-
1
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
7, (Autumn)
-
Clark C. Havighurst & Barak D. Richman, Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 7, 8 (Autumn 2006).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 8
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
2
-
-
17444413178
-
-
See generally (Regina E. Herzlinger ed.), (providing extensive overview of consumer-driven health care policies)
-
See generally Consumer-Driven Health Care: Implications for Providers, Payers and Policy Makers (Regina E. Herzlinger ed., 2004) (providing extensive overview of consumer-driven health care policies);
-
(2004)
Consumer-Driven Health Care: Implications for Providers, Payers and Policy Makers
-
-
-
3
-
-
1942478618
-
Reinvention of Health Insurance in the Consumer Era
-
(same)
-
James C. Robinson, Reinvention of Health Insurance in the Consumer Era, 291 JAMA 1880 (2004) (same);
-
(2004)
JAMA
, vol.291
, pp. 1880
-
-
Robinson, J.C.1
-
4
-
-
33947396214
-
The Promise and Peril of Ownership Society Health Care Policy
-
(analyzing the claims made by proponents of consumer-driven health care)
-
Amy B. Monahan, The Promise and Peril of Ownership Society Health Care Policy, 80 Tul. L. Rev. 777 (2006) (analyzing the claims made by proponents of consumer-driven health care).
-
(2006)
Tul. L. Rev.
, vol.80
, pp. 777
-
-
Monahan, S.B.1
-
5
-
-
33947404944
-
-
The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 § 1201
-
The Medicare Prescription Drug, Improvement, and Modernization Act of 2003 § 1201, 26 U.S.C.A. § 223 (2003).
-
(2003)
U.S.C.A.
, vol.26
, pp. 223
-
-
-
6
-
-
33947360422
-
Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care
-
536
-
Richard L. Kaplan, Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care, 36 McGeorge L. Rev. 536, 551-52 (2005);
-
(2005)
McGeorge L. Rev.
, vol.36
, pp. 551-552
-
-
Kaplan, R.L.1
-
7
-
-
33947402007
-
The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year
-
1087, These numbers are not precise because they are adjusted each year for inflation
-
Edward J. Larson & Marc Dettmann, The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year, 40 Wake Forest L. Rev. 1087, 1097 (2006). These numbers are not precise because they are adjusted each year for inflation.
-
(2006)
Wake Forest L. Rev.
, vol.40
, pp. 1097
-
-
Larson, E.J.1
Dettmann, M.2
-
8
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
See (Autumn) (supporting "proposals to let consumers... choose more or less freely the style of health care they want to purchase for their families"). To the surprise of many, they are also amenable to a single-payer government insurance system
-
See Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 79 (supporting "proposals to let consumers... choose more or less freely the style of health care they want to purchase for their families"). To the surprise of many, they are also amenable to a single-payer government insurance system.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 79
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
9
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
(Autumn) ("Indeed, we would not object if our [arguments]... were cited as a reason to adopt a monolithic national health program."). Still, they insist that those who are well-off remain free to purchase supplemental coverage that provides a higher tier of service
-
See id. ("Indeed, we would not object if our [arguments]... were cited as a reason to adopt a monolithic national health program."). Still, they insist that those who are well-off remain free to purchase supplemental coverage that provides a higher tier of service.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 79
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
10
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
See (Autumn) (expressing openness to "scrapping private health insurance altogether (except insofar as it might supplement the national system's coverage)")
-
See id. (expressing openness to "scrapping private health insurance altogether (except insofar as it might supplement the national system's coverage)").
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 79
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
11
-
-
33947367453
-
Distributional Considerations in the Overregulation of Health Professionals, Health Facilities, and Health Plans
-
Others in this symposium consider public insurance and government regulation of providers. See, e.g., (Autumn)
-
Others in this symposium consider public insurance and government regulation of providers. See, e.g., Christopher J. Conover, Distributional Considerations in the Overregulation of Health Professionals, Health Facilities, and Health Plans, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 181 (Autumn 2006);
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 181
-
-
Conover, C.J.1
-
12
-
-
33947399786
-
The Political Economy of Unfairness in U.S. Health Policy
-
(Autumn)
-
Jonathan Oberlander, The Political Economy of Unfairness in U.S. Health Policy, 69 Law & Contemp. Probs. 245 (Autumn 2006).
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 245
-
-
Oberlander, J.1
-
15
-
-
32044444367
-
The Precarious Pricing System for Hospital Services
-
45
-
Christopher P. Tompkins, Stuart H. Altman & Efrat Eilat, The Precarious Pricing System for Hospital Services, 25 Health Aff. 45, 52 (2006).
-
(2006)
Health Aff.
, vol.25
, pp. 52
-
-
Tompkins, C.P.1
Altman, S.H.2
Eilat, E.3
-
16
-
-
33947397762
-
Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?
-
26
-
Kenneth T. Bowden, Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?, 34 Brief 26, 28 (2005);
-
(2005)
Brief
, vol.34
, pp. 28
-
-
Bowden, K.T.1
-
17
-
-
32044433779
-
The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy
-
57
-
Uwe E. Reinhardt, The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy, 25 Health Aff. 57, 62 (2006);
-
(2006)
Health Aff.
, vol.25
, pp. 62
-
-
Reinhardt, U.E.1
-
18
-
-
33947390125
-
Hospitals Sock Uninsured with Much Bigger Bills
-
Feb. 25
-
Julie Appleby, Hospitals Sock Uninsured with Much Bigger Bills, USA Today, Feb. 25, 2004, at B1;
-
(2004)
USA Today
-
-
Appleby, J.1
-
19
-
-
32044451673
-
Anatomy of a Hospital Bill
-
Sept. 21
-
Lucette Lagnado, Anatomy of a Hospital Bill, Wall St. J., Sept. 21, 2004, at B1.
-
(2004)
Wall St. J.
