메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 9, Issue 1, 1996, Pages 95-106

The myth of the income effect

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 34249755675     PISSN: 08893047     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1007/bf01101883     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (8)

References (9)
  • 1
    • 53349091963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I thank Philippe Lacoude and Frédéric Sautet for their very pertinent comments on a previous version of this paper, the idea of which actually stemmed from a talk with them.
  • 2
    • 53349108997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The increase in a tax rate decreases the tax base and, beyond a certain tax rate, this effect is sufficiently important for the increase in the tax rate to induce a decrease in tax revenues instead of an increase. It is now usual to label this process as the "Laffer-effect." But it had been developed before Arthur Laffer gave it its popular expression. One can find it, for instance, in a refined form, in Geoffrey Brennan and James Buchanan, The Power to Tax (Cambridge University Press, 1980).
  • 3
    • 53349151325 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hans-Hermann Hoppe raised an interesting question on a previous version of this paper: If the income effect does not exist, does it imply that a supply curve cannot be backward sloping? We explain in the appendix why, in our opinion, it is impossible.
  • 4
    • 0004211588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • But a similar graph can be found in most microeconomics textbooks
    • Figure 1 is extracted from the classic textbook by James M. Henderson and Richard E. Quandt, Microeconomic Theory. But a similar graph can be found in most microeconomics textbooks.
    • Microeconomic Theory
    • Henderson, J.M.1    Quandt, R.E.2
  • 5
    • 53349120548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Let us use this traditional concept, although it induces the danger of splitting a human being into different, non-coordinated, parts (the consumer, the producer, the taxpayer, etc.).
  • 6
    • 53349175058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As an example, one may imagine that the budget constraint is rotating around point R.
  • 7
    • 53349160523 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Both interpretations are very close to one another. They imply that, from a given stock of resources-for instance time resources-an individual can obtain a good either via a technological process of transformation he is doing by himself, or via a process of exchange involving his labor services or the outcome of his labor.
  • 8
    • 53349091964 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There is always a certain degree of specificity in the employment of a worker. For instance, as transaction costs do exist, an employer will prefer paying more for extra hours by a worker who is already employed in his firm than hiring an additional worker.
  • 9
    • 53349099452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If B was not preferred to A, it would just mean that the supply curve cannot go through B.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.