메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 69, Issue 4, 2006, Pages 159-180

Paying for what you get and getting what you pay for: Legal responses to consumer-driven health care

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33947401052     PISSN: 00239186     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (6)

References (182)
  • 1
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • 7, (Autumn)
    • Clark C. Havighurst & Barak D. Richman, Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 7, 8 (Autumn 2006).
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 8
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 2
    • 17444413178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally (Regina E. Herzlinger ed.), (providing extensive overview of consumer-driven health care policies)
    • See generally Consumer-Driven Health Care: Implications for Providers, Payers and Policy Makers (Regina E. Herzlinger ed., 2004) (providing extensive overview of consumer-driven health care policies);
    • (2004) Consumer-Driven Health Care: Implications for Providers, Payers and Policy Makers
  • 3
    • 1942478618 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reinvention of Health Insurance in the Consumer Era
    • (same)
    • James C. Robinson, Reinvention of Health Insurance in the Consumer Era, 291 JAMA 1880 (2004) (same);
    • (2004) JAMA , vol.291 , pp. 1880
    • Robinson, J.C.1
  • 4
    • 33947396214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Promise and Peril of Ownership Society Health Care Policy
    • (analyzing the claims made by proponents of consumer-driven health care)
    • Amy B. Monahan, The Promise and Peril of Ownership Society Health Care Policy, 80 Tul. L. Rev. 777 (2006) (analyzing the claims made by proponents of consumer-driven health care).
    • (2006) Tul. L. Rev. , vol.80 , pp. 777
    • Monahan, S.B.1
  • 5
    • 33947404944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 § 1201
    • The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 § 1201, 26 U.S.C.A. § 223 (2003).
    • (2003) U.S.C.A. , vol.26 , pp. 223
  • 6
    • 33947360422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care
    • 536
    • Richard L. Kaplan, Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care, 36 McGeorge L. Rev. 536, 551-52 (2005);
    • (2005) McGeorge L. Rev. , vol.36 , pp. 551-552
    • Kaplan, R.L.1
  • 7
    • 33947402007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year
    • 1087, These numbers are not precise because they are adjusted each year for inflation
    • Edward J. Larson & Marc Dettmann, The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year, 40 Wake Forest L. Rev. 1087, 1097 (2006). These numbers are not precise because they are adjusted each year for inflation.
    • (2006) Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 1097
    • Larson, E.J.1    Dettmann, M.2
  • 8
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • See (Autumn) (supporting "proposals to let consumers... choose more or less freely the style of health care they want to purchase for their families"). To the surprise of many, they are also amenable to a single-payer government insurance system
    • See Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 79 (supporting "proposals to let consumers... choose more or less freely the style of health care they want to purchase for their families"). To the surprise of many, they are also amenable to a single-payer government insurance system.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 79
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 9
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • (Autumn) ("Indeed, we would not object if our [arguments]... were cited as a reason to adopt a monolithic national health program."). Still, they insist that those who are well-off remain free to purchase supplemental coverage that provides a higher tier of service
    • See id. ("Indeed, we would not object if our [arguments]... were cited as a reason to adopt a monolithic national health program."). Still, they insist that those who are well-off remain free to purchase supplemental coverage that provides a higher tier of service.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 79
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 10
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • See (Autumn) (expressing openness to "scrapping private health insurance altogether (except insofar as it might supplement the national system's coverage)")
    • See id. (expressing openness to "scrapping private health insurance altogether (except insofar as it might supplement the national system's coverage)").
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 79
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 11
    • 33947367453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributional Considerations in the Overregulation of Health Professionals, Health Facilities, and Health Plans
    • Others in this symposium consider public insurance and government regulation of providers. See, e.g., (Autumn)
    • Others in this symposium consider public insurance and government regulation of providers. See, e.g., Christopher J. Conover, Distributional Considerations in the Overregulation of Health Professionals, Health Facilities, and Health Plans, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 181 (Autumn 2006);
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 181
    • Conover, C.J.1
  • 12
    • 33947399786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Political Economy of Unfairness in U.S. Health Policy
    • (Autumn)
    • Jonathan Oberlander, The Political Economy of Unfairness in U.S. Health Policy, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 245 (Autumn 2006).
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 245
    • Oberlander, J.1
  • 15
    • 32044444367 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Precarious Pricing System for Hospital Services
    • 45
    • Christopher P. Tompkins, Stuart H. Altman & Efrat Eilat, The Precarious Pricing System for Hospital Services, 25 Health Aff. 45, 52 (2006).
    • (2006) Health Aff. , vol.25 , pp. 52
    • Tompkins, C.P.1    Altman, S.H.2    Eilat, E.3
  • 16
    • 33947397762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?
    • 26
    • Kenneth T. Bowden, Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?, 34 Brief 26, 28 (2005);
    • (2005) Brief , vol.34 , pp. 28
    • Bowden, K.T.1
  • 17
    • 32044433779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy
    • 57
    • Uwe E. Reinhardt, The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy, 25 Health Aff. 57, 62 (2006);
    • (2006) Health Aff. , vol.25 , pp. 62
    • Reinhardt, U.E.1
  • 18
    • 33947390125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hospitals Sock Uninsured with Much Bigger Bills
    • Feb. 25
    • Julie Appleby, Hospitals Sock Uninsured with Much Bigger Bills, USA Today, Feb. 25, 2004, at B1;
    • (2004) USA Today
    • Appleby, J.1
  • 19
    • 32044451673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Anatomy of a Hospital Bill
    • Sept. 21
    • Lucette Lagnado, Anatomy of a Hospital Bill, Wall St. J., Sept. 21, 2004, at B1.
    • (2004) Wall St. J.
    • Lagnado, L.1
  • 20
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • (Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
    • Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 13-82. These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 13-82
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 21
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • (Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
    • See id. at 71-72.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 71-72
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 22
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
    • (Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
    • Id. at 72.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 72
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 23
    • 33947422220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation
    • For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Sept
    • For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Richard G. Stuhan, Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation, Health Lawyer News, Sept. 2005, at 18.
    • (2005) Health Lawyer News , pp. 18
    • Stuhan, R.G.1
  • 24
    • 33947422220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation
    • For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Sept
    • Id.
    • (2005) Health Lawyer News , pp. 18
    • Stuhan, R.G.1
  • 25
    • 33947420565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Temple Univ. Hosp. v. Healthcare Management Alternatives
    • 501, (Pa. Super. Ct.)
    • Temple Univ. Hosp. v. Healthcare Management Alternatives, 832 A.2d 501, 508 (Pa. Super. Ct. 2003);
    • (2003) A.2d , vol.832 , pp. 508
  • 26
    • 33947415455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • River Park Hosp. v. Bluecross Blueshield of Tenn
    • 43, (Tenn.)
    • River Park Hosp. v. Bluecross Blueshield of Tenn., 173 S.W.3d 43, 58 (Tenn. 2003).
    • (2003) S.W.3d , vol.173 , pp. 58
  • 27
    • 33947397762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?
    • Bowden, supra note 10, at 29;
    • (2005) Brief , vol.34 , pp. 29
    • Bowden, K.T.1
  • 28
    • 32044433779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy
    • Reinhardt, supra note 10, at 62;
    • (2006) Health Aff. , vol.25 , pp. 62
    • Reinhardt, U.E.1
  • 30
    • 84942948238 scopus 로고
    • Legal Responsibility for Medical Malpractice
    • Enacted about 2030 B. C., the Code of Hammurabi declared, for instance: If a doctor has cured the shattered limb of a gentleman or has cured the diseased bowel, the patient shall give five shekels of silver to the doctor. If it is the son of a poor man he shall give three shekels of silver. If a gentleman's servant, the master of the slave shall give two shekels of silver to the doctor. 942, It is not entirely clear, though, whether these rules were based on ability to pay rather than on the social value of the service to different classes of patients
    • Enacted about 2030 B. C., the Code of Hammurabi declared, for instance: If a doctor has cured the shattered limb of a gentleman or has cured the diseased bowel, the patient shall give five shekels of silver to the doctor. If it is the son of a poor man he shall give three shekels of silver. If a gentleman's servant, the master of the slave shall give two shekels of silver to the doctor. Hubert W. Smith, Legal Responsibility for Medical Malpractice, 116 JAMA 942, 943 (1941). It is not entirely clear, though, whether these rules were based on ability to pay rather than on the social value of the service to different classes of patients.