-
-
Lagnado, L.1
-
20
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
(Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
-
Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 13-82. These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 13-82
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
21
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
(Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
-
See id. at 71-72.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 71-72
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
22
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice(s) In American Health Care
-
(Autumn). These factors include the following: (1) the charitable mission of most nonprofit hospitals, which encourages them to support various collective goods, (2) the ability of public and private insurers to insist on deep discounts that eliminate pricing support for collective goods, and (3) hospitals' market power over the uninsured. Also relevant are regulatory barriers to hospitals regularly offering non-negotiated price discounts
-
Id. at 72.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 72
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
23
-
-
33947422220
-
Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation
-
For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Sept
-
For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Richard G. Stuhan, Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation, Health Lawyer News, Sept. 2005, at 18.
-
(2005)
Health Lawyer News
, pp. 18
-
-
Stuhan, R.G.1
-
24
-
-
33947422220
-
Decisions to Date on Dispositive Motions in the Charity Care Litigation
-
For instance, federal courts have refused to certify a class, have found an absence of any federal cause of action, or have declined supplemental jurisdiction over state-law breach-of-contract claims. Moreover, courts have dismissed some contract claims on res judicata grounds when the claim was previously settled through normal collection processes. Sept
-
Id.
-
(2005)
Health Lawyer News
, pp. 18
-
-
Stuhan, R.G.1
-
25
-
-
33947420565
-
Temple Univ. Hosp. v. Healthcare Management Alternatives
-
501, (Pa. Super. Ct.)
-
Temple Univ. Hosp. v. Healthcare Management Alternatives, 832 A.2d 501, 508 (Pa. Super. Ct. 2003);
-
(2003)
A.2d
, vol.832
, pp. 508
-
-
-
26
-
-
33947415455
-
River Park Hosp. v. Bluecross Blueshield of Tenn
-
43, (Tenn.)
-
River Park Hosp. v. Bluecross Blueshield of Tenn., 173 S.W.3d 43, 58 (Tenn. 2003).
-
(2003)
S.W.3d
, vol.173
, pp. 58
-
-
-
27
-
-
33947397762
-
Determining a Reasonable Price for Health Care in the United States: Is This Possible?
-
Bowden, supra note 10, at 29;
-
(2005)
Brief
, vol.34
, pp. 29
-
-
Bowden, K.T.1
-
28
-
-
32044433779
-
The Pricing of U.S. Hospital Services: Chaos Behind a Veil of Secrecy
-
Reinhardt, supra note 10, at 62;
-
(2006)
Health Aff.
, vol.25
, pp. 62
-
-
Reinhardt, U.E.1
-
30
-
-
84942948238
-
Legal Responsibility for Medical Malpractice
-
Enacted about 2030 B. C., the Code of Hammurabi declared, for instance: If a doctor has cured the shattered limb of a gentleman or has cured the diseased bowel, the patient shall give five shekels of silver to the doctor. If it is the son of a poor man he shall give three shekels of silver. If a gentleman's servant, the master of the slave shall give two shekels of silver to the doctor. 942, It is not entirely clear, though, whether these rules were based on ability to pay rather than on the social value of the service to different classes of patients
-
Enacted about 2030 B. C., the Code of Hammurabi declared, for instance: If a doctor has cured the shattered limb of a gentleman or has cured the diseased bowel, the patient shall give five shekels of silver to the doctor. If it is the son of a poor man he shall give three shekels of silver. If a gentleman's servant, the master of the slave shall give two shekels of silver to the doctor. Hubert W. Smith, Legal Responsibility for Medical Malpractice, 116 JAMA 942, 943 (1941). It is not entirely clear, though, whether these rules were based on ability to pay rather than on the social value of the service to different classes of patients.
-
(1941)
JAMA
, vol.116
, pp. 943
-
-
Smith, H.W.1
-
31
-
-
0342793437
-
-
The historical and legal bases for barring physicians from suing for fees has not been studied as thoroughly as it has been for lawyers. For physicians, the best scholarly discussion is well over a century old. 10-14, (Arno Press 1973)
-
The historical and legal bases for barring physicians from suing for fees has not been studied as thoroughly as it has been for lawyers. For physicians, the best scholarly discussion is well over a century old. John Ordronaux, The Jurisprudence of Medicine in its Relations to the Law of Contracts, Torts, and Evidende 10-14, 34-41 (Arno Press 1973) (1869).
-
(1869)
The Jurisprudence of Medicine in Its Relations to the Law of Contracts, Torts, and Evidende
, pp. 34-41
-
-
Ordronaux, J.1
-
32
-
-
0003577958
-
-
It appears that medieval Roman law codified the ancient practice based in part on concerns that physicians were overcharging their patients. (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985)
-
It appears that medieval Roman law codified the ancient practice based in part on concerns that physicians were overcharging their patients. Thomas Percival, Medical Ethics: Or a Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons 175-76 (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985) (1803).
-
(1803)
Medical Ethics: Ora Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons
, pp. 175-176
-
-
Percival, T.1
-
33
-
-
0003577958
-
-
In Renaissance England, the rule appears to be based more on the notion of legal recognition of professional norms, that is, refusing to find an implied promise to pay when the common practice at the time was to receive honoraria. However, it seems there was no rule barring physicians from making and enforcing an express contract. (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985)
-
In Renaissance England, the rule appears to be based more on the notion of legal recognition of professional norms, that is, refusing to find an implied promise to pay when the common practice at the time was to receive honoraria. However, it seems there was no rule barring physicians from making and enforcing an express contract. Id. at 177-78;
-
(1803)
Medical Ethics: Ora Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons
, pp. 177-178
-
-
Percival, T.1
-
34
-
-
33947433354
-
Rondel v. Worsley
-
191, (Lord Morris), 280 (Lord Upjohn) (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2002) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.)
-
Rondel v. Worsley, [1969] 1 A.C. 191, 237 (Lord Morris), 280 (Lord Upjohn) (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2002) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.).
-
(1969)
A.C.
