift in South Korea's Trade Strategy," in Aggarwal and Urata, eds., Bilateral Trade Arrangements in the Asia-Pacific.
    • Bilateral Trade Arrangements in the Asia-Pacific
    • Gyo Koo, M.1
  • 39
    • 33745239798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Research Notes: US-Singapore Free Trade Agreement: Implications for ASEAN
    • Jose L. Tongzon, "Research Notes: US-Singapore Free Trade Agreement: Implications for ASEAN," ASEAN Economic Bulletin, vol. 20, no. 2 (2003), pp. 174-78.
    • (2003) ASEAN Economic Bulletin , vol.20 , Issue.2 , pp. 174-178
    • Tongzon, J.L.1
  • 40
    • 16244408319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This group of fifteen East Asian economies includes ASEAN, Japan, Korea, China, Taiwan and Hong Kong. Figures are taken from Masahiro Kawai, East Asian Economic Regionalism: Progress and Challenges, Journal of Asian Economics, 16 2005, p. 32
    • This group of fifteen East Asian economies includes ASEAN, Japan, Korea, China, Taiwan and Hong Kong. Figures are taken from Masahiro Kawai, "East Asian Economic Regionalism: Progress and Challenges," Journal of Asian Economics, vol. 16 (2005), p. 32.
  • 41
    • 85036961123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The index value for East Asia is 2.2, while it is 2.5 for NAFTA and 1.7 for Europe; see Kawai, East Asian Economic Regionalism, p. 32. The intra-regional trade intensity index takes into account the weight of a region in the overall world economy to avoid overestimating the importance of intra-regional trade for regions that are registering above-average growth. See Lincoln, East Asian Economic Regionalism.
    • The index value for East Asia is 2.2, while it is 2.5 for NAFTA and 1.7 for Europe; see Kawai, "East Asian Economic Regionalism," p. 32. The intra-regional trade intensity index takes into account the weight of a region in the overall world economy to avoid overestimating the importance of intra-regional trade for regions that are registering above-average growth. See Lincoln, East Asian Economic Regionalism.
  • 46
    • 85036991957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All figures from Kawai, East Asian Economic Regionalism, pp. 32-33.
    • All figures from Kawai, "East Asian Economic Regionalism," pp. 32-33.
  • 49
    • 36048988523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Has Politics Caught up with Markets? In Search ofEast Asian Economic Regionalism
    • See, Peter J. Katztenstein and Takashi Shiraishi. eds, Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press
    • See Naoko Munakata, "Has Politics Caught up with Markets? In Search ofEast Asian Economic Regionalism," in Peter J. Katztenstein and Takashi Shiraishi. eds., Beyond Japan: The Dynamics of East Asian Regionalism (Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press. 2006).
    • (2006) Beyond Japan: The Dynamics of East Asian Regionalism
    • Munakata, N.1
  • 50
    • 85036975435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, as we will elaborate later on in this and the subsequent articles in this the objective of securing preferential access with key extra-regional economic partners is by no means the most important rationale behind many cases of East Asian cross-regionalism. Rather, more defensive economic reasons (counter trade diversion) or security ang leverage motives frequently guide the selection of cross-regional partners at this early stage in East Asia's FTA diplomacy.
    • However, as we will elaborate later on in this and the subsequent articles in this volume, the objective of securing preferential access with key extra-regional economic partners is by no means the most important rationale behind many cases of East Asian cross-regionalism. Rather, more defensive economic reasons (counter trade diversion) or security ang leverage motives frequently guide the selection of cross-regional partners at this early stage in East Asia's FTA diplomacy.
  • 52
    • 33645206743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regionalism and Critical Junctures: Explaining the 'Organization Gap' in Northeast Asia
    • Kent Calder and Min Ye, "Regionalism and Critical Junctures: Explaining the 'Organization Gap' in Northeast Asia." Journal of East Asian Studies, vol. 4 (2004), pp. 204-08.
    • (2004) Journal of East Asian Studies , vol.4 , pp. 204-208
    • Calder, K.1    Ye, M.2
  • 54
    • 0003225010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Major-Power Trade Flows
    • Mansfield and Milner, eds
    • and Edward D. Mansfield and Rachel Bronson, "The Political Economy of Major-Power Trade Flows," in Mansfield and Milner, eds., The Political Economy of Regionalism.
    • The Political Economy of Regionalism
    • Mansfield, E.D.1    Bronson, R.2
  • 57
  • 58
    • 0033730551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Japan, the US, and the Emergence of Multilateralism in Asia
    • Ellis Krauss, "Japan, the US, and the Emergence of Multilateralism in Asia," The Pacific Review, vol. 13, no. 3 (2000), pp. 473-94.