    • (1941) JAMA , vol.116 , pp. 943
    • Smith, H.W.1
  • 31
    • 0342793437 scopus 로고
    • The historical and legal bases for barring physicians from suing for fees has not been studied as thoroughly as it has been for lawyers. For physicians, the best scholarly discussion is well over a century old. 10-14, (Arno Press 1973)
    • The historical and legal bases for barring physicians from suing for fees has not been studied as thoroughly as it has been for lawyers. For physicians, the best scholarly discussion is well over a century old. John Ordronaux, The Jurisprudence of Medicine in its Relations to the Law of Contracts, Torts, and Evidende 10-14, 34-41 (Arno Press 1973) (1869).
    • (1869) The Jurisprudence of Medicine in Its Relations to the Law of Contracts, Torts, and Evidende , pp. 34-41
    • Ordronaux, J.1
  • 32
    • 0003577958 scopus 로고
    • It appears that medieval Roman law codified the ancient practice based in part on concerns that physicians were overcharging their patients. (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985)
    • It appears that medieval Roman law codified the ancient practice based in part on concerns that physicians were overcharging their patients. Thomas Percival, Medical Ethics: Or a Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons 175-76 (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985) (1803).
    • (1803) Medical Ethics: Ora Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons , pp. 175-176
    • Percival, T.1
  • 33
    • 0003577958 scopus 로고
    • In Renaissance England, the rule appears to be based more on the notion of legal recognition of professional norms, that is, refusing to find an implied promise to pay when the common practice at the time was to receive honoraria. However, it seems there was no rule barring physicians from making and enforcing an express contract. (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985)
    • In Renaissance England, the rule appears to be based more on the notion of legal recognition of professional norms, that is, refusing to find an implied promise to pay when the common practice at the time was to receive honoraria. However, it seems there was no rule barring physicians from making and enforcing an express contract. Id. at 177-78;
    • (1803) Medical Ethics: Ora Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons , pp. 177-178
    • Percival, T.1
  • 34
    • 33947433354 scopus 로고
    • Rondel v. Worsley
    • 191, (Lord Morris), 280 (Lord Upjohn) (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2002) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.)
    • Rondel v. Worsley, [1969] 1 A.C. 191, 237 (Lord Morris), 280 (Lord Upjohn) (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2002) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.).
    • (1969) A.C. , vol.1 , pp. 237
  • 35
    • 0041577670 scopus 로고
    • In ancient Rome, lawyers and other "liberal arts" practitioners from the nobility undertook service pursuant to a "mandate," meaning that their services were required without compensation. This understanding arose from the social order among the Roman nobility that regarded public service as one of the duties of citizenship and that assumed that other nobles would reciprocate in kind with their services, as the need arose. See
    • In ancient Rome, lawyers and other "liberal arts" practitioners from the nobility undertook service pursuant to a "mandate," meaning that their services were required without compensation. This understanding arose from the social order among the Roman nobility that regarded public service as one of the duties of citizenship and that assumed that other nobles would reciprocate in kind with their services, as the need arose. See Barry Nicholas, An Introduction to Roman Law 187-89 (1962);
    • (1962) An Introduction to Roman Law , pp. 187-189
    • Nicholas, B.1
  • 37
    • 0003761921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • British barristers adopted the convention of voluntary honoraria rather than contractual fees, in part in order to elevate their social and professional standing over solicitors and attorneys
    • Reinhard Zimmerman, The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition 413-20 (1996). British barristers adopted the convention of voluntary honoraria rather than contractual fees, in part in order to elevate their social and professional standing over solicitors and attorneys.
    • (1996) The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition , pp. 413-420
    • Zimmerman, R.1
  • 39
    • 0346930919 scopus 로고
    • These legal characterizations were largely just formalities, however, in that both in England and in ancient Rome, lawyers usually expected to receive their standard payment before they took a case. Also, they sometimes could sue for payment on legal grounds other than ordinary contract, such as quantum meruit (equity) or to enforce a sealed bond given in exchange for service
    • These legal characterizations were largely just formalities, however, in that both in England and in ancient Rome, lawyers usually expected to receive their standard payment before they took a case. Also, they sometimes could sue for payment on legal grounds other than ordinary contract, such as quantum meruit (equity) or to enforce a sealed bond given in exchange for service. Id.
    • (1986) The Legal Profession and the Common Law: Historical Essays , pp. 119
    • Baker, J.H.1
  • 41
    • 84924177265 scopus 로고
    • Rondel v. Worsley
    • Lawyers never fully adopted this part of the creed. Instead, the practice among barristers was to insist on payment of their usual fee in advance, before taking on a case. Only in criminal cases were barristers required to work without pay. This prepayment practice obviated the need to sue for fees, which legal historians speculate made it convenient for barristers to adopt the non-enforceability doctrine as a means of elevating their professional standing. Later, barristers used the noncontractual basis of legal services to argue for immunity from tort liability. See (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2000) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.)
    • Lawyers never fully adopted this part of the creed. Instead, the practice among barristers was to insist on payment of their usual fee in advance, before taking on a case. Only in criminal cases were barristers required to work without pay. This prepayment practice obviated the need to sue for fees, which legal historians speculate made it convenient for barristers to adopt the non-enforceability doctrine as a means of elevating their professional standing. Later, barristers used the noncontractual basis of legal services to argue for immunity from tort liability. See Rondel v. Worsley, [1969] 1 A.C. 191 (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2000) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.).
    • (1969) A.C. , vol.1 , pp. 191
  • 44
    • 33947368770 scopus 로고
    • Ability to Pay as Factor in Determining Reasonableness of Charge of Physician or Surgeon
    • Annotation
    • D.E. Evins, Annotation, Ability to Pay as Factor in Determining Reasonableness of Charge of Physician or Surgeon, 97 A.L.R.2d 1232 (1964).
    • (1964) A.L.R.2d , vol.97 , pp. 1232
    • Evins, D.E.1
  • 45
    • 33947369192 scopus 로고
    • Zumwalt v. Schwarz
    • See, e.g., 608, (Cal. Ct. App.) ("[T]here is evidence of a recognized usage, which has grown into a custom, to graduate professional charges with reference to the financial condition of the patient...."). One widespread practice was to charge the patient one month of his or her salary for a major operation
    • See, e.g., Zumwalt v. Schwarz, 297 P. 608, 610 (Cal. Ct. App. 1931) ("[T]here is evidence of a recognized usage, which has grown into a custom, to graduate professional charges with reference to the financial condition of the patient...."). One widespread practice was to charge the patient one month of his or her salary for a major operation.
    • (1931) P. , vol.297 , pp. 610
  • 46
    • 33947430270 scopus 로고
    • Houda v. McDonald
    • 249, (Wash.)
    • Houda v. McDonald, 294 P. 249, 251 (Wash. 1930).
    • (1930) P. , vol.294 , pp. 251
  • 47
    • 33947390124 scopus 로고
    • Citron v. Fields
    • For instance, (Cal. Ct. App.) was a suit against the famous actor W.C. Fields for $12,000 in medical fees
    • For instance, Citron v. Fields, 85 P.2d 534 (Cal. Ct. App. 1938), was a suit against the famous actor W.C. Fields for $12,000 in medical fees.
    • (1938) P.2d , vol.85 , pp. 534
  • 48
    • 33947357914 scopus 로고
    • Spencer v. West
    • Although courts have not specifically repudiated the rule that considers patients' ability to pay, the last reported case following this principle is 423, (La. Ct. App.)