, vol.1
, pp. 237
-
-
-
35
-
-
0041577670
-
-
In ancient Rome, lawyers and other "liberal arts" practitioners from the nobility undertook service pursuant to a "mandate," meaning that their services were required without compensation. This understanding arose from the social order among the Roman nobility that regarded public service as one of the duties of citizenship and that assumed that other nobles would reciprocate in kind with their services, as the need arose. See
-
In ancient Rome, lawyers and other "liberal arts" practitioners from the nobility undertook service pursuant to a "mandate," meaning that their services were required without compensation. This understanding arose from the social order among the Roman nobility that regarded public service as one of the duties of citizenship and that assumed that other nobles would reciprocate in kind with their services, as the need arose. See Barry Nicholas, An Introduction to Roman Law 187-89 (1962);
-
(1962)
An Introduction to Roman Law
, pp. 187-189
-
-
Nicholas, B.1
-
37
-
-
0003761921
-
-
British barristers adopted the convention of voluntary honoraria rather than contractual fees, in part in order to elevate their social and professional standing over solicitors and attorneys
-
Reinhard Zimmerman, The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition 413-20 (1996). British barristers adopted the convention of voluntary honoraria rather than contractual fees, in part in order to elevate their social and professional standing over solicitors and attorneys.
-
(1996)
The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition
, pp. 413-420
-
-
Zimmerman, R.1
-
39
-
-
0346930919
-
-
These legal characterizations were largely just formalities, however, in that both in England and in ancient Rome, lawyers usually expected to receive their standard payment before they took a case. Also, they sometimes could sue for payment on legal grounds other than ordinary contract, such as quantum meruit (equity) or to enforce a sealed bond given in exchange for service
-
These legal characterizations were largely just formalities, however, in that both in England and in ancient Rome, lawyers usually expected to receive their standard payment before they took a case. Also, they sometimes could sue for payment on legal grounds other than ordinary contract, such as quantum meruit (equity) or to enforce a sealed bond given in exchange for service. Id.
-
(1986)
The Legal Profession and the Common Law: Historical Essays
, pp. 119
-
-
Baker, J.H.1
-
40
-
-
0003577958
-
-
Thomas Percival, for instance, in his seminal Medical Ethics, carefully refers to physicians' payments as "pecuniary acknowledgements" rather than as fees, charges, or the like at 39-40 (Birmingham: Classics of Medicine 1985)
-
Thomas Percival, for instance, in his seminal Medical Ethics, carefully refers to physicians' payments as "pecuniary acknowledgements" rather than as fees, charges, or the like. Percival, supra note 19, at 39-40, 174-79.
-
(1803)
Medical Ethics: Ora Code of Institutes and Precepts Adapted to the Professional Conduct of Physicians and Surgeons
, pp. 174-179
-
-
Percival, T.1
-
41
-
-
84924177265
-
Rondel v. Worsley
-
Lawyers never fully adopted this part of the creed. Instead, the practice among barristers was to insist on payment of their usual fee in advance, before taking on a case. Only in criminal cases were barristers required to work without pay. This prepayment practice obviated the need to sue for fees, which legal historians speculate made it convenient for barristers to adopt the non-enforceability doctrine as a means of elevating their professional standing. Later, barristers used the noncontractual basis of legal services to argue for immunity from tort liability. See (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2000) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.)
-
Lawyers never fully adopted this part of the creed. Instead, the practice among barristers was to insist on payment of their usual fee in advance, before taking on a case. Only in criminal cases were barristers required to work without pay. This prepayment practice obviated the need to sue for fees, which legal historians speculate made it convenient for barristers to adopt the non-enforceability doctrine as a means of elevating their professional standing. Later, barristers used the noncontractual basis of legal services to argue for immunity from tort liability. See Rondel v. Worsley, [1969] 1 A.C. 191 (H.L. 1967) (appeal taken from Eng.), overruled by Arthur J.S. Hall & Co. v. Simons, (2000) 3 Eng. Rep. 673 (H.L.) (appeal taken from Scot.).
-
(1969)
A.C.
, vol.1
, pp. 191
-
-
-
44
-
-
33947368770
-
Ability to Pay as Factor in Determining Reasonableness of Charge of Physician or Surgeon
-
Annotation
-
D.E. Evins, Annotation, Ability to Pay as Factor in Determining Reasonableness of Charge of Physician or Surgeon, 97 A.L.R.2d 1232 (1964).
-
(1964)
A.L.R.2d
, vol.97
, pp. 1232
-
-
Evins, D.E.1
-
45
-
-
33947369192
-
Zumwalt v. Schwarz
-
See, e.g., 608, (Cal. Ct. App.) ("[T]here is evidence of a recognized usage, which has grown into a custom, to graduate professional charges with reference to the financial condition of the patient...."). One widespread practice was to charge the patient one month of his or her salary for a major operation
-
See, e.g., Zumwalt v. Schwarz, 297 P. 608, 610 (Cal. Ct. App. 1931) ("[T]here is evidence of a recognized usage, which has grown into a custom, to graduate professional charges with reference to the financial condition of the patient...."). One widespread practice was to charge the patient one month of his or her salary for a major operation.
-
(1931)
P.
, vol.297
, pp. 610
-
-
-
46
-
-
33947430270
-
Houda v. McDonald
-
249, (Wash.)
-
Houda v. McDonald, 294 P. 249, 251 (Wash. 1930).
-
(1930)
P.
, vol.294
, pp. 251
-
-
-
47
-
-
33947390124
-
Citron v. Fields
-
For instance, (Cal. Ct. App.) was a suit against the famous actor W.C. Fields for $12,000 in medical fees
-
For instance, Citron v. Fields, 85 P.2d 534 (Cal. Ct. App. 1938), was a suit against the famous actor W.C. Fields for $12,000 in medical fees.
-
(1938)
P.2d
, vol.85
, pp. 534
-
-
-
48
-
-
33947357914
-
Spencer v. West
-
Although courts have not specifically repudiated the rule that considers patients' ability to pay, the last reported case following this principle is 423, (La. Ct. App.)
-
Although courts have not specifically repudiated the rule that considers patients' ability to pay, the last reported case following this principle is Spencer v. West, 126 So. 2d 423, 426-27 (La. Ct. App. 1960).
