메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 37, Issue 2, 2007, Pages 281-312

Bicameral conflict resolution in the European Union: An empirical analysis of conciliation committee bargains

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33947685965     PISSN: 00071234     EISSN: 14692112     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0007123407000142     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (69)

References (90)
  • 1
    • 0000388293 scopus 로고
    • Bicameralism: When Are Two Decisions Better than One?
    • 145-62, p
    • Saul Levmore, 'Bicameralism: When Are Two Decisions Better than One?' International Review of Law and Economics, 12 (1992), 145-62, p. 150.
    • (1992) International Review of Law and Economics , vol.12 , pp. 150
    • Levmore, S.1
  • 3
    • 85055299528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Role of the European Commission in Co-decision - A Strategic Facilitator Operating in a Situation of Structural Disadvantage
    • Anne Rasmussen, 'The Role of the European Commission in Co-decision - A Strategic Facilitator Operating in a Situation of Structural Disadvantage', European Integration Online Papers, 7 (2003), http://eiop.or.at/eiop/ texte/2003-010a.htm.
    • (2003) European Integration Online Papers , vol.7
    • Rasmussen, A.1
  • 4
    • 0040357449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Although the Commission has the sole right to initiate legislation, it has no gatekeeping power (Heiner Schulz and Thomas König, Institutional Reform and Decision-Making Efficiency in the European Union, American Journal of Political Science, 44 2000, 653-66
    • Although the Commission has the sole right to initiate legislation, it has no gatekeeping power (Heiner Schulz and Thomas König, 'Institutional Reform and Decision-Making Efficiency in the European Union', American Journal of Political Science, 44 (2000), 653-66).
  • 8
    • 84996242683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative Politics in the European Union
    • 9-36, p
    • George Tsebelis and Geoffrey Garrett, 'Legislative Politics in the European Union', European Union Politics, 1 (2000), 9-36, p. 25;
    • (2000) European Union Politics , vol.1 , pp. 25
    • Tsebelis, G.1    Garrett, G.2
  • 9
    • 84972202504 scopus 로고
    • The Politics of Legal Integration in the European Union
    • Geoffrey Garrett, "The Politics of Legal Integration in the European Union', International Organization, 49 (1995), 171-81.
    • (1995) International Organization , vol.49 , pp. 171-181
    • Garrett, G.1
  • 10
    • 0011834886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Co-decision Procedure in the European Union
    • Christophe Crombez, 'The Co-decision Procedure in the European Union', Legislative Studies Quarterly, 22 (1997), 97-119;
    • (1997) Legislative Studies Quarterly , vol.22 , pp. 97-119
    • Crombez, C.1
  • 11
    • 21244445320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Treaty of Amsterdam and the Codecision Procedure
    • Mark Aspinwall and Gerald Schneider, eds, Manchester: University of Manchester Press
    • Christophe Crombez, 'The Treaty of Amsterdam and the Codecision Procedure', in Mark Aspinwall and Gerald Schneider, eds, The Rules of Integration (Manchester: University of Manchester Press, 2000), pp. 101-22.
    • (2000) The Rules of Integration , pp. 101-122
    • Crombez, C.1
  • 13
    • 3843074524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Codecision and Its Reform: A Comparative Analysis of Decision-making Rules in the European Union
    • Bernard Steunenberg and Frans van Vught, eds, Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers
    • Bernhard Steunenberg, 'Codecision and Its Reform: A Comparative Analysis of Decision-making Rules in the European Union', in Bernard Steunenberg and Frans van Vught, eds, Political Institutions and Public Policy: Perspectives on the European Decision-Making (Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1997), pp. 205-29.
    • (1997) Political Institutions and Public Policy: Perspectives on the European Decision-Making , pp. 205-229
    • Steunenberg, B.1
  • 15
    • 33947682622 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are some empirical studies on how many parliamentary amendments survive conciliation, whether these amendments are important, and what the chances are of the European Parliament enjoying such success (Amie Kreppel, The European Parliament and Supranational Party System: A Study in Institutional Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)).