    • Although courts have not specifically repudiated the rule that considers patients' ability to pay, the last reported case following this principle is Spencer v. West, 126 So. 2d 423, 426-27 (La. Ct. App. 1960).
    • (1960) So. 2d , vol.126 , pp. 426-427
  • 49
    • 33947404522 scopus 로고
    • Anticaglia v. Lynch
    • The principle was briefly mentioned in one unreported case since then. No. 90C-11-175, 1992 WL 138983, (Del. Super. Ct. Mar. 16)
    • The principle was briefly mentioned in one unreported case since then. Anticaglia v. Lynch, No. 90C-11-175, 1992 WL 138983, at *19 (Del. Super. Ct. Mar. 16, 1992).
    • (1992) , pp. 19
  • 50
    • 33947378051 scopus 로고
    • Rush Presbyterian-St. Luke's Med. Ctr. v. Hellenic Republic
    • Most modern cases simply state that patients owe reasonable rates based on prevailing charges. E.g., 449, (7th Cir.)
    • Most modern cases simply state that patients owe reasonable rates based on prevailing charges. E.g., Rush Presbyterian-St. Luke's Med. Ctr. v. Hellenic Republic, 980 F.2d 449, 453-54 (7th Cir. 1992).
    • (1992) F.2d , vol.980 , pp. 453-454
  • 51
    • 33947429373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Op. 8.055 ("Physicians have a professional obligation to provide care to those in need, regardless of ability to pay, particularly to those in need of urgent care")
    • See, e.g., American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions with Annotations Op. 8.055 (2005) ("Physicians have a professional obligation to provide care to those in need, regardless of ability to pay, particularly to those in need of urgent care.");
    • (2005) Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions With Annotations
  • 52
    • 0003705423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Op. 9.065 ("Each physician has an obligation to share in providing care to the indigent.... Caring for the poor should be a regular part of the physician's practice schedule")
    • id Op. 9.065 ("Each physician has an obligation to share in providing care to the indigent.... Caring for the poor should be a regular part of the physician's practice schedule.").
    • (2005) Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions With Annotations
  • 57
    • 0027243648 scopus 로고
    • The Struggle for the Soul of Health Insurance
    • See (stressing the social value of community rating)
    • See Deborah Stone, The Struggle for the Soul of Health Insurance, 18 J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. 287 (1993) (stressing the social value of community rating).
    • (1993) J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. , vol.18 , pp. 287
    • Stone, D.1
  • 59
    • 0004132001 scopus 로고
    • "Medical underwriting" means that insurers in some fashion assess and price the health risk of each subscriber
    • "Medical underwriting" means that insurers in some fashion assess and price the health risk of each subscriber. Id at 16-17.
    • (1994) Reforming Private Health Insurance , pp. 16-17
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 60
    • 0034146108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Geography of Health Insurance Regulation: A Guide to Identifying, Exploiting, and Policing Market Boundaries
    • Mar.-Apr. at 173
    • Mark A. Hall, The Geography of Health Insurance Regulation: A Guide to Identifying, Exploiting, and Policing Market Boundaries, Health Aff., Mar.-Apr. 2000, at 173, 173.
    • (2000) Health Aff. , pp. 173
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 61
    • 0026705265 scopus 로고
    • Poorer is Riskier
    • 333
    • John D. Graham et al., Poorer is Riskier, 12 Risk Analysis 333, 334 (1992);
    • (1992) Risk Analysis , vol.12 , pp. 334
    • Graham, J.D.1
  • 62
    • 0032478951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Socioeconomic Factors, Health Behaviors, and Mortality: Results from a Nationally Representative Prospective Study of U.S. Adults
    • Paula M. Lantz et al., Socioeconomic Factors, Health Behaviors, and Mortality: Results from a Nationally Representative Prospective Study of U.S. Adults, 279 JAMA 1703-08 (1998).
    • (1998) JAMA , vol.279 , pp. 1703-1708
    • Lantz, P.M.1
  • 63
    • 33947356371 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another possible explanation is that lower-income people are less likely to purchase insurance, so insurers may consider that it is not worthwhile to add that factor into an already-complex rating formula.
  • 64
    • 0034464255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Structure and Enforcement of Health Insurance Rating Reforms
    • Insurance pricing is regulated by state, not federal, law. State law regulates small-group insurance rating in much greater detail than the rating of individual ("non-group") insurance. See 376, (describing rating rules and practices for the small-group and individual markets)
    • Insurance pricing is regulated by state, not federal, law. State law regulates small-group insurance rating in much greater detail than the rating of individual ("non-group") insurance. See Mark A. Hall, The Structure and Enforcement of Health Insurance Rating Reforms, 37 Inquiry 376, 376-77 (2001) (describing rating rules and practices for the small-group and individual markets).
    • (2001) Inquiry , vol.37 , pp. 376-377
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 65
    • 0142014120 scopus 로고
    • The Political Economics of Health Insurance Market Reform
    • See Summer at 108, (discussing the insurance industry's influence over market reforms)
    • See Mark A. Hall, The Political Economics of Health Insurance Market Reform, Health Aff., Summer 1992, at 108, 119 (discussing the insurance industry's influence over market reforms).
    • (1992) Health Aff. , pp. 119
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 70
    • 33645295808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Role of State Regulation in Consumer-Driven Health Care
    • 395
    • Timothy S. Jost & Mark A. Hall, The Role of State Regulation in Consumer-Driven Health Care, 31 Am. J.L. & Med. 395, 413-14 (2005).
    • (2005) Am. J.L. & Med. , vol.31 , pp. 413-414
    • Jost, T.S.1    Hall, M.A.2
  • 73
    • 0035181103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Designing Employer Health Benefits for a Heterogeneous Workforce: Risk Adjustment and Its Alternatives
    • (describing various options for employers to allocate health care costs among employees)
    • W.E. Encinosa & T.M. Selden, Designing Employer Health Benefits for a Heterogeneous Workforce: Risk Adjustment and Its Alternatives, 38 Inquiry 270 (2001) (describing various options for employers to allocate health care costs among employees).
    • (2001) Inquiry , vol.38 , pp. 270
    • Encinosa, W.E.1    Selden, T.M.2
  • 74
    • 33947378050 scopus 로고
    • The Regulation of Private Health Insurance
    • As surveyed in in (Mark Hall ed.) federal law preempts much of this arena from state regulatory oversight and asserts little direct substantive regulation of its own. Employers' decisions to offer fringe benefits are affected indirectly by federal tax law, but tax law does not require employers to provide equal benefits to all workers. Instead, unless they self-insure, employers may favor some employees over others
    • As surveyed in Henry Greely, The Regulation of Private Health Insurance, in Health Care Corporate Law: Formation and Regulation 8-1 (Mark Hall ed., 1993), federal law preempts much of this arena from state regulatory oversight and asserts little direct substantive regulation of its own. Employers' decisions to offer fringe benefits are affected indirectly by federal tax law, but tax law does not require employers to provide equal benefits to all workers. Instead, unless they self-insure, employers may favor some employees over others.
    • (1993) Health Care Corporate Law: Formation and Regulation , pp. 1-8
    • Greely, H.1
  • 76
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice (s) In American Health Care
    • As Havighurst and Richman discuss, economists argue that workers effectively pay for all premium costs through reduced wages, because total payroll costs are constrained by market forces, and employers are economically agnostic as to whether payroll expenses are paid in the form of wages or benefits. Therefore, it largely does not matter how much of compensation goes toward health insurance. This argument is most convincing, however, only for aggregate payroll costs. The economic effects of allocating these costs among classes of employees remain more speculative. As Havighurst and Richman argue, it remains unproven whether having lower costs for the health benefits of one subset of workers would result in higher wages for those workers or whether the opposite would be true
    • As Havighurst and Richman discuss, economists argue that workers effectively pay for all premium costs through reduced wages, because total payroll costs are constrained by market forces, and employers are economically agnostic as to whether payroll expenses are paid in the form of wages or benefits. Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 44-45. Therefore, it largely does not matter how much of compensation goes toward health insurance. This argument is most convincing, however, only for aggregate payroll costs. The economic effects of allocating these costs among classes of employees remain more speculative. As Havighurst and Richman argue, it remains unproven whether having lower costs for the health benefits of one subset of workers would result in higher wages for those workers or whether the opposite would be true.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 44-45
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 77
    • 33947366476 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Distributive Injustice (s) In American Health Care
    • For instance, employers generally do not pay some equally qualified workers more simply because they elect not to receive health benefits. Therefore, it is relevant to focus on the portion of premiums charged explicitly to workers
    • Id at 46. For instance, employers generally do not pay some equally qualified workers more simply because they elect not to receive health benefits. Therefore, it is relevant to focus on the portion of premiums charged explicitly to workers.