-
(1960)
So. 2d
, vol.126
, pp. 426-427
-
-
-
49
-
-
33947404522
-
Anticaglia v. Lynch
-
The principle was briefly mentioned in one unreported case since then. No. 90C-11-175, 1992 WL 138983, (Del. Super. Ct. Mar. 16)
-
The principle was briefly mentioned in one unreported case since then. Anticaglia v. Lynch, No. 90C-11-175, 1992 WL 138983, at *19 (Del. Super. Ct. Mar. 16, 1992).
-
(1992)
, pp. 19
-
-
-
50
-
-
33947378051
-
Rush Presbyterian-St. Luke's Med. Ctr. v. Hellenic Republic
-
Most modern cases simply state that patients owe reasonable rates based on prevailing charges. E.g., 449, (7th Cir.)
-
Most modern cases simply state that patients owe reasonable rates based on prevailing charges. E.g., Rush Presbyterian-St. Luke's Med. Ctr. v. Hellenic Republic, 980 F.2d 449, 453-54 (7th Cir. 1992).
-
(1992)
F.2d
, vol.980
, pp. 453-454
-
-
-
51
-
-
33947429373
-
-
See, e.g., American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Op. 8.055 ("Physicians have a professional obligation to provide care to those in need, regardless of ability to pay, particularly to those in need of urgent care")
-
See, e.g., American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions with Annotations Op. 8.055 (2005) ("Physicians have a professional obligation to provide care to those in need, regardless of ability to pay, particularly to those in need of urgent care.");
-
(2005)
Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions With Annotations
-
-
-
52
-
-
0003705423
-
-
American Medical Association Council on Ethical and Judicial Affairs, Op. 9.065 ("Each physician has an obligation to share in providing care to the indigent.... Caring for the poor should be a regular part of the physician's practice schedule")
-
id Op. 9.065 ("Each physician has an obligation to share in providing care to the indigent.... Caring for the poor should be a regular part of the physician's practice schedule.").
-
(2005)
Code of Medical Ethics: Current Opinions With Annotations
-
-
-
57
-
-
0027243648
-
The Struggle for the Soul of Health Insurance
-
See (stressing the social value of community rating)
-
See Deborah Stone, The Struggle for the Soul of Health Insurance, 18 J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. 287 (1993) (stressing the social value of community rating).
-
(1993)
J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L.
, vol.18
, pp. 287
-
-
Stone, D.1
-
59
-
-
0004132001
-
-
"Medical underwriting" means that insurers in some fashion assess and price the health risk of each subscriber
-
"Medical underwriting" means that insurers in some fashion assess and price the health risk of each subscriber. Id at 16-17.
-
(1994)
Reforming Private Health Insurance
, pp. 16-17
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
60
-
-
0034146108
-
The Geography of Health Insurance Regulation: A Guide to Identifying, Exploiting, and Policing Market Boundaries
-
Mar.-Apr. at 173
-
Mark A. Hall, The Geography of Health Insurance Regulation: A Guide to Identifying, Exploiting, and Policing Market Boundaries, Health Aff., Mar.-Apr. 2000, at 173, 173.
-
(2000)
Health Aff.
, pp. 173
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
61
-
-
0026705265
-
Poorer is Riskier
-
333
-
John D. Graham et al., Poorer is Riskier, 12 Risk Analysis 333, 334 (1992);
-
(1992)
Risk Analysis
, vol.12
, pp. 334
-
-
Graham, J.D.1
-
62
-
-
0032478951
-
Socioeconomic Factors, Health Behaviors, and Mortality: Results from a Nationally Representative Prospective Study of U.S. Adults
-
Paula M. Lantz et al., Socioeconomic Factors, Health Behaviors, and Mortality: Results from a Nationally Representative Prospective Study of U.S. Adults, 279 JAMA 1703-08 (1998).
-
(1998)
JAMA
, vol.279
, pp. 1703-1708
-
-
Lantz, P.M.1
-
63
-
-
33947356371
-
-
note
-
Another possible explanation is that lower-income people are less likely to purchase insurance, so insurers may consider that it is not worthwhile to add that factor into an already-complex rating formula.
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
0034464255
-
The Structure and Enforcement of Health Insurance Rating Reforms
-
Insurance pricing is regulated by state, not federal, law. State law regulates small-group insurance rating in much greater detail than the rating of individual ("non-group") insurance. See 376, (describing rating rules and practices for the small-group and individual markets)
-
Insurance pricing is regulated by state, not federal, law. State law regulates small-group insurance rating in much greater detail than the rating of individual ("non-group") insurance. See Mark A. Hall, The Structure and Enforcement of Health Insurance Rating Reforms, 37 Inquiry 376, 376-77 (2001) (describing rating rules and practices for the small-group and individual markets).
-
(2001)
Inquiry
, vol.37
, pp. 376-377
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
65
-
-
0142014120
-
The Political Economics of Health Insurance Market Reform
-
See Summer at 108, (discussing the insurance industry's influence over market reforms)
-
See Mark A. Hall, The Political Economics of Health Insurance Market Reform, Health Aff., Summer 1992, at 108, 119 (discussing the insurance industry's influence over market reforms).
-
(1992)
Health Aff.
, pp. 119
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
70
-
-
33645295808
-
The Role of State Regulation in Consumer-Driven Health Care
-
395
-
Timothy S. Jost & Mark A. Hall, The Role of State Regulation in Consumer-Driven Health Care, 31 Am. J.L. & Med. 395, 413-14 (2005).
-
(2005)
Am. J.L. & Med.
, vol.31
, pp. 413-414
-
-
Jost, T.S.1
Hall, M.A.2
-
73
-
-
0035181103
-
Designing Employer Health Benefits for a Heterogeneous Workforce: Risk Adjustment and Its Alternatives
-
(describing various options for employers to allocate health care costs among employees)
-
W.E. Encinosa & T.M. Selden, Designing Employer Health Benefits for a Heterogeneous Workforce: Risk Adjustment and Its Alternatives, 38 Inquiry 270 (2001) (describing various options for employers to allocate health care costs among employees).