    • (2000) The Pacific Review , vol.13 , Issue.3 , pp. 473-494
    • Krauss, E.1
  • 59
    • 85036983264 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Saori N. Katada, Banking on Stability: Cross-Pacific Dynamics of International Financial Crisis Management (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2001). The one important exception was China, which opposed the AMF. Bowles notes that the Chinese opposed the idea because they feared this initiative would enhance Japan's leadership position in the region, while Amyx notes that the Japanese government, going through the Hong Kong Monetary Authority first, made it harder for the Chinese authorities to reach a decision.
    • See Saori N. Katada, Banking on Stability: Cross-Pacific Dynamics of International Financial Crisis Management (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2001). The one important exception was China, which opposed the AMF. Bowles notes that the Chinese opposed the idea because they feared this initiative would enhance Japan's leadership position in the region, while Amyx notes that the Japanese government, going through the Hong Kong Monetary Authority first, made it harder for the Chinese authorities to reach a decision.
  • 60
    • 84991327600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Asia's Post-Crisis Regionalism: Bringing the State Back In, Keeping the (United) States Out
    • Paul Bowles, "Asia's Post-Crisis Regionalism: Bringing the State Back In, Keeping the (United) States Out," Review of International Political Economy, vol. 9, no. 2 (2002), pp. 255-56;
    • (2002) Review of International Political Economy , vol.9 , Issue.2 , pp. 255-256
    • Bowles, P.1
  • 61
    • 15944416440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What Motivates Regional Financial Cooperation in East Asia Today?
    • February
    • Jennifer Amyx, "What Motivates Regional Financial Cooperation in East Asia Today?" Asia Pacific Issues, no. 76 (February 2005), pp.2-3.
    • (2005) Asia Pacific Issues , Issue.76 , pp. 2-3
    • Amyx, J.1
  • 62
    • 85036973069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The United States has not reacted strongly against its exclusion from the East Asia Summit held in Kuala Lumpur because it remains skeptical it can yield an inclusive regional block given the open disagreements between China and Japan over the future evolution of this forum
    • The United States has not reacted strongly against its exclusion from the East Asia Summit held in Kuala Lumpur because it remains skeptical it can yield an inclusive regional block given the open disagreements between China and Japan over the future evolution of this forum.
  • 65
    • 85036973127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The factors that have led to the souring of the Sino-Japan bilateral relations are many, including the phasing out of Japanese official development assistance (ODA) loans, a bilateral trade imbalance and occasional trade wars, the exploitation of gas reserves on the East China Sea, pending territorial disputes, the Japanese bid for a permanent seat at the UN Security Council, controversy over the official visits in Japan to the Yasukuni shrine, approval of history books that downplay wartime atrocities and the anti-Japanese riots in China
    • The factors that have led to the souring of the Sino-Japan bilateral relations are many, including the phasing out of Japanese official development assistance (ODA) loans, a bilateral trade imbalance and occasional trade wars, the exploitation of gas reserves on the East China Sea, pending territorial disputes, the Japanese bid for a permanent seat at the UN Security Council, controversy over the official visits in Japan to the Yasukuni shrine, approval of history books that downplay wartime atrocities and the anti-Japanese riots in China.
  • 67
    • 85036981876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ernst Haas, Beyond the Nation-State (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1964). Although economic objectives (managing growing interdependence) are of central importance in explaining the demand for regional integration, neofunctionalism is essentially a political explanation in that it explains how the lobbying activities of interest groups to establish supranational institutions that erode state autonomy will move forward the integration process. We thank an anonymous reviewer for pressing us to clarify this important point.
    • Ernst Haas, Beyond the Nation-State (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1964). Although economic objectives (managing growing interdependence) are of central importance in explaining the demand for regional integration, neofunctionalism is essentially a political explanation in that it explains how the lobbying activities of interest groups to establish supranational institutions that erode state autonomy will move forward the integration process. We thank an anonymous reviewer for pressing us to clarify this important point.
  • 69
    • 0000358277 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trading Preferentially: Theory and Policy
    • See
    • See Jagdish Bhagwatti, David Greenaway and Arvind Panagariya, "Trading Preferentially: Theory and Policy," The Economic Journal, vol. 108 (1998), pp. 1128-48.
    • (1998) The Economic Journal , vol.108 , pp. 1128-1148
    • Bhagwatti, J.1    Greenaway, D.2    Panagariya, A.3
  • 70
    • 0029526355 scopus 로고
    • The Politics of Free-Trade Agreements
    • See
    • See Gene M. Grossman and Elhanan Helpman, "The Politics of Free-Trade Agreements," The American Economic Review, vol. 85, no. 4 (1995), pp. 667-90.
    • (1995) The American Economic Review , vol.85 , Issue.4 , pp. 667-690
    • Grossman, G.M.1    Helpman, E.2
  • 71
    • 85036994253 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fact, preferential rules of origin are now considered one of the most pernicious elements of FTAs in that they provide an effective and hidden form of protection for bloc producers. We thank Steph Haggard for pointing this out to us. Some of the best works on rules of origin are by Anne O. Krueger, Free Trade Agreements as Protectionist Devices: Rules of Origin. Working Paper no. 4352 (Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1993);
    • In fact, preferential rules of origin are now considered one of the most pernicious elements of FTAs in that they provide an effective and hidden form of protection for bloc producers. We thank Steph Haggard for pointing this out to us. Some of the best works on rules of origin are by Anne O. Krueger, "Free Trade Agreements as Protectionist Devices: Rules of Origin." Working Paper no. 4352 (Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1993);
  • 72
    • 31344475153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules of Origin in Preferential Trading Arrangements: Is All Well with the Spaghetti Bowl in the Americas?