    • (2006) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.69 , pp. 46
    • Havighurst, C.C.1    Richman, B.D.2
  • 78
    • 0027155942 scopus 로고
    • Income-Related Cost Sharing in Health Insurance
    • Spring at 21, (recommending that employers tie cost-sharing to employees' income level)
    • See Thomas Rice & Kenneth E. Thorpe, Income-Related Cost Sharing in Health Insurance, Health Aff., Spring 1993, at 21, 21 (recommending that employers tie cost-sharing to employees' income level);
    • (1993) Health Aff. , pp. 21
    • Rice, T.1    Thorpe, K.E.2
  • 79
    • 3042727061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Consumer Cost Sharing in Private Health Insurance: On the Threshold of Change
    • May available at
    • see also Veronica Goff, Consumer Cost Sharing in Private Health Insurance: On the Threshold of Change, Nat'l Health Pol'y Forum Issue Brief, May 2004, at 8, available at http://www.nhpf.org/pdfs_ib/ IB798_CostSharing.pdf;
    • (2004) Nat'l Health Pol'y Forum Issue Brief , pp. 8
    • Goff, V.1
  • 80
    • 54049089412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patient Cost-Sharing Innovations: Promises and Pitfalls
    • Jan. available at
    • Sally Trude & Joy M. Grossman, Patient Cost-Sharing Innovations: Promises and Pitfalls, Ctr. for Studying Health Sys. Change Issue Brief, Jan. 2004, at 3, available at http://www.hschange.org/CONTENT/643/.
    • (2004) Ctr. for Studying Health Sys. Change Issue Brief , pp. 3
    • Trude, S.1    Grossman, J.M.2
  • 81
    • 33846152413 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What High-Deductible Plans Look Like: Findings from a National Survey of Employers
    • W-439
    • Gary Claxton et al., What High-Deductible Plans Look Like: Findings from a National Survey of Employers, 2005 Helath Aff. (Web Exclusives) W5-434, W-439.
    • (2005) Helath Aff. (Web Exclusives)
    • Claxton, G.1
  • 82
    • 33947367013 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 4980G
    • 26 U.S.C.A. § 4980G (2003);
    • (2003) U.S.C.A. , vol.26
  • 83
    • 33947385093 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar. 6)
    • U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, http://www.ustreas.gov/offices/public-affairs/hsa/faq_basics.shtml (last visited Mar. 6, 2006).
    • (2006)
  • 84
    • 33947420564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recently, President Bush proposed allowing employers to make higher contributions to the HSAs of chronically ill employees. Press Release, White House Office of the Press Sec'y, State of the Union: Affordable and Accessible Health Care (Jan. 31), available at This proposal does not include different contributions based on income, however. Currently, this can be done only through a "section 125 cafeteria plan," also known as a flexible spending account
    • Recently, President Bush proposed allowing employers to make higher contributions to the HSAs of chronically ill employees. Press Release, White House Office of the Press Sec'y, State of the Union: Affordable and Accessible Health Care (Jan. 31, 2006), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2006/01/20060131-7.html. This proposal does not include different contributions based on income, however. Currently, this can be done only through a "section 125 cafeteria plan," also known as a flexible spending account.
    • (2006)
  • 85
    • 33947415020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar. 6)
    • See U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, supra note 52.
    • (2006)
  • 86
    • 33947369579 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar 6), This would comply with requirements for HSAs so long as the lowest deductible meets the HSA floor. For example, employers could give low-wage workers coverage with a $1000 deductible while giving high-wage workers coverage with a $5000 deductible - each group being charged the same amount for their coverage. The only constraint set by HSA law is that if the employer contributes to the HSA, it must contribute equal amounts for each employee and no more than the deductible amount
    • See U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, supra note 52. This would comply with requirements for HSAs so long as the lowest deductible meets the HSA floor. For example, employers could give low-wage workers coverage with a $1000 deductible while giving high-wage workers coverage with a $5000 deductible - each group being charged the same amount for their coverage. The only constraint set by HSA law is that if the employer contributes to the HSA, it must contribute equal amounts for each employee and no more than the deductible amount.
    • (2006)
  • 87
    • 33947407384 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra text accompanying note 52. Therefore, under this example, employers could fund only one-fifth of the deductible for higher-wage workers
    • See supra text accompanying note 52. Therefore, under this example, employers could fund only one-fifth of the deductible for higher-wage workers.
  • 88
    • 33947412467 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The most notable example is the nondiscrimination requirement for employer contributions to HSAs, which poses a regulatory barrier to implementing these new benefit structures in a way that does not overburden lower-income workers.
  • 91
    • 12144285043 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Is the Health Care Revolution Finished? - A Foreword
    • See generally (Autumn) (introducing this symposium discussing the failed potential of managed care)
    • See generally Clark C. Havighurst, Is the Health Care Revolution Finished? - A Foreword, 65 Law & Contemp. Probs. 1 (Autumn 2002) (introducing this symposium discussing the failed potential of managed care).
    • (2002) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.65 , pp. 1
    • Havighurst, C.C.1
  • 92
    • 21344442616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Death of Managed Care: A Regulatory Autopsy
    • Naturally, it is possible that managed care failed to drive substantial change because law was not more conducive to change, but most observers believe that managed care's failures were market-driven or were related to federal tax policy. (detailing the reasons for the downfall of managed care)
    • Naturally, it is possible that managed care failed to drive substantial change because law was not more conducive to change, but most observers believe that managed care's failures were market-driven or were related to federal tax policy. See Mark A. Hall, The Death of Managed Care: A Regulatory Autopsy, 30 J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. 427 (2005) (detailing the reasons for the downfall of managed care).
    • (2005) J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. , vol.30 , pp. 427
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 93
    • 0038297038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Therefore, the extent of legal resistance was never seriously tested in many arenas. See generally (analyzing legal responses to various aspects of managed care)
    • Therefore, the extent of legal resistance was never seriously tested in many arenas. See generally Peter D. Jacobson, Strangers in the Night: Law and Medicine in the Managed Care Era (2002) (analyzing legal responses to various aspects of managed care).
    • (2002) Strangers in the Night: Law and Medicine in the Managed Care Era
    • Jacobson, P.D.1
  • 94
    • 33947406955 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See text accompanying supra notes 2-4
    • See text accompanying supra notes 2-4.
  • 96
    • 0027605736 scopus 로고
    • U.S. Health Care Coverage and Costs: Historical Development and Choices for the 1990s
    • See generally Randall R. Bovbjerg et al., U.S. Health Care Coverage and Costs: Historical Development and Choices for the 1990s, 21 J.L., Med., & Ethics 141 (1993).
    • (1993) J.L., Med., & Ethics , vol.21 , pp. 141
    • Bovbjerg, R.R.1
  • 97
    • 28444451504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
    • See 1490, (documenting the highly skewed distribution of health care spending that produces this phenomenon)
    • See Mark A. Hall & Clark C. Havighurst, Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts, 24 Health Aff. 1490, 1491 (2005) (documenting the highly skewed distribution of health care spending that produces this phenomenon).
