-
5
-
-
84974233496
-
Strategic Voting Equilibria Under the Single Non-Transferable Vote
-
Gary Cox, 'Strategic Voting Equilibria Under the Single Non-Transferable Vote', American Political Science Review, 88 (1994), 608-21;
-
(1994)
American Political Science Review
, vol.88
, pp. 608-621
-
-
Cox, G.1
-
6
-
-
0004226894
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Gary Cox, Making Votes Count (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997).
-
(1997)
Making Votes Count
-
-
Cox, G.1
-
7
-
-
33947676233
-
-
A single-member plurality system is one in which each electoral district elects only one representative and that representative is chosen by receiving a plurality of the vote
-
A single-member plurality system is one in which each electoral district elects only one representative and that representative is chosen by receiving a plurality of the vote.
-
-
-
-
9
-
-
33947683712
-
Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Non-transferable Vote'; and Cox
-
Cox, 'Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Non-transferable Vote'; and Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
Making Votes Count
-
-
Cox1
-
13
-
-
33947641447
-
-
While game theorists have become interested in strategic voting in the last fifteen years, a number of decision theorists tackled the issue somewhat earlier. Important works include Richard McKelvey and Peter Ordeshook, A General Theory of the Calculus of Voting, in J. F. Herndon and J. L. Bernd, Mathematical Applications in Political Science, 6 1972, pp. 32-78;
-
While game theorists have become interested in strategic voting in the last fifteen years, a number of decision theorists tackled the issue somewhat earlier. Important works include Richard McKelvey and Peter Ordeshook, 'A General Theory of the Calculus of Voting', in J. F. Herndon and J. L. Bernd, Mathematical Applications in Political Science, 6 (1972), pp. 32-78;
-
-
-
-
16
-
-
0002352436
-
A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law
-
Peter C. Ordeshook, ed, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
-
Thomas Palfrey, 'A Mathematical Proof of Duverger's Law', in Peter C. Ordeshook, ed., Models of Strategic Choice in Politics (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1989), pp. 69-91.
-
(1989)
Models of Strategic Choice in Politics
, pp. 69-91
-
-
Palfrey, T.1
-
17
-
-
33947680609
-
Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Non-transferable Vote'; Cox
-
Cox, 'Strategic Voting Equilibria under the Single Non-transferable Vote'; Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
Making Votes Count
-
-
Cox1
-
18
-
-
0031286129
-
-
For instance, Mark Fey's ('Stability and Coordination in Duverger's Law: A Formal Model of Preelection Polls and Strategic Voting', American Political Science Review, 91 (1997), 135-47)
-
For instance, Mark Fey's ('Stability and Coordination in Duverger's Law: A Formal Model of Preelection Polls and Strategic Voting', American Political Science Review, 91 (1997), 135-47)
-
-
-
-
19
-
-
0040390947
-
-
treatment of Roger Meyerson and Robert Weber's ('A Theory of Voting Equilibria', American Political Science Review, 87 (1993), 102-14) model showed how polling could eliminate non-Duvergerian equilibria.
-
treatment of Roger Meyerson and Robert Weber's ('A Theory of Voting Equilibria', American Political Science Review, 87 (1993), 102-14) model showed how polling could eliminate non-Duvergerian equilibria.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
0036132566
-
Predicting the 1998 Indian Parliamentary Election
-
Rajeeva L. Karandikar, Clive Payne and Yogendra Yadav, 'Predicting the 1998 Indian Parliamentary Election', Electoral Studies, 21 (2002), 69-89.
-
(2002)
Electoral Studies
, vol.21
, pp. 69-89
-
-
Karandikar, R.L.1
Payne, C.2
Yadav, Y.3
-
24
-
-
84971720906
-
Sophisticated Voting in the 1988 Presidential Primaries
-
Paul R. Abramson, John H. Aldrich, Phil Paolino and David W. Rohde, 'Sophisticated Voting in the 1988 Presidential Primaries', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 55-69.
-
(1992)
American Political Science Review
, vol.86
, pp. 55-69
-
-
Abramson, P.R.1
Aldrich, J.H.2
Paolino, P.3
Rohde, D.W.4
-
25
-
-
0001052116
-
The Multicandidate Calculus of Voting: Applications to Canadian Federal Elections
-
Jerome Black, 'The Multicandidate Calculus of Voting: Applications to Canadian Federal Elections', American Journal of Political Science, 22 (1978), 609-38.
-
(1978)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.22
, pp. 609-638
-
-
Black, J.1
-
26
-
-
0002118854
-
An Experiment on Coordination in Multicandidate Elections: The Importance of Polls and Election Histories
-
Robert Forsythe et al., 'An Experiment on Coordination in Multicandidate Elections: The Importance of Polls and Election Histories', Social Choice and Welfare, 10 (1993), 223-47.