-
(2001)
Inquiry
, vol.38
, pp. 270
-
-
Encinosa, W.E.1
Selden, T.M.2
-
74
-
-
33947378050
-
The Regulation of Private Health Insurance
-
As surveyed in in (Mark Hall ed.) federal law preempts much of this arena from state regulatory oversight and asserts little direct substantive regulation of its own. Employers' decisions to offer fringe benefits are affected indirectly by federal tax law, but tax law does not require employers to provide equal benefits to all workers. Instead, unless they self-insure, employers may favor some employees over others
-
As surveyed in Henry Greely, The Regulation of Private Health Insurance, in Health Care Corporate Law: Formation and Regulation 8-1 (Mark Hall ed., 1993), federal law preempts much of this arena from state regulatory oversight and asserts little direct substantive regulation of its own. Employers' decisions to offer fringe benefits are affected indirectly by federal tax law, but tax law does not require employers to provide equal benefits to all workers. Instead, unless they self-insure, employers may favor some employees over others.
-
(1993)
Health Care Corporate Law: Formation and Regulation
, pp. 1-8
-
-
Greely, H.1
-
76
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice (s) In American Health Care
-
As Havighurst and Richman discuss, economists argue that workers effectively pay for all premium costs through reduced wages, because total payroll costs are constrained by market forces, and employers are economically agnostic as to whether payroll expenses are paid in the form of wages or benefits. Therefore, it largely does not matter how much of compensation goes toward health insurance. This argument is most convincing, however, only for aggregate payroll costs. The economic effects of allocating these costs among classes of employees remain more speculative. As Havighurst and Richman argue, it remains unproven whether having lower costs for the health benefits of one subset of workers would result in higher wages for those workers or whether the opposite would be true
-
As Havighurst and Richman discuss, economists argue that workers effectively pay for all premium costs through reduced wages, because total payroll costs are constrained by market forces, and employers are economically agnostic as to whether payroll expenses are paid in the form of wages or benefits. Havighurst & Richman, supra note 1, at 44-45. Therefore, it largely does not matter how much of compensation goes toward health insurance. This argument is most convincing, however, only for aggregate payroll costs. The economic effects of allocating these costs among classes of employees remain more speculative. As Havighurst and Richman argue, it remains unproven whether having lower costs for the health benefits of one subset of workers would result in higher wages for those workers or whether the opposite would be true.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 44-45
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
77
-
-
33947366476
-
Distributive Injustice (s) In American Health Care
-
For instance, employers generally do not pay some equally qualified workers more simply because they elect not to receive health benefits. Therefore, it is relevant to focus on the portion of premiums charged explicitly to workers
-
Id at 46. For instance, employers generally do not pay some equally qualified workers more simply because they elect not to receive health benefits. Therefore, it is relevant to focus on the portion of premiums charged explicitly to workers.
-
(2006)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.69
, pp. 46
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
Richman, B.D.2
-
78
-
-
0027155942
-
Income-Related Cost Sharing in Health Insurance
-
Spring at 21, (recommending that employers tie cost-sharing to employees' income level)
-
See Thomas Rice & Kenneth E. Thorpe, Income-Related Cost Sharing in Health Insurance, Health Aff., Spring 1993, at 21, 21 (recommending that employers tie cost-sharing to employees' income level);
-
(1993)
Health Aff.
, pp. 21
-
-
Rice, T.1
Thorpe, K.E.2
-
79
-
-
3042727061
-
Consumer Cost Sharing in Private Health Insurance: On the Threshold of Change
-
May available at
-
see also Veronica Goff, Consumer Cost Sharing in Private Health Insurance: On the Threshold of Change, Nat'l Health Pol'y Forum Issue Brief, May 2004, at 8, available at http://www.nhpf.org/pdfs_ib/ IB798_CostSharing.pdf;
-
(2004)
Nat'l Health Pol'y Forum Issue Brief
, pp. 8
-
-
Goff, V.1
-
80
-
-
54049089412
-
Patient Cost-Sharing Innovations: Promises and Pitfalls
-
Jan. available at
-
Sally Trude & Joy M. Grossman, Patient Cost-Sharing Innovations: Promises and Pitfalls, Ctr. for Studying Health Sys. Change Issue Brief, Jan. 2004, at 3, available at http://www.hschange.org/CONTENT/643/.
-
(2004)
Ctr. for Studying Health Sys. Change Issue Brief
, pp. 3
-
-
Trude, S.1
Grossman, J.M.2
-
81
-
-
33846152413
-
What High-Deductible Plans Look Like: Findings from a National Survey of Employers
-
W-439
-
Gary Claxton et al., What High-Deductible Plans Look Like: Findings from a National Survey of Employers, 2005 Helath Aff. (Web Exclusives) W5-434, W-439.
-
(2005)
Helath Aff. (Web Exclusives)
-
-
Claxton, G.1
-
82
-
-
33947367013
-
-
§ 4980G
-
26 U.S.C.A. § 4980G (2003);
-
(2003)
U.S.C.A.
, vol.26
-
-
-
83
-
-
33947385093
-
-
U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar. 6)
-
U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, http://www.ustreas.gov/offices/public-affairs/hsa/faq_basics.shtml (last visited Mar. 6, 2006).
-
(2006)
-
-
-
84
-
-
33947420564
-
-
Recently, President Bush proposed allowing employers to make higher contributions to the HSAs of chronically ill employees. Press Release, White House Office of the Press Sec'y, State of the Union: Affordable and Accessible Health Care (Jan. 31), available at This proposal does not include different contributions based on income, however. Currently, this can be done only through a "section 125 cafeteria plan," also known as a flexible spending account
-
Recently, President Bush proposed allowing employers to make higher contributions to the HSAs of chronically ill employees. Press Release, White House Office of the Press Sec'y, State of the Union: Affordable and Accessible Health Care (Jan. 31, 2006), available at http://www.whitehouse.gov/news/releases/2006/01/20060131-7.html. This proposal does not include different contributions based on income, however. Currently, this can be done only through a "section 125 cafeteria plan," also known as a flexible spending account.
-
(2006)
-
-
-
85
-
-
33947415020
-
-
U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar. 6)
-
See U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, supra note 52.