    • (2005) Health Aff. , vol.24 , pp. 1491
    • Hall, M.A.1    Havighurst, C.C.2
  • 98
    • 28444451504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
    • It is also the case, however, that most medical expenditures will still be insured. This apparent paradox is explained by the fact that the minority of people who exceed their deductible will have medical costs far above average, due to the highly-skewed distribution of medical problems across the population
    • It is also the case, however, that most medical expenditures will still be insured. This apparent paradox is explained by the fact that the minority of people who exceed their deductible will have medical costs far above average, due to the highly-skewed distribution of medical problems across the population. Id. at 1494.
    • (2005) Health Aff. , vol.24 , pp. 1494
    • Hall, M.A.1    Havighurst, C.C.2
  • 99
    • 33947389378 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra notes 2-4
    • See sources cited supra notes 2-4.
  • 101
    • 84933495832 scopus 로고
    • Health Insurers' Assessment of Medical Necessity
    • Although this failure to innovate may be due in significant part to regulatory barriers, it may also be due in large part to the important jurisprudential, relational, and expressive functions served by the standard medical-necessity concept
    • Mark A. Hall & Gerard F. Anderson, Health Insurers' Assessment of Medical Necessity, 140 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1637 (1992). Although this failure to innovate may be due in significant part to regulatory barriers, it may also be due in large part to the important jurisprudential, relational, and expressive functions served by the standard medical-necessity concept.
    • (1992) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.140 , pp. 1637
    • Hall, M.A.1    Anderson, G.F.2
  • 102
    • 33644814388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Dealing with Dying: How Insurers Can Help Patients Seeking Last-Chance Therapies (Even when the Answer Is "No")
    • See Kathy Cerminara, Dealing with Dying: How Insurers Can Help Patients Seeking Last-Chance Therapies (Even when the Answer Is "No"), 15 Health Matrix 285 (2005);
    • (2005) Health Matrix , vol.15 , pp. 285
    • Cerminara, K.1
  • 103
    • 3142673745 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Managed Care's Crimea: Medical Necessity, Therapeutic Benefit, and the Goals of Administrative Process in Health Insurance
    • 597, Health insurance contracts cover complex professional judgments made in an almost infinite array of uncertain circumstances. Therefore, they partake heavily of "relational contracting" features that are difficult or impossible to specify in advance. In general legal theory, one solution is to contract for a broad existing professional norm and to leave specification and application to largely noncontractual processes
    • William M. Sage, Managed Care's Crimea: Medical Necessity, Therapeutic Benefit, and the Goals of Administrative Process in Health Insurance, 53 Duke L.J. 597, 600-45 (2003). Health insurance contracts cover complex professional judgments made in an almost infinite array of uncertain circumstances. Therefore, they partake heavily of "relational contracting" features that are difficult or impossible to specify in advance. In general legal theory, one solution is to contract for a broad existing professional norm and to leave specification and application to largely noncontractual processes.
    • (2003) Duke L.J. , vol.53 , pp. 600-645
    • Sage, W.M.1
  • 104
    • 33947420563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Relational Contract Theory: Unanswered Questions
    • See Symposium, (detailing various applications of relational contract theory). This solution has prevailed under many types of health insurance for half a century, and it is highly doubtful that consumer-driven insurance will suddenly cause a radical change
    • See Symposium, Relational Contract Theory: Unanswered Questions, 94 Nw. U. L. Rev. 737 (2000) (detailing various applications of relational contract theory). This solution has prevailed under many types of health insurance for half a century, and it is highly doubtful that consumer-driven insurance will suddenly cause a radical change.
    • (2000) Nw. U. L. Rev. , vol.94 , pp. 737
  • 105
    • 33947417821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Most of the points in this section regarding insurers apply as well to self-insured employers, to the extent they make their own coverage determinations or review those made for them by contracted insurance administrators.
  • 106
    • 33947380724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These coverage denials will be less frequently appealed, however, because they will be for lower-cost treatments and because many patients will be able to pay for them in any event from their health savings accounts. Underscoring the latter point, the tax qualification of HSAs extends to a broad list of health-related expenditures, regardless of whether they meet the stricter definition of "medical necessity" in the accompanying insurance policy
    • These coverage denials will be less frequently appealed, however, because they will be for lower-cost treatments and because many patients will be able to pay for them in any event from their health savings accounts. Underscoring the latter point, the tax qualification of HSAs extends to a broad list of health-related expenditures, regardless of whether they meet the stricter definition of "medical necessity" in the accompanying insurance policy. See sources cited supra note 4.
  • 109
    • 33947410954 scopus 로고
    • For example, in Wickline v. State, the court reasoned: The stakes, the risks at issue, are much higher when a prospective cost containment review process is utilized than when a retrospective review process is used. A mistaken conclusion about medical necessity following retrospective review will result in the wrongful withholding of payment. An erroneous decision in a prospective review process, on the other hand, in practical consequences, results in the withholding of necessary care, potentially leading to a patient's permanent disability or death. 1630
    • For example, in Wickline v. State, the court reasoned: The stakes, the risks at issue, are much higher when a prospective cost containment review process is utilized than when a retrospective review process is used. A mistaken conclusion about medical necessity following retrospective review will result in the wrongful withholding of payment. An erroneous decision in a prospective review process, on the other hand, in practical consequences, results in the withholding of necessary care, potentially leading to a patient's permanent disability or death. 192 Cal. App. 3d 1630, 1634 (1986).
    • (1986) Cal. App. 3d , vol.192 , pp. 1634
  • 110
    • 0030308416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judicial Protection of Managed Care Consumers: An Empirical Study of Insurance Coverage Disputes
    • 1055, (documenting legal factors in coverage disputes prior to widespread managed care)
    • See Mark A. Hall, Teresa R. Smith, Michelle Naughton & Andrea Ebbers, Judicial Protection of Managed Care Consumers: An Empirical Study of Insurance Coverage Disputes, 26 Seton Hall L. Rev. 1055, 1063 (1996) (documenting legal factors in coverage disputes prior to widespread managed care).
    • (1996) Seton Hall L. Rev. , vol.26 , pp. 1063
    • Hall, M.A.1    Smith, T.R.2    Naughton, M.3    Ebbers, A.4
  • 111
    • 33947397761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
    • See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • See, e.g., Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc., 9 Fed. App'x 147, 151 (4th Cir. 2001) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund);
    • (2001) Fed. App'x , vol.9 , pp. 151
  • 112
    • 33947407806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
    • 1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
    • Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan, 144 F.3d 1014, 1020 (7th Cir. 1998) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available);
    • (1998) F.3d , vol.144 , pp. 1020
  • 113
    • 33947373562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
    • 433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co., 113 F.3d 433, 437 n.4 (3d Cir. 1997) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund);
    • (1997) F.3d , vol.113 , Issue.4 , pp. 437
  • 114
    • 33947409681 scopus 로고
    • Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
    • 1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
    • Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees, 970 F.2d 1165, 1173 (3d Cir. 1992) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict).
    • (1992) F.2d , vol.970 , pp. 1173
  • 115
    • 33947365286 scopus 로고
    • Firestone Tire & Rubber Co. v. Bruch
    • 101
    • Firestone Tire & Rubber Co. v. Bruch, 489 U.S. 101, 112 (1989).
    • (1989) U.S. , vol.489 , pp. 112
  • 116
    • 33947425328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Judicial Standard of Review in ERISA Benefit Claim Cases
    • See generally Kathryn J. Kennedy, Judicial Standard of Review in ERISA Benefit Claim Cases, 50 Am. U. L. Rev. 1083 (2001);
    • (2001) Am. U. L. Rev. , vol.50 , pp. 1083
    • Kennedy, K.J.1
  • 117
    • 33947396213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Discretionary Language, Conflicts of Interest, and Standard of Review for ERISA Disability Plans
    • Peter A. Meyers, Discretionary Language, Conflicts of Interest, and Standard of Review for ERISA Disability Plans, 28 Seattle U. L. Rev. 925 (2005).