    • There are some empirical studies on how many parliamentary amendments survive conciliation, whether these amendments are important, and what the chances are of the European Parliament enjoying such success (Amie Kreppel, The European Parliament and Supranational Party System: A Study in Institutional Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)).
  • 16
    • 33947645243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Amsterdam Treaty established a modified version of the co-decision procedure, in which conciliation is possible. Other procedures of EU decision making, such as the consultation and the co-operation procedure, do not provide for a conciliation process
    • The Amsterdam Treaty established a modified version of the co-decision procedure, in which conciliation is possible. Other procedures of EU decision making, such as the consultation and the co-operation procedure, do not provide for a conciliation process.
  • 19
    • 84928284665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Thomson, Frans N. Stokman, Christopher H. Achen and Thomas König, eds, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Robert Thomson, Frans N. Stokman, Christopher H. Achen and Thomas König, eds, The European Union Decides (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006).
    • (2006) The European Union Decides
  • 20
    • 33947702990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The co-decision procedure starts with a Commission proposal, which is sent to both institutional actors, the European Parliament and the Council. The Council, acting by qualified majority after obtaining the opinion of the European Parliament, may adopt the proposal if it approves all the proposed parliamentary amendments, or, if the European Parliament did not propose amendments; otherwise the Council adopts a common position and sends it to the European Parliament, and the Commission also informs the European Parliament of its position. Within three months, the European Parliament can either approve the common position of the Council, reject it or propose amendments to the common position. If the Council does not accept the parliamentary amendments within three months, a conciliation committee must be convened. The conciliation committee successfully produces a joint text, the European Parliament and the Council have to adopt it within six weeks
    • The co-decision procedure starts with a Commission proposal, which is sent to both institutional actors, the European Parliament and the Council. The Council, acting by qualified majority after obtaining the opinion of the European Parliament, may adopt the proposal if it approves all the proposed parliamentary amendments, or, if the European Parliament did not propose amendments; otherwise the Council adopts a common position and sends it to the European Parliament, and the Commission also informs the European Parliament of its position. Within three months, the European Parliament can either approve the common position of the Council, reject it or propose amendments to the common position. If the Council does not accept the parliamentary amendments within three months, a conciliation committee must be convened. The conciliation committee successfully produces a joint text, the European Parliament and the Council have to adopt it within six weeks.
  • 21
    • 0034416530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Amendments not voted on by the European Parliament in the second reading cannot be discussed during the negotiations (Michael Shackleton, The Politics of Codecision, Journal of Common Market Studies, 38 2000, 325-42, p. 335
    • Amendments not voted on by the European Parliament in the second reading cannot be discussed during the negotiations (Michael Shackleton, 'The Politics of Codecision', Journal of Common Market Studies, 38 (2000), 325-42, p. 335),
  • 22
    • 0032362347 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Behind the Scenes: An Examination of the Importance of the Informal Processes at Work in Conciliation
    • see also, 271-84, p
    • see also Julie Garman and Louise Hilditch, 'Behind the Scenes: An Examination of the Importance of the Informal Processes at Work in Conciliation', Journal of European Public Policy, 5 (1998), 271-84, p. 282.
    • (1998) Journal of European Public Policy , vol.5 , pp. 282
    • Garman, J.1    Hilditch, L.2
  • 23
    • 84973994613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regarding the success of conciliation committees, legislative studies have stressed the agenda-setting power under closed rule (David Baron and John Ferejohn, 'Bargaining in Legislatures', American Political Science Review, 89 (1989), 1181-206).
    • Regarding the success of conciliation committees, legislative studies have stressed the agenda-setting power under closed rule (David Baron and John Ferejohn, 'Bargaining in Legislatures', American Political Science Review, 89 (1989), 1181-206).