-
(2006)
-
-
-
86
-
-
33947369579
-
-
U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, HSA Frequently Asked Questions, (last visited Mar 6), This would comply with requirements for HSAs so long as the lowest deductible meets the HSA floor. For example, employers could give low-wage workers coverage with a $1000 deductible while giving high-wage workers coverage with a $5000 deductible - each group being charged the same amount for their coverage. The only constraint set by HSA law is that if the employer contributes to the HSA, it must contribute equal amounts for each employee and no more than the deductible amount
-
See U.S. Dep't of the Treasury, supra note 52. This would comply with requirements for HSAs so long as the lowest deductible meets the HSA floor. For example, employers could give low-wage workers coverage with a $1000 deductible while giving high-wage workers coverage with a $5000 deductible - each group being charged the same amount for their coverage. The only constraint set by HSA law is that if the employer contributes to the HSA, it must contribute equal amounts for each employee and no more than the deductible amount.
-
(2006)
-
-
-
87
-
-
33947407384
-
-
See supra text accompanying note 52. Therefore, under this example, employers could fund only one-fifth of the deductible for higher-wage workers
-
See supra text accompanying note 52. Therefore, under this example, employers could fund only one-fifth of the deductible for higher-wage workers.
-
-
-
-
88
-
-
33947412467
-
-
note
-
The most notable example is the nondiscrimination requirement for employer contributions to HSAs, which poses a regulatory barrier to implementing these new benefit structures in a way that does not overburden lower-income workers.
-
-
-
-
91
-
-
12144285043
-
Is the Health Care Revolution Finished? - A Foreword
-
See generally (Autumn) (introducing this symposium discussing the failed potential of managed care)
-
See generally Clark C. Havighurst, Is the Health Care Revolution Finished? - A Foreword, 65 Law & Contemp. Probs. 1 (Autumn 2002) (introducing this symposium discussing the failed potential of managed care).
-
(2002)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.65
, pp. 1
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
-
92
-
-
21344442616
-
The Death of Managed Care: A Regulatory Autopsy
-
Naturally, it is possible that managed care failed to drive substantial change because law was not more conducive to change, but most observers believe that managed care's failures were market-driven or were related to federal tax policy. (detailing the reasons for the downfall of managed care)
-
Naturally, it is possible that managed care failed to drive substantial change because law was not more conducive to change, but most observers believe that managed care's failures were market-driven or were related to federal tax policy. See Mark A. Hall, The Death of Managed Care: A Regulatory Autopsy, 30 J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L. 427 (2005) (detailing the reasons for the downfall of managed care).
-
(2005)
J. Health Pol. Pol'y & L.
, vol.30
, pp. 427
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
93
-
-
0038297038
-
-
Therefore, the extent of legal resistance was never seriously tested in many arenas. See generally (analyzing legal responses to various aspects of managed care)
-
Therefore, the extent of legal resistance was never seriously tested in many arenas. See generally Peter D. Jacobson, Strangers in the Night: Law and Medicine in the Managed Care Era (2002) (analyzing legal responses to various aspects of managed care).
-
(2002)
Strangers in the Night: Law and Medicine in the Managed Care Era
-
-
Jacobson, P.D.1
-
94
-
-
33947406955
-
-
See text accompanying supra notes 2-4
-
See text accompanying supra notes 2-4.
-
-
-
-
96
-
-
0027605736
-
U.S. Health Care Coverage and Costs: Historical Development and Choices for the 1990s
-
See generally Randall R. Bovbjerg et al., U.S. Health Care Coverage and Costs: Historical Development and Choices for the 1990s, 21 J.L., Med., & Ethics 141 (1993).
-
(1993)
J.L., Med., & Ethics
, vol.21
, pp. 141
-
-
Bovbjerg, R.R.1
-
97
-
-
28444451504
-
Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
-
See 1490, (documenting the highly skewed distribution of health care spending that produces this phenomenon)
-
See Mark A. Hall & Clark C. Havighurst, Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts, 24 Health Aff. 1490, 1491 (2005) (documenting the highly skewed distribution of health care spending that produces this phenomenon).
-
(2005)
Health Aff.
, vol.24
, pp. 1491
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Havighurst, C.C.2
-
98
-
-
28444451504
-
Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
-
It is also the case, however, that most medical expenditures will still be insured. This apparent paradox is explained by the fact that the minority of people who exceed their deductible will have medical costs far above average, due to the highly-skewed distribution of medical problems across the population
-
It is also the case, however, that most medical expenditures will still be insured. This apparent paradox is explained by the fact that the minority of people who exceed their deductible will have medical costs far above average, due to the highly-skewed distribution of medical problems across the population. Id. at 1494.
-
(2005)
Health Aff.
, vol.24
, pp. 1494
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Havighurst, C.C.2
-
99
-
-
33947389378
-
-
See sources cited supra notes 2-4
-
See sources cited supra notes 2-4.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
84933495832
-
Health Insurers' Assessment of Medical Necessity
-
Although this failure to innovate may be due in significant part to regulatory barriers, it may also be due in large part to the important jurisprudential, relational, and expressive functions served by the standard medical-necessity concept
-
Mark A. Hall & Gerard F. Anderson, Health Insurers' Assessment of Medical Necessity, 140 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1637 (1992). Although this failure to innovate may be due in significant part to regulatory barriers, it may also be due in large part to the important jurisprudential, relational, and expressive functions served by the standard medical-necessity concept.