-
(1993)
Social Choice and Welfare
, vol.10
, pp. 223-247
-
-
Forsythe, R.1
-
27
-
-
0036989035
-
-
Recently David P. Myatt and Stephen D. Fisher, 'Tactical Coordination in Plurality Electoral Systems', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18 (2002), 504-22;
-
Recently David P. Myatt and Stephen D. Fisher, 'Tactical Coordination in Plurality Electoral Systems', Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 18 (2002), 504-22;
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
33947637026
-
-
and David P. Myatt, 'A New Theory of Strategic Voting', Oxford Working Paper, no. 12 (2002), used the concept of a global game to look at strategic voting without common knowledge. Global games are games that alter the assumption of common knowledge by having each player observe a noisy signal from the true state of things. While the system generating the noise is common knowledge, the underlying state is not. This approach does allow the authors to move further from the common knowledge assumption.
-
and David P. Myatt, 'A New Theory of Strategic Voting', Oxford Working Paper, no. 12 (2002), used the concept of a global game to look at strategic voting without common knowledge. Global games are games that alter the assumption of common knowledge by having each player observe a noisy signal from the true state of things. While the system generating the noise is common knowledge, the underlying state is not. This approach does allow the authors to move further from the common knowledge assumption.
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
84971758042
-
Adaptive Parties in Spatial Elections
-
Kenneth Kollman, John Miller and Scott Page, 'Adaptive Parties in Spatial Elections', American Political Science Review, 86 (1992), 929-37.
-
(1992)
American Political Science Review
, vol.86
, pp. 929-937
-
-
Kollman, K.1
Miller, J.2
Page, S.3
-
32
-
-
33947651513
-
-
Given the simple nature of the model and the way utilities are calculated, multiple policy dimensions should have no effect in this model. However, it is possible that multi-dimensional preferences would affect where individuals acquire information. Voters may acquire information about different policy areas from different parts of their social networks. One interesting variation on the relatively simple model here would be to have individuals collecting information about different dimensions from different individuals
-
Given the simple nature of the model and the way utilities are calculated, multiple policy dimensions should have no effect in this model. However, it is possible that multi-dimensional preferences would affect where individuals acquire information. Voters may acquire information about different policy areas from different parts of their social networks. One interesting variation on the relatively simple model here would be to have individuals collecting information about different dimensions from different individuals.
-
-
-
-
36
-
-
0016264378
-
Judgement Under Uncertainty
-
Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman, 'Judgement Under Uncertainty', Science, 185 (1974), 1124-31.
-
(1974)
Science
, vol.185
, pp. 1124-1131
-
-
Tversky, A.1
Kahneman, D.2
-
42
-
-
33947629595
-
-
The model was run on a Macintosh G5 computer with 1.25 GB of memory.
-
The model was run on a Macintosh G5 computer with 1.25 GB of memory.
-
-
-
-
43
-
-
33947680608
-
-
A torus is a shape in which the bottom and the top meet and the sides meet with one another; essentially, it looks like a doughnut
-
A torus is a shape in which the bottom and the top meet and the sides meet with one another; essentially, it looks like a doughnut.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
33947668230
-
-
Introduced in Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
Introduced in Cox, Making Votes Count.
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
33947654742
-
-
In order to test the effects of size of the grid on the results presented, the 8-168 neighbour versions of the model were run on a 25 × 25 grid. The increased size of the grid made it impossible to run results for larger neighbourhood sizes, especially the full information version of the model. While not precisely the same, the results were very similar, and the basic relationships between the relevant variables still held. This strongly suggests that the results hold for larger grid sizes (and hence larger populations).
-
In order to test the effects of size of the grid on the results presented, the 8-168 neighbour versions of the model were run on a 25 × 25 grid. The increased size of the grid made it impossible to run results for larger neighbourhood sizes, especially the full information version of the model. While not precisely the same, the results were very similar, and the basic relationships between the relevant variables still held. This strongly suggests that the results hold for larger grid sizes (and hence larger populations).
-
-
-
-
52
-
-
33947634409
-
-
Using a two-tailed difference of proportions test, these differences were found to be significant at the 0.01 level
-
Using a two-tailed difference of proportions test, these differences were found to be significant at the 0.01 level.
-
-
-
-
53
-
-
33947670308
-
-
Once again, these differences are significant at the 0.01 level
-
Once again, these differences are significant at the 0.01 level.
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
33947697079
-
-
Once again, these differences are significant at the 0.01 level
-
Once again, these differences are significant at the 0.01 level.
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
33947614000
-
-
When neighbourhood size is 168, voters are talking to the whole community
-
When neighbourhood size is 168, voters are talking to the whole community.
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
33947619916
-
-
In each case the histogram for the SF ratio distribution has a large spike at 0. In addition, the median SF ratio is 0 for each of these conditions and the average SF ratio is below 0.05.
-
In each case the histogram for the SF ratio distribution has a large spike at 0. In addition, the median SF ratio is 0 for each of these conditions and the average SF ratio is below 0.05.
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
33947661307
-
-
These intervals are calculated using a finite population correction, and the standard errors were estimated using a proportion of 0.5
-
These intervals are calculated using a finite population correction, and the standard errors were estimated using a proportion of 0.5.
-
-
-
|