    • (2005) Seattle U. L. Rev. , vol.28 , pp. 925
    • Meyers, P.A.1
  • 119
    • 33947397761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
    • See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (2001) Fed. App'x , vol.9 , pp. 151
  • 120
    • 33947407806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
    • 1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1998) F.3d , vol.144 , pp. 1020
  • 121
    • 33947373562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
    • 433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1997) F.3d , vol.113 , Issue.4 , pp. 437
  • 122
    • 33947409681 scopus 로고
    • Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
    • 1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1992) F.2d , vol.970 , pp. 1173
  • 123
    • 33947398148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pinto v. Reliance Standard Life Ins. Co
    • Leading cases also include 377, (3d Cir.)
    • Leading cases also include Pinto v. Reliance Standard Life Ins. Co., 214 F.3d 377, 383-84 (3d Cir. 2000)
    • (2000) F.3d , vol.214 , pp. 383-384
  • 124
    • 33947356811 scopus 로고
    • Brown v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Ala
    • and 1556, (11th Cir.)
    • and Brown v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Ala, 898 F.2d 1556, 1561-62 (11th Cir. 1990).
    • (1990) F.2d , vol.898 , pp. 1561-1562
  • 125
    • 28444451504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
    • Alternatively, an insurer might deny coverage because a different type of effective treatment is available that is substantially less costly yet still expensive. If the alternative treatment still costs as much as the deductible, however, then the insurer would enjoy all the benefits of the denial, increasing its financial conflict of interest. It is for this reason that Clark Havighurst and I propose that insurers share some portion of the savings with the patient in such circumstances - for instance, by agreeing to pay for the more expensive option if the patient will pay half the difference in cost
    • Alternatively, an insurer might deny coverage because a different type of effective treatment is available that is substantially less costly yet still expensive. If the alternative treatment still costs as much as the deductible, however, then the insurer would enjoy all the benefits of the denial, increasing its financial conflict of interest. It is for this reason that Clark Havighurst and I propose that insurers share some portion of the savings with the patient in such circumstances - for instance, by agreeing to pay for the more expensive option if the patient will pay half the difference in cost. See Hall & Havighurst, supra note 63, at 1498.
    • (2005) Health Aff. , vol.24 , pp. 1498
    • Hall, M.A.1    Havighurst, C.C.2
  • 126
    • 33947397761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
    • See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (2001) Fed. App'x , vol.9 , pp. 151
  • 127
    • 33947407806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
    • 1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1998) F.3d , vol.144 , pp. 1020
  • 128
    • 33947373562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
    • 433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1997) F.3d , vol.113 , Issue.4 , pp. 437
  • 129
    • 33947409681 scopus 로고
    • Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
    • 1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
    • See cases cited supra note 72.
    • (1992) F.2d , vol.970 , pp. 1173
  • 130
    • 33947360422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care
    • As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra and accompanying text
    • As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra note 4 and accompanying text.
    • (2005) McGeorge L. Rev. , vol.36 , pp. 551-552
    • Kaplan, R.L.1
  • 131
    • 33947402007 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year
    • As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra and accompanying text
    • As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra note 4 and accompanying text.
    • (2006) Wake Forest L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 1097
    • Larson, E.J.1    Dettmann, M.2
  • 133
    • 33751242303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract
    • In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see
    • In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see E. Haavi Morreim, High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract, 59 Vand. L. Rev. 1207 (2006).
    • (2006) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 1207
    • Haavi Morreim, E.1
  • 134
    • 33751242303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract
    • In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see This precise combination of legal and medical attributes may not be the most common scenario in which liability issues will arise under consumer-driven insurance, but this particular framing helps to focus squarely on the legal issues that are uniquely raised by this form of insurance. See also (framing and analyzing the issues similarly)
    • This precise combination of legal and medical attributes may not be the most common scenario in which liability issues will arise under consumer-driven insurance, but this particular framing helps to focus squarely on the legal issues that are uniquely raised by this form of insurance. See also id. (framing and analyzing the issues similarly).
    • (2006) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.59 , pp. 1207
    • Haavi Morreim, E.1
  • 135
    • 33947371011 scopus 로고
    • Becker v. Janiski
    • For older authorities, see 675, (N.Y. Civ. Ct.)
    • For older authorities, see Becker v. Janiski, 15 N.Y.S. 675, 677 (N.Y. Civ. Ct. 1891),
    • (1891) N.Y.S. , vol.15 , pp. 677
  • 137
    • 0023423124 scopus 로고
    • Cost Containment and the Standard of Medical Care
    • For a modern analysis, 1719
    • For a modern analysis, see E. Haavi Morreim, Cost Containment and the Standard of Medical Care, 75 Cal. L. Rev. 1719, 1724-25 (1987),
    • (1987) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.75 , pp. 1724-1725
    • Haavi Morreim, E.1
  • 138
    • 1542413206 scopus 로고
    • Wealth, Equity, and the Unitary Medical Malpractice Standard
    • 439
    • and John A. Siliciano, Wealth, Equity, and the Unitary Medical Malpractice Standard, 77 Va. L. Rev. 439, 441 (1991).
    • (1991) Va. L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 441
    • Siliciano, J.A.1
  • 139
    • 33947407805 scopus 로고
    • Tunkl v. Regents of University of California
    • 441, (Cal.)
    • Tunkl v. Regents of University of California, 383 P.2d 441, 448 (Cal. 1963);
    • (1963) P.2d , vol.383 , pp. 448
  • 140
    • 0007153097 scopus 로고
    • Fiduciary Contracting: Limitations on Bargaining Between Patients and Health Care Providers
    • 365
    • Maxwell J. Mehlman, Fiduciary Contracting: Limitations on Bargaining Between Patients and Health Care Providers, 51 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 365, 401-14 (1990);
    • (1990) U. Pitt. L. Rev. , vol.51 , pp. 401-414
    • Mehlman, M.J.1
  • 141
    • 33947428919 scopus 로고
    • Validity and Construction of Contract Exempting Hospital or Doctor from Liability for Negligence to Patient
    • Annotation
    • A.M. Swarthout, Annotation, Validity and Construction of Contract Exempting Hospital or Doctor from Liability for Negligence to Patient, 6 A.L.R.3D 704 (1966).
    • (1966) A.L.R.3D , vol.6 , pp. 704
    • Swarthout, A.M.1
  • 142
    • 33947396910 scopus 로고
    • President and Dirs. of Georgetown Coll. v. Hughes
    • See, e.g., 810, (D.C. Cir.) (rejecting complete immunity for charitable hospitals)
    • See, e.g., President and Dirs. of Georgetown Coll. v. Hughes, 130 F.2d 810,827 (D.C. Cir. 1942) (rejecting complete immunity for charitable hospitals).
    • (1942) F.2d , vol.130 , pp. 827
  • 143
    • 0028509186 scopus 로고
    • Universal Health Care and the Continued Reliance on Custom in Determining Medical Malpractice
    • 1382, (noting that courts "covertly" adjust the standard of care to resource-dependent professional customs)
    • James H. Henderson & John A. Siliciano, Universal Health Care and the Continued Reliance on Custom in Determining Medical Malpractice, 79 Cornell L. Rev. 1382, 1403 (1994) (noting that courts "covertly" adjust the standard of care to resource-dependent professional customs);
    • (1994) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 1403
    • Henderson, J.H.1    Siliciano, J.A.2
  • 144
    • 33947376630 scopus 로고
    • Hall v. Hilbun
    • 856, (Miss. Ct. App.) (considering resources in determining which localities are similar)
    • see also Hall v. Hilbun, 466 So. 2d 856, 872-73 (Miss. Ct. App. 1985) (considering resources in determining which localities are similar).
    • (1985) So. 2d , vol.466 , pp. 872-873
  • 146
    • 33646410588 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (surveying various authorities) Courts have not faced this issue for several reasons. One is that defense lawyers are reluctant to raise resource constraints as a defense because financial motivation for substandard care would likely be used by plaintiffs as a sword, even to the extent of justifying punitive damages
    • Courts have not faced this issue for several reasons. One is that defense lawyers are reluctant to raise resource constraints as a defense because financial motivation for substandard care would likely be used by plaintiffs as a sword, even to the extent of justifying punitive damages. Id at 325-26.