-
(1992)
U. Pa. L. Rev.
, vol.140
, pp. 1637
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Anderson, G.F.2
-
102
-
-
33644814388
-
Dealing with Dying: How Insurers Can Help Patients Seeking Last-Chance Therapies (Even when the Answer Is "No")
-
See Kathy Cerminara, Dealing with Dying: How Insurers Can Help Patients Seeking Last-Chance Therapies (Even when the Answer Is "No"), 15 Health Matrix 285 (2005);
-
(2005)
Health Matrix
, vol.15
, pp. 285
-
-
Cerminara, K.1
-
103
-
-
3142673745
-
Managed Care's Crimea: Medical Necessity, Therapeutic Benefit, and the Goals of Administrative Process in Health Insurance
-
597, Health insurance contracts cover complex professional judgments made in an almost infinite array of uncertain circumstances. Therefore, they partake heavily of "relational contracting" features that are difficult or impossible to specify in advance. In general legal theory, one solution is to contract for a broad existing professional norm and to leave specification and application to largely noncontractual processes
-
William M. Sage, Managed Care's Crimea: Medical Necessity, Therapeutic Benefit, and the Goals of Administrative Process in Health Insurance, 53 Duke L.J. 597, 600-45 (2003). Health insurance contracts cover complex professional judgments made in an almost infinite array of uncertain circumstances. Therefore, they partake heavily of "relational contracting" features that are difficult or impossible to specify in advance. In general legal theory, one solution is to contract for a broad existing professional norm and to leave specification and application to largely noncontractual processes.
-
(2003)
Duke L.J.
, vol.53
, pp. 600-645
-
-
Sage, W.M.1
-
104
-
-
33947420563
-
Relational Contract Theory: Unanswered Questions
-
See Symposium, (detailing various applications of relational contract theory). This solution has prevailed under many types of health insurance for half a century, and it is highly doubtful that consumer-driven insurance will suddenly cause a radical change
-
See Symposium, Relational Contract Theory: Unanswered Questions, 94 Nw. U. L. Rev. 737 (2000) (detailing various applications of relational contract theory). This solution has prevailed under many types of health insurance for half a century, and it is highly doubtful that consumer-driven insurance will suddenly cause a radical change.
-
(2000)
Nw. U. L. Rev.
, vol.94
, pp. 737
-
-
-
105
-
-
33947417821
-
-
note
-
Most of the points in this section regarding insurers apply as well to self-insured employers, to the extent they make their own coverage determinations or review those made for them by contracted insurance administrators.
-
-
-
-
106
-
-
33947380724
-
-
These coverage denials will be less frequently appealed, however, because they will be for lower-cost treatments and because many patients will be able to pay for them in any event from their health savings accounts. Underscoring the latter point, the tax qualification of HSAs extends to a broad list of health-related expenditures, regardless of whether they meet the stricter definition of "medical necessity" in the accompanying insurance policy
-
These coverage denials will be less frequently appealed, however, because they will be for lower-cost treatments and because many patients will be able to pay for them in any event from their health savings accounts. Underscoring the latter point, the tax qualification of HSAs extends to a broad list of health-related expenditures, regardless of whether they meet the stricter definition of "medical necessity" in the accompanying insurance policy. See sources cited supra note 4.
-
-
-
-
109
-
-
33947410954
-
-
For example, in Wickline v. State, the court reasoned: The stakes, the risks at issue, are much higher when a prospective cost containment review process is utilized than when a retrospective review process is used. A mistaken conclusion about medical necessity following retrospective review will result in the wrongful withholding of payment. An erroneous decision in a prospective review process, on the other hand, in practical consequences, results in the withholding of necessary care, potentially leading to a patient's permanent disability or death. 1630
-
For example, in Wickline v. State, the court reasoned: The stakes, the risks at issue, are much higher when a prospective cost containment review process is utilized than when a retrospective review process is used. A mistaken conclusion about medical necessity following retrospective review will result in the wrongful withholding of payment. An erroneous decision in a prospective review process, on the other hand, in practical consequences, results in the withholding of necessary care, potentially leading to a patient's permanent disability or death. 192 Cal. App. 3d 1630, 1634 (1986).
-
(1986)
Cal. App. 3d
, vol.192
, pp. 1634
-
-
-
110
-
-
0030308416
-
Judicial Protection of Managed Care Consumers: An Empirical Study of Insurance Coverage Disputes
-
1055, (documenting legal factors in coverage disputes prior to widespread managed care)
-
See Mark A. Hall, Teresa R. Smith, Michelle Naughton & Andrea Ebbers, Judicial Protection of Managed Care Consumers: An Empirical Study of Insurance Coverage Disputes, 26 Seton Hall L. Rev. 1055, 1063 (1996) (documenting legal factors in coverage disputes prior to widespread managed care).
-
(1996)
Seton Hall L. Rev.
, vol.26
, pp. 1063
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Smith, T.R.2
Naughton, M.3
Ebbers, A.4
-
111
-
-
33947397761
-
Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
-
See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
See, e.g., Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc., 9 Fed. App'x 147, 151 (4th Cir. 2001) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund);
-
(2001)
Fed. App'x
, vol.9
, pp. 151
-
-
-
112
-
-
33947407806
-
Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
-
1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
-
Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan, 144 F.3d 1014, 1020 (7th Cir. 1998) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available);
-
(1998)
F.3d
, vol.144
, pp. 1020
-
-
-
113
-
-
33947373562
-
Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
-
433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co., 113 F.3d 433, 437 n.4 (3d Cir. 1997) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund);
-
(1997)
F.3d
, vol.113
, Issue.4
, pp. 437
-
-
-
114
-
-
33947409681
-
Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
-
1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
-
Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees, 970 F.2d 1165, 1173 (3d Cir. 1992) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict).
-
(1992)
F.2d
, vol.970
, pp. 1173
-
-
-
115
-
-
33947365286
-
Firestone Tire & Rubber Co. v. Bruch
-
101
-
Firestone Tire & Rubber Co. v. Bruch, 489 U.S. 101, 112 (1989).
-
(1989)
U.S.
, vol.489
, pp. 112
-
-
-
116
-
-
33947425328
-
Judicial Standard of Review in ERISA Benefit Claim Cases
-
See generally Kathryn J. Kennedy, Judicial Standard of Review in ERISA Benefit Claim Cases, 50 Am. U. L. Rev. 1083 (2001);
-
(2001)
Am. U. L. Rev.
, vol.50
, pp. 1083
-
-
Kennedy, K.J.1
-
117
-
-
33947396213
-
Discretionary Language, Conflicts of Interest, and Standard of Review for ERISA Disability Plans
-
Peter A. Meyers, Discretionary Language, Conflicts of Interest, and Standard of Review for ERISA Disability Plans, 28 Seattle U. L. Rev. 925 (2005).