    • and Antoni Estevadeordal and Kati Suominen, "Rules of Origin in Preferential Trading Arrangements: Is All Well with the Spaghetti Bowl in the Americas?" Economia (2005), pp. 63-103.
    • (2005) Economia , pp. 63-103
    • Estevadeordal, A.1    Suominen, K.2
  • 76
    • 85197681182 scopus 로고
    • Perhaps one of the most compelling accounts of such practice remains Hirschman's study of Nazi Germany's use of economic diplomacy to create webs of asymmetrical dependence to increase its power among neighbours. See, Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Perhaps one of the most compelling accounts of such practice remains Hirschman's study of Nazi Germany's use of economic diplomacy to create webs of asymmetrical dependence to increase its power among neighbours. See Albert O. Hirschman, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1980).
    • (1980) National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade
    • Hirschman, A.O.1
  • 77
    • 85036993401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Mansfield and Milner, The New Wave of Regionalism;
    • See Mansfield and Milner, "The New Wave of Regionalism";
  • 78
    • 36048973659 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Logic of Regional Integration; World Bank
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • Mattli, The Logic of Regional Integration; World Bank, Trade Blocs (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000);
    • (2000) Trade Blocs
    • Mattli1
  • 81
    • 24944538323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • China's 'Peaceful Rise' to Great-Power Status
    • Zheng Bijian, "China's 'Peaceful Rise' to Great-Power Status," Foreign Affairs, vol. 84, no. 5 (2005), pp. 18-24.
    • (2005) Foreign Affairs , vol.84 , Issue.5 , pp. 18-24
    • Bijian, Z.1
  • 82
    • 85036996456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chinese, Trade Bilateralism: Politics still in command
    • Aggarwal and Urata, eds
    • Elaine S. Kwei, "Chinese, Trade Bilateralism: Politics still in command," in Aggarwal and Urata, eds., Bilateral Trade Arrangements in the Asia-Pacific, p. 133.
    • Bilateral Trade Arrangements in the Asia-Pacific , pp. 133
    • Kwei, E.S.1
  • 83
    • 0042532102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • And Wong and Chan point to lack of complementarities in trade structures between China and ASEAN; see John Wong and Sarah Chan, China-ASEAN Free Trade Agreement: Shaping Future Economic Relations, Asian Survey, 43, no. 3 2003, pp. 516-23
    • And Wong and Chan point to lack of complementarities in trade structures between China and ASEAN; see John Wong and Sarah Chan, "China-ASEAN Free Trade Agreement: Shaping Future Economic Relations," Asian Survey, vol. 43, no. 3 (2003), pp. 516-23.
  • 84
    • 0004115169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • World Bank
    • World Bank, Trade Blocs, p. 19.
    • Trade Blocs , pp. 19
  • 85
    • 0141994438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Spaghetti Regionalism or Strategic Foreign Trade: Some Evidence for Mexico
    • Alejandro Ibarra-Yunez, "Spaghetti Regionalism or Strategic Foreign Trade: Some Evidence for Mexico," Journal of Development Economics, vol. 72 (2003), pp. 567-84.
    • (2003) Journal of Development Economics , vol.72 , pp. 567-584
    • Ibarra-Yunez, A.1
  • 87
    • 85036982542 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aggarwal and Koo make exactly the same argument when they note that Korea selected Chile as its first FTA partner with the explicit goal of capacity building for a more expansive discussion of this issue see the article by Park and Koo in this See Aggarwal and Koo, Beyond Network Power, p. 7.
    • Aggarwal and Koo make exactly the same argument when they note that Korea selected Chile as its first FTA partner with the explicit goal of capacity building (for a more expansive discussion of this issue see the article by Park and Koo in this volume). See Aggarwal and Koo, "Beyond Network Power," p. 7.
  • 88
    • 34248249473 scopus 로고
    • Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmental Approach
    • Andrew Moravcsik, "Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmental Approach," Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 31, no. 4 (1993), pp. 473-524.
    • (1993) Journal of Common Market Studies , vol.31 , Issue.4 , pp. 473-524
    • Moravcsik, A.1
  • 90
    • 85036958759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The same reservation applies to the efforts of Thailand and Korea noted above to position themselves as trade hubs: access to their FTA network is contingent on the compliance with different rules of origin
    • The same reservation applies to the efforts of Thailand and Korea noted above to position themselves as trade hubs: access to their FTA network is contingent on the compliance with different rules of origin.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.