  • 24
    • 84974146810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Using the spatial model of legislative choice, Ken Shepsle and Barry R. Weingast, The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power, American Political Science Review, 81 1987, 85-104
    • Using the spatial model of legislative choice, Ken Shepsle and Barry R. Weingast ('The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power', American Political Science Review, 81 (1987), 85-104)
  • 25
    • 33947695554 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • show that the conciliation committee is the 'institutional foundation of committee power'. Due to the closed voting rule, such committees have an ex-post veto, which enables the standing committee to re-enforce its position, after the proposal has been considered by both the Senate and House floors (Shepsle and Weingast, 'The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power', p. 95). Informational approaches argue that committees are faithful agents of their parent chambers because they determine the voting rules for the conference report (Thomas Gilligan and Keith Krehbiel, 'The Organization of Informative Committees by a Rational Legislature', American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 531-64;
    • show that the conciliation committee is the 'institutional foundation of committee power'. Due to the closed voting rule, such committees have an ex-post veto, which enables the standing committee to re-enforce its position, after the proposal has been considered by both the Senate and House floors (Shepsle and Weingast, 'The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power', p. 95). Informational approaches argue that committees are faithful agents of their parent chambers because they determine the voting rules for the conference report (Thomas Gilligan and Keith Krehbiel, 'The Organization of Informative Committees by a Rational Legislature', American Journal of Political Science, 34 (1990), 531-64;
  • 26
    • 33947662887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organizations (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991)).
    • Keith Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organizations (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991)).
  • 27
    • 33947612441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The right to amend a bill in conference and to present the conference report to the parent chambers under closed rule is the highest incentive for conferees to specialize Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organizations, p. 199
    • The right to amend a bill in conference and to present the conference report to the parent chambers under closed rule is the highest incentive for conferees to specialize (Krehbiel, Information and Legislative Organizations, p. 199).
  • 29
    • 0037261884 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Codecision since Amsterdam: A Laboratory for Institutional Innovation and Change
    • 171-87, p
    • Michael Shackleton and Tapio Raunio, 'Codecision since Amsterdam: A Laboratory for Institutional Innovation and Change', Journal of European Public Policy, 10 (2003), 171-87, p. 172.
    • (2003) Journal of European Public Policy , vol.10 , pp. 172
    • Shackleton, M.1    Raunio, T.2
  • 30
    • 33947686555 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EP representation is a mixture between the issue-related flexible model of the US Congress and the German model of a permanent conciliation committee: three members from the EP vice-presidents, the chair and the rapporteur of the standing committee having jurisdiction over the proposal, and ten additional members selected by the political parties Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism: Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions, p. 204
    • EP representation is a mixture between the issue-related flexible model of the US Congress and the German model of a permanent conciliation committee: three members from the EP vice-presidents, the chair and the rapporteur of the standing committee having jurisdiction over the proposal, and ten additional members selected by the political parties (Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism: Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions, p. 204).
  • 32
    • 33947707737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chris Davies, 'Report on the joint text approved by the Conciliation Committee for a European Parliament and Council directive relating to ozone in ambient air' (A5-0454/2001 - 1999/0068(COD)). (2001), http://www.europarl.eu. int/oeil/file.jsp?id = 157782 (26.10.2005).
    • Chris Davies, 'Report on the joint text approved by the Conciliation Committee for a European Parliament and Council directive relating to ozone in ambient air' (A5-0454/2001 - 1999/0068(COD)). (2001), http://www.europarl.eu. int/oeil/file.jsp?id = 157782 (26.10.2005).
  • 33
    • 33947676234 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rapporteurs as Legislative Entrepreneurs: The Dynamics of the Codecision Procedure in Europe's Parliament
    • London
    • Giacomo Benedetto, 'Rapporteurs as Legislative Entrepreneurs: The Dynamics of the Codecision Procedure in Europe's Parliament' (London: LSE Working Paper, 2004);
    • (2004) LSE Working Paper
    • Benedetto, G.1
  • 34
    • 33947668231 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rasmussen, 'The Role of the European Commission in Co-decision'; David Judge and David Earnshaw, The European Parliament (Basingstoke, Hants: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003).
    • Rasmussen, 'The Role of the European Commission in Co-decision'; David Judge and David Earnshaw, The European Parliament (Basingstoke, Hants: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003).