    • (2005) Medical Liability and Treatment Relationships , pp. 325-326
    • Hall, M.A.1    Bobinski, M.A.2    Orentlicher, D.3
  • 147
    • 33947391433 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another is that medical practices in HMOs or other resource-constrained settings do not in fact vary much from full-payment settings. See (reviewing empirical studies of HMO impacts)
    • Another is that medical practices in HMOs or other resource-constrained settings do not in fact vary much from full-payment settings. See Mark A. Hall, Mary Anne Bobinski & David Orentlicher, The Law of Health Care Finance and Organization 220-21 (2005) (reviewing empirical studies of HMO impacts).
    • (2005) The Law of Health Care Finance and Organization , pp. 220-221
    • Hall, M.A.1    Bobinski, M.A.2    Orentlicher, D.3
  • 148
    • 33947378882 scopus 로고
    • Compare Moss v. Miller
    • Research has turned up only two cases broadly on point. One suggests financial resources should matter and the second holds they should not. 1044, (Ill. App. Ct.) with Rogers v. Okin, 478 F. Supp. 1342, 1384 (D. Mass. 1979), rev'd on other grounds, Rogers v. Okin, 634 F.2d 650 (1st Cir. 1980)
    • Research has turned up only two cases broadly on point. One suggests financial resources should matter and the second holds they should not. Compare Moss v. Miller, 625 N.E.2d 1044, 1051 (Ill. App. Ct. 1993) with Rogers v. Okin, 478 F. Supp. 1342, 1384 (D. Mass. 1979), rev'd on other grounds, Rogers v. Okin, 634 F.2d 650 (1st Cir. 1980).
    • (1993) N.E.2d , vol.625 , pp. 1051
  • 149
    • 33947393752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Neither addresses patient cost-sharing. Instead, they both consider care provided for free by institutions with limited budgets. The first case reversed a defense verdict against a prisoner who alleged negligent failure to refer him to a specialist, reasoning that the jury instructions improperly suggested that "those practicing the medical arts in the penitentiary are held to [a different] standard of care." Moss
    • Neither addresses patient cost-sharing. Instead, they both consider care provided for free by institutions with limited budgets. The first case reversed a defense verdict against a prisoner who alleged negligent failure to refer him to a specialist, reasoning that the jury instructions improperly suggested that "those practicing the medical arts in the penitentiary are held to [a different] standard of care." Moss, 625 N.E.2d at 1051.
    • N.E.2d , vol.625 , pp. 1051
  • 150
    • 33947431130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The second case, however, ruled in a challenge to conditions at a state mental hospital that it was "relevant... to consider the medical resources and support facilities available" to the psychiatrists at the hospital in determining whether they used psychotropic medication reasonably. Rogers
    • The second case, however, ruled in a challenge to conditions at a state mental hospital that it was "relevant... to consider the medical resources and support facilities available" to the psychiatrists at the hospital in determining whether they used psychotropic medication reasonably. Rogers, 478 F. Supp. at 1384.
    • F. Supp. , vol.478 , pp. 1384
  • 152
    • 0022940911 scopus 로고
    • Coverage and Care for the Medically Indigent: Public and Private Options
    • 857
    • Randall R. Bovbjerg & William G. Kopit, Coverage and Care for the Medically Indigent: Public and Private Options, 19 Ind. L. Rev. 857, 916 (1986);
    • (1986) Ind. L. Rev. , vol.19 , pp. 916
    • Bovbjerg, R.R.1    Kopit, W.G.2
  • 153
    • 0025443928 scopus 로고
    • Health Care Cost Containment and the Stratification of Malpractice Law
    • Mark A. Hall, Health Care Cost Containment and the Stratification of Malpractice Law, 30 Jurimetrics J. 501-08 (1990);
    • (1990) Jurimetrics J. , vol.30 , pp. 501-508
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 154
    • 1542413206 scopus 로고
    • Wealth,Equity and the Unitary Medical Malpratice Standard
    • Siliciano, supra note 83, at 482;
    • (1991) Va L. Rev. , vol.77 , pp. 482
    • Siliciano, J.A.1
  • 155
    • 84937303381 scopus 로고
    • Medical Malpractice Law and Health Care Cost Containment
    • Note, 1297
    • Jonathan J. Frankel, Note, Medical Malpractice Law and Health Care Cost Containment, 103 Yale L.J. 1297, 1325-26 (1994).
    • (1994) Yale L.J. , vol.103 , pp. 1325-1326
    • Frankel, J.J.1
  • 156
    • 33947392687 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See sources cited supra note 90
    • See sources cited supra note 90.
  • 157
    • 33947420995 scopus 로고
    • Some support can be found in Hall v. Hilbun, which held that the skill component is uniform but that the resource component varies by similar locality. 856, (Miss. Ct. App.)
    • Some support can be found in Hall v. Hilbun, which held that the skill
    • (1985) So. 2d , vol.466 , pp. 872
  • 158
    • 33947379784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Primus v. Galgano
    • see also 236, (1st Cir.) (stating that it is permissible to consider local resources as a relevant circumstance in determining the standard of care under a uniform national standard)
    • see also Primus v. Galgano, 329 F.3d 236, 241 (1st Cir. 2003) (stating that it is permissible to consider local resources as a relevant circumstance in determining the standard of care under a uniform national standard);
    • (2003) F.3d , vol.329 , pp. 241
  • 159
    • 33947384688 scopus 로고
    • Brune v. Belinkoff
    • 793, (Mass.) (same). Support is also found in a federal statute that adjusts the standard of care according to whether treatment is consistent with Medicare payment guidelines while still requiring physicians to "exercise[] due care." 42 U.S.C. § 1320c-6(c) (2000)
    • Brune v. Belinkoff, 235 N.E.2d 793, 798 (Mass. 1968) (same). Support is also found in a federal statute that adjusts the standard of care according to whether treatment is consistent with Medicare payment guidelines while still requiring physicians to "exercise[] due care." 42 U.S.C. § 1320c-6(c) (2000);
    • (1968) N.E.2d , vol.235 , pp. 798
  • 160
    • 0026274668 scopus 로고
    • The Defensive Effect of Medical Practice Policies in Malpractice Litigation
    • 119, (Spring) (discussing the statute)
    • see Mark A. Hall, The Defensive Effect of Medical Practice Policies in Malpractice Litigation, 54 Law & Contemp. Probs. 119, 136-40 (Spring 1991) (discussing the statute);
    • (1991) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.54 , pp. 136-140
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 161
    • 33947397760 scopus 로고
    • Professional Standards Review and the Limitation of Services
    • Note, (same)
    • Leah S. Crothers, Note, Professional Standards Review and the Limitation of Services, 54 B.U. L. Rev. 931 (1974) (same).
    • (1974) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.54 , pp. 931
    • Crothers, L.S.1
  • 162
    • 0022680210 scopus 로고
    • Private Reform of Tort Law Dogma: Market Opportunities and Legal Obstacles
    • E.g., (Spring)
    • E.g., Clark C. Havighurst, Private Reform of Tort Law Dogma: Market Opportunities and Legal Obstacles, 49 Law & Contemp. Probs. 143 (Spring 1986).
    • (1986) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.49 , pp. 143
    • Havighurst, C.C.1
  • 163
    • 33947370024 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Some courts have also refused to enforce agreements to arbitrate malpractice disputes, but most courts have approved these. (surveying various authorities)
    • Some courts have also refused to enforce agreements to arbitrate malpractice disputes, but most courts have approved these. Hall, Bobinski & Orentlicher, supra note 87, at 427.
    • (2005) Medical and Treatment Relationships , pp. 427
    • Hall, M.A.1    Bobinski, M.A.2    Orentlicher, D.3
  • 164
    • 0022674763 scopus 로고
    • Contractual Revisions to Medical Malpractice Liability
    • (Spring) (reviewing relevant cases)
    • See William H. Ginsburg, Steven J. Kahn, Michael C. Thornhill & Steven C. Gambardella, Contractual Revisions to Medical Malpractice Liability, 49 Law & Contemp. Probs. 253 (Spring 1986) (reviewing relevant cases).