  • 35
    • 33947665421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism. Most often, two models are used in the literature, the Rubinstein model and the Nash bargaining solution. While the co-operative Nash solution does not attempt to explain why the actors reach the bargain (only predicting the bargaining outcome), the non-cooperative Rubinstein model assumes that actors alternate bargaining offers sequentially: one actor makes an offer that the other can accept or reject. If rejected, the second actor makes a counteroffer etc.
    • Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism. Most often, two models are used in the literature, the Rubinstein model and the Nash bargaining solution. While the co-operative Nash solution does not attempt to explain why the actors reach the bargain (only predicting the bargaining outcome), the non-cooperative Rubinstein model assumes that actors alternate bargaining offers sequentially: one actor makes an offer that the other can accept or reject. If rejected, the second actor makes a counteroffer etc.
  • 36
    • 33947704540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hammond and Miller, 'Core of the Constitution'; Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism, p. 90.
    • Hammond and Miller, 'Core of the Constitution'; Tsebelis and Money, Bicameralism, p. 90.
  • 37
    • 84935839409 scopus 로고
    • Electoral Equilibrium under Alternative Voting Institutions
    • Gary W. Cox, 'Electoral Equilibrium under Alternative Voting Institutions', American Journal of Political Science, 31 (1987), 82-108;
    • (1987) American Journal of Political Science , vol.31 , pp. 82-108
    • Cox, G.W.1
  • 38
    • 0034339662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Institutional Effect of Majority Rule Instability: Bicameralism in Spatial Policy Decisions
    • William Bottom, Cheryl Eavey, Gary Miller and Jennifer Victor, "The Institutional Effect of Majority Rule Instability: Bicameralism in Spatial Policy Decisions', American Journal of Political Science, 44 (2000), 523-40.
    • (2000) American Journal of Political Science , vol.44 , pp. 523-540
    • Bottom, W.1    Eavey, C.2    Miller, G.3    Victor, J.4
  • 39
    • 0142086653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When Simple Voting Doesn't Work: Mulitcameral Systems for the Representation and Aggregation of Interests in International Organisations
    • 681-703, p
    • Thomas Bräuninger, 'When Simple Voting Doesn't Work: Mulitcameral Systems for the Representation and Aggregation of Interests in International Organisations', British Journal of Political Science, 33 (2003), 681-703, p. 684.
    • (2003) British Journal of Political Science , vol.33 , pp. 684
    • Bräuninger, T.1
  • 45
    • 33947624611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Napel and Widgren ('EU Conciliation Committee') assume that the two institutional actors have symmetric preferences and conclude from the difference in the formal voting threshold that the Council is the more powerful actor (Napel and Widgren, 'EU Conciliation Committee').
    • Napel and Widgren ('EU Conciliation Committee') assume that the two institutional actors have symmetric preferences and conclude from the difference in the formal voting threshold that the Council is the more powerful actor (Napel and Widgren, 'EU Conciliation Committee').
  • 47
    • 33947633894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules, Ideology and Coalition Formation in the European Parliament: Past, Present and Future
    • Amie Kreppel, 'Rules, Ideology and Coalition Formation in the European Parliament: Past, Present and Future', EPRG Working Paper, 4 (1999), p. 1;
    • (1999) EPRG Working Paper , vol.4 , pp. 1
    • Kreppel, A.1
  • 50
    • 33947628039 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We do not enter the debate on the effect of cohesiveness for the yolk as the centre of collective actors without an equilibrium solution. With respect to the size of the winset, we only examine whether, in the case of no equilibrium solution, the less cohesive actor has more room to manœuvre
    • We do not enter the debate on the effect of cohesiveness for the yolk as the centre of collective actors without an equilibrium solution. With respect to the size of the winset, we only examine whether - in the case of no equilibrium solution - the less cohesive actor has more room to manœuvre.
  • 51
    • 0000291018 scopus 로고
    • The Bargaining Problem
    • John F. Nash, 'The Bargaining Problem', Econometrica, 18 (1950), 155-62;
    • (1950) Econometrica , vol.18 , pp. 155-162
    • Nash, J.F.1
  • 52
    • 0001058478 scopus 로고
    • Two-Person Cooperative Games
    • John F. Nash, 'Two-Person Cooperative Games', Econometrica, 21 (1953), 128-40.
    • (1953) Econometrica , vol.21 , pp. 128-140
    • Nash, J.F.1
  • 53
    • 33947638337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • According to Osborne and Rubinstein ('A Course in Game Theory', p. 36), a present-oriented actor who discounts the future heavily, has a low discount factor and a high discount rate.
    • According to Osborne and Rubinstein ('A Course in Game Theory', p. 36), a present-oriented actor who discounts the future heavily, has a low discount factor and a high discount rate.
  • 61
    • 84996180934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Unanimity in the Council?
    • Mikko Mattila and Jan-Erik Lane, 'Why Unanimity in the Council?' European Union Politics, 1 (2001), 31-52.
    • (2001) European Union Politics , vol.1 , pp. 31-52
    • Mattila, M.1    Lane, J.2
  • 62
    • 33947670830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • During our period of study from March 1999 to July 2002, the following countries held the Council presidencies: Finland, Portugal, France, Sweden, Belgium and Spain. According to Mattila and Lane ('Why Unanimity in the Council?'), these presidencies exhibited a specific voting pattern in the Council.
    • During our period of study from March 1999 to July 2002, the following countries held the Council presidencies: Finland, Portugal, France, Sweden, Belgium and Spain. According to Mattila and Lane ('Why Unanimity in the Council?'), these presidencies exhibited a specific voting pattern in the Council.
  • 66
    • 33947637797 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parliamentary Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2000-2001 (2001) at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/activity_reports/ activity_report_2001_en.pdf (23.03.2002), p. 14.
    • Parliamentary Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2000-2001 (2001) at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/activity_reports/ activity_report_2001_en.pdf (23.03.2002), p. 14.
  • 67
    • 33947613472 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Steunenberg, 'Codecision and Its Reform'; Crombez, 'The Treaty of Amsterdam and the Codecision Procedure'; Tsebelis and Garrett, 'Legislative Politics in the European Union'.
    • Steunenberg, 'Codecision and Its Reform'; Crombez, 'The Treaty of Amsterdam and the Codecision Procedure'; Tsebelis and Garrett, 'Legislative Politics in the European Union'.
  • 69
    • 0031504236 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Delegation, Agency, and Agenda Setting in the European Community
    • 99-134, pp
    • Mark A. Pollack, 'Delegation, Agency, and Agenda Setting in the European Community', International Organization, 51 (1997), 99-134, pp. 126ff.;
    • (1997) International Organization , vol.51
    • Pollack, M.A.1
  • 71
    • 33947626978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • During the period studied, fifty-four dossiers passed through the conciliation committee. Experts for all fifty-four dossiers could be located and interviewed, and of them thirty-four interview partners were members of the European Parliament (MEPs) and seven were MEP advisers. The remaining thirteen interviews were conducted with legislative administrators from the parliamentary conciliation committee secretariat that was responsible for the dossier
    • During the period studied, fifty-four dossiers passed through the conciliation committee. Experts for all fifty-four dossiers could be located and interviewed, and of them thirty-four interview partners were members of the European Parliament (MEPs) and seven were MEP advisers. The remaining thirteen interviews were conducted with legislative administrators from the parliamentary conciliation committee secretariat that was responsible for the dossier.
  • 72
    • 33947623550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Benedetto, 'Rapporteurs as Legislative Entrepreneurs'.
    • Benedetto, 'Rapporteurs as Legislative Entrepreneurs'.
  • 74
    • 33947673784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The parliamentary conciliation secretariat's documents that were consulted were the Activity Reports for the years 1999-2000, 2000-01, 2001-02. The variables for the Council presidency and the political party of the rapporteur are based on information from these documents.
    • The parliamentary conciliation secretariat's documents that were consulted were the Activity Reports for the years 1999-2000, 2000-01, 2001-02. The variables for the Council presidency and the political party of the rapporteur are based on information from these documents.