    • (1986) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.49 , pp. 253
    • Ginsburg, W.H.1    Kahn, S.J.2    Thornhill, M.C.3    Gambardella, S.C.4
  • 166
    • 33947415859 scopus 로고
    • Truman v. Thomas
    • Note, though, that some courts require treatment refusals to meet legal standards of informed consent. E.g., 902, (Cal.) (requiring a physician to better inform a patient of why she needed a cancer screening test that she refused on multiple occasions)
    • Note, though, that some courts require treatment refusals to meet legal standards of informed consent. E.g., Truman v. Thomas, 611 P.2d 902, 906-07 (Cal. 1980) (requiring a physician to better inform a patient of why she needed a cancer screening test that she refused on multiple occasions).
    • (1980) P.2d , vol.611 , pp. 906-907
  • 167
    • 0036319340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Discharge Against Medical Advice: Sociodemographic, Clinical and Financial Perspectives
    • Z.Y. Aliyu, Discharge Against Medical Advice: Sociodemographic, Clinical and Financial Perspectives, 56 Int'l J. Clinical Practice 325 (2002);
    • (2002) Int'l J. Clinical Practice , vol.56 , pp. 325
    • Aliyu, Z.Y.1
  • 168
    • 2942670021 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Patients Sign out Against Medical Advice (AMA): Factors Motivating Patients to Sign out AMA
    • Patricia Green, Diane Watts, Sabrina Poole & Vasant Dhopesh, Why Patients Sign out Against Medical Advice (AMA): Factors Motivating Patients to Sign out AMA, 30 Am. J. Drug & Alcohol Abuse 489 (2004);
    • (2004) Am. J. Drug & Alcohol Abuse , vol.30 , pp. 489
    • Green, P.1    Watts, D.2    Poole, S.3    Dhopesh, V.4
  • 169
    • 0025968596 scopus 로고
    • Discharges Against Medical Advice at Regional Acute Care Hospitals
    • David B. Smith & Joel L. Telles, Discharges Against Medical Advice at Regional Acute Care Hospitals, 81 Am. J. Public Health 212 (1991);
    • (1991) Am. J. Public Health , vol.81 , pp. 212
    • Smith, D.B.1    Telles, J.L.2
  • 170
    • 0031718383 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Patients Discharged Against Medical Advice from a General Medicine Service
    • Saul N. Weingart, Roger B. Davis & Russell S. Phillips, Patients Discharged Against Medical Advice from a General Medicine Service, 13 J. Gen. Internal Med. 568 (1998).
    • (1998) J. Gen. Internal Med. , vol.13 , pp. 568
    • Weingart, S.N.1    Davis, R.B.2    Phillips, R.S.3
  • 171
    • 33947415019 scopus 로고
    • Baxley v. Rosenblum
    • E.g., 502, (S.C. Ct. App.) (upholding assumption-of-risk instruction when a patient, who also was a physician, refused a treatment option recommended by his doctor)
    • E.g., Baxley v. Rosenblum, 400 S.E.2d 502,508 (S.C. Ct. App. 1991) (upholding assumption-of-risk instruction when a patient, who also was a physician, refused a treatment option recommended by his doctor).
    • (1991) S.E.2d , vol.400 , pp. 508
  • 172
    • 33947371814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Contributory Negligence, Comparative Negligence, or Assumption of Risk, Other than Failing to Reveal Medical History or Follow Instructions, as Defense in Action Against Physician or Surgeon for Medical Malpractice
    • Other examples arise in cases of Jehovah's Witnesses who refuse blood transfusions. See generally Annotation
    • Other examples arise in cases of Jehovah's Witnesses who refuse blood transfusions. See generally Kurtis A. Kemper, Annotation, Contributory Negligence, Comparative Negligence, or Assumption of Risk, Other than Failing to Reveal Medical History or Follow Instructions, as Defense in Action Against Physician or Surgeon for Medical Malpractice, 108 A.L.R.5TH 385 (2005).
    • (2005) A.L.R.5TH , vol.108 , pp. 385
    • Kemper, K.A.1
  • 173
    • 0036054041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Legal Liability Regime: How Well Is It Doing in Assuring Quality, Accounting for Costs, and Coping with an Evolving Reality in the Health Care Marketplace?
    • 125, (discussing various ways in which the law accommodates "medical pluralism")
    • See James F. Blumsein, The Legal Liability Regime: How Well Is It Doing in Assuring Quality, Accounting for Costs, and Coping with an Evolving Reality in the Health Care Marketplace?, 11 Annals Health L. 125, 133-34 (2002) (discussing various ways in which the law accommodates "medical pluralism").
    • (2002) Annals Health L. , vol.11 , pp. 133-134
    • Blumsein, J.F.1
  • 174
    • 1242287573 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Winners and Losers
    • See, for example, the following account by a physician who was sued for following a conservative approach to screening for prostate cancer, as recommended by national guidelines. 15, ("The jury sent a message... that they didn't believe in the national guidelines")
    • See, for example, the following account by a physician who was sued for following a conservative approach to screening for prostate cancer, as recommended by national guidelines. Daniel Merenstein, Winners and Losers, 291 JAMA 15, 16 (2004) ("The jury sent a message... that they didn't believe in the national guidelines.").
    • (2004) JAMA , vol.291 , pp. 16
    • Merenstein, D.1
  • 175
    • 33947393751 scopus 로고
    • Schneider v. Revici
    • Cf., e.g., 987, (2d Cir.) (signing an informed consent form for unorthodox cancer treatment created a jury question regarding patient's assumption of risk)
    • Cf., e.g., Schneider v. Revici, 817 F.2d 987, 996 (2d Cir. 1987) (signing an informed consent form for unorthodox cancer treatment created a jury question regarding patient's assumption of risk).
    • (1987) F.2d , vol.817 , pp. 996
  • 176
    • 33947393751 scopus 로고
    • Schneider v. Revici
    • See, e.g., (permitting jury to find that unorthodox treatment was acceptable despite testimony that the practitioner was a "quack" and "one of the cruelest killers in the United States")
    • See, e.g., id at 993 (permitting jury to find that unorthodox treatment was acceptable despite testimony that the practitioner was a "quack" and "one of the cruelest killers in the United States").
    • (1987) F.2d , vol.817 , pp. 993
  • 178
    • 0025443958 scopus 로고
    • Hard Choices: Patient Autonomy in an Era of Health Care Cost Containment
    • 483
    • Mathew Gregory, Hard Choices: Patient Autonomy in an Era of Health Care Cost Containment, 30 Jurimetrics J. 483, 499 (1990);
    • (1990) Jurimetrics J. , vol.30 , pp. 499
    • Gregory, M.1
  • 179
    • 0000426727 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Theory of Economic Informed Consent
    • 511
    • Mark A. Hall, A Theory of Economic Informed Consent, 31 U. Ga. L. Rev. 511, 528-33 (1997).
    • (1997) U. Ga. L. Rev. , vol.31 , pp. 528-533
    • Hall, M.A.1
  • 181
    • 33947431765 scopus 로고
    • Hurley v. Eddingfield
    • For instance, the leading case on a physician's freedom to refuse patients is a century old. (Ind.) (holding that a physician need not give any justification for refusing to treat a patient who subsequently died). The core of medical malpractice doctrine remains largely unchanged from the nineteenth century, other than the locality component of the standard of care
    • For instance, the leading case on a physician's freedom to refuse patients is a century old. Hurley v. Eddingfield, 59 N.E. 1058 (Ind. 1901) (holding that a physician need not give any justification for refusing to treat a patient who subsequently died). The core of medical malpractice doctrine remains largely unchanged from the nineteenth century, other than the locality component of the standard of care.
    • (1901) N.E. , vol.59 , pp. 1058


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.