  • 75
    • 33947674595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 1999-2000 (2000), at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2000_en.pdf (23.03.2002);
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 1999-2000 (2000), at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2000_en.pdf (23.03.2002);
  • 76
    • 33947683178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2000-2001 (2001) at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2001_en.pdf (23.03.2002);
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2000-2001 (2001) at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2001_en.pdf (23.03.2002);
  • 77
    • 33947711115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2001-2002 (2002): at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2002_en.pdf (20.06.2002).
    • Parliamentarian Conciliation Secretariat, Activity Report 2001-2002 (2002): at: http://www.europarl.eu.int/code/information/ activity_reports/activity_report_2002_en.pdf (20.06.2002).
  • 79
    • 33947667301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Javier Arregui, Frans N. Stokman and Robert Thomson found that Council members change their position over time (European Union Politics, 1 (2004), 47-72).
    • Javier Arregui, Frans N. Stokman and Robert Thomson found that Council members change their position over time (European Union Politics, 1 (2004), 47-72).
  • 80
    • 33947695053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Due to the nature of the policy space we only distinguish whether the Council or the European Parliament is closer to the status quo, or whether no information on the location of the status quo was recorded
    • Due to the nature of the policy space we only distinguish whether the Council or the European Parliament is closer to the status quo, or whether no information on the location of the status quo was recorded.
  • 81
    • 84996260388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Examining the EU Legislative Process: The Relative Importance of Agenda Setting and Veto Power
    • Thomas König and Mirja Pöter, 'Examining the EU Legislative Process: The Relative Importance of Agenda Setting and Veto Power', European Union Politics, 2 (2001), 329-51;
    • (2001) European Union Politics , vol.2 , pp. 329-351
    • König, T.1    Pöter, M.2
  • 82
    • 1842783948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Dimensionality of European Union Legislative Decision-Making
    • Thorsten Selck, 'On the Dimensionality of European Union Legislative Decision-Making', Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16 (2004), 203-23.
    • (2004) Journal of Theoretical Politics , vol.16 , pp. 203-223
    • Selck, T.1
  • 83
    • 33947671761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kreppel, 'Rules, Ideology and Coalition Formation in the European Parliament'; Hix, Noury and Roland, 'Understanding the European Parliament'; Stephanie Bailer and Gerald Schneider, 'When Words Matter: Informal Rules and the Enlargement Debate', in Bernard Steunenberg and Jacques Thomassen, eds, The European Parliament - Moving Toward Democracy in the EU (Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield, 2002), pp. 139-61.
    • Kreppel, 'Rules, Ideology and Coalition Formation in the European Parliament'; Hix, Noury and Roland, 'Understanding the European Parliament'; Stephanie Bailer and Gerald Schneider, 'When Words Matter: Informal Rules and the Enlargement Debate', in Bernard Steunenberg and Jacques Thomassen, eds, The European Parliament - Moving Toward Democracy in the EU (Lanham, Md.: Rowman & Littlefield, 2002), pp. 139-61.
  • 85
    • 33947618170 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Note that we are using a specification without intercept such that two threshold parameters can be identified. The parameter estimates can be easily transformed corresponding to an equivalent specification with one threshold and an intercept
    • Note that we are using a specification without intercept such that two threshold parameters can be identified. The parameter estimates can be easily transformed corresponding to an equivalent specification with one threshold and an intercept.
  • 86
    • 0000895478 scopus 로고
    • A General Approach to Serial Correlation
    • Christian Gourieroux, Alain Monfort and Alain Trognon, 'A General Approach to Serial Correlation', Econometric Theory, 1 (1985), 315-40.
    • (1985) Econometric Theory , vol.1 , pp. 315-340
    • Gourieroux, C.1    Monfort, A.2    Trognon, A.3
  • 87
    • 0000183696 scopus 로고
    • Maximum Likelihood Specification Testing and Conditional Moment Tests
    • Whitney K. Newey, 'Maximum Likelihood Specification Testing and Conditional Moment Tests', Econometrica, 53 (1985), 1047-70.
    • (1985) Econometrica , vol.53 , pp. 1047-1070
    • Newey, W.K.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.