-
(2005)
Seattle U. L. Rev.
, vol.28
, pp. 925
-
-
Meyers, P.A.1
-
119
-
-
33947397761
-
Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
-
See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(2001)
Fed. App'x
, vol.9
, pp. 151
-
-
-
120
-
-
33947407806
-
Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
-
1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1998)
F.3d
, vol.144
, pp. 1020
-
-
-
121
-
-
33947373562
-
Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
-
433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1997)
F.3d
, vol.113
, Issue.4
, pp. 437
-
-
-
122
-
-
33947409681
-
Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
-
1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1992)
F.2d
, vol.970
, pp. 1173
-
-
-
123
-
-
33947398148
-
Pinto v. Reliance Standard Life Ins. Co
-
Leading cases also include 377, (3d Cir.)
-
Leading cases also include Pinto v. Reliance Standard Life Ins. Co., 214 F.3d 377, 383-84 (3d Cir. 2000)
-
(2000)
F.3d
, vol.214
, pp. 383-384
-
-
-
124
-
-
33947356811
-
Brown v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Ala
-
and 1556, (11th Cir.)
-
and Brown v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Ala, 898 F.2d 1556, 1561-62 (11th Cir. 1990).
-
(1990)
F.2d
, vol.898
, pp. 1561-1562
-
-
-
125
-
-
28444451504
-
Reviving Managed Care with Health Savings Accounts
-
Alternatively, an insurer might deny coverage because a different type of effective treatment is available that is substantially less costly yet still expensive. If the alternative treatment still costs as much as the deductible, however, then the insurer would enjoy all the benefits of the denial, increasing its financial conflict of interest. It is for this reason that Clark Havighurst and I propose that insurers share some portion of the savings with the patient in such circumstances - for instance, by agreeing to pay for the more expensive option if the patient will pay half the difference in cost
-
Alternatively, an insurer might deny coverage because a different type of effective treatment is available that is substantially less costly yet still expensive. If the alternative treatment still costs as much as the deductible, however, then the insurer would enjoy all the benefits of the denial, increasing its financial conflict of interest. It is for this reason that Clark Havighurst and I propose that insurers share some portion of the savings with the patient in such circumstances - for instance, by agreeing to pay for the more expensive option if the patient will pay half the difference in cost. See Hall & Havighurst, supra note 63, at 1498.
-
(2005)
Health Aff.
, vol.24
, pp. 1498
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Havighurst, C.C.2
-
126
-
-
33947397761
-
Crossman v. Media Gen. Inc
-
See, e.g., 147, (4th Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(2001)
Fed. App'x
, vol.9
, pp. 151
-
-
-
127
-
-
33947407806
-
Mers v. Marriott Int'l Group Accidental Death and Dismemberment Plan
-
1014, (7th Cir.) (finding no conflict when the amount at stake is small compared to total assets available)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1998)
F.3d
, vol.144
, pp. 1020
-
-
-
128
-
-
33947373562
-
Mitchell v. Eastman Kodak Co
-
433, (3d Cir.) (finding no conflict of interest when the employer paid benefits from a dedicated trust fund)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1997)
F.3d
, vol.113
, Issue.4
, pp. 437
-
-
-
129
-
-
33947409681
-
Kotrosits v. GATX Corp. Non-Contributory Pension Plan for Salaried Employees
-
1165, (3d Cir.) (ruling that a potential future benefit to the decisionmaker is not sufficient to create a conflict)
-
See cases cited supra note 72.
-
(1992)
F.2d
, vol.970
, pp. 1173
-
-
-
130
-
-
33947360422
-
Who's Afraid of Personal Responsibility? Health Savings Accounts and the Future of American Health Care
-
As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra and accompanying text
-
As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra note 4 and accompanying text.
-
(2005)
McGeorge L. Rev.
, vol.36
, pp. 551-552
-
-
Kaplan, R.L.1
-
131
-
-
33947402007
-
The Impact of HSAs on Health Care Reform: Preliminary Results After One Year
-
As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra and accompanying text
-
As explained earlier, this is true even though most treatment costs will still be covered by insurance because insurance will primarily cover the relatively fewer situations of "catastrophic" costs that exceed the high deductible, such as hospitalizations of more than just a few days. See supra note 4 and accompanying text.
-
(2006)
Wake Forest L. Rev.
, vol.40
, pp. 1097
-
-
Larson, E.J.1
Dettmann, M.2
-
133
-
-
33751242303
-
High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract
-
In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see
-
In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see E. Haavi Morreim, High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract, 59 Vand. L. Rev. 1207 (2006).
-
(2006)
Vand. L. Rev.
, vol.59
, pp. 1207
-
-
Haavi Morreim, E.1
-
134
-
-
33751242303
-
High-Deductible Health Plans: New Twists on Old Challenges from Tort and Contract
-
In other words, this analysis purposefully avoids the informed consent aspects of the issue, such as who should raise the question of cost in considering treatment options and how cost issues should be discussed between patient and physician. For analysis of this issue, see This precise combination of legal and medical attributes may not be the most common scenario in which liability issues will arise under consumer-driven insurance, but this particular framing helps to focus squarely on the legal issues that are uniquely raised by this form of insurance. See also (framing and analyzing the issues similarly)
-
This precise combination of legal and medical attributes may not be the most common scenario in which liability issues will arise under consumer-driven insurance, but this particular framing helps to focus squarely on the legal issues that are uniquely raised by this form of insurance. See also id. (framing and analyzing the issues similarly).
-
(2006)
Vand. L. Rev.
, vol.59
, pp. 1207
-
-
Haavi Morreim, E.1
-
135
-
-
33947371011
-
Becker v. Janiski
-
For older authorities, see 675, (N.Y. Civ. Ct.)
-
For older authorities, see Becker v. Janiski, 15 N.Y.S. 675, 677 (N.Y. Civ. Ct. 1891),
-
(1891)
N.Y.S.
, vol.15
, pp. 677
-
-
-
137
-
-
0023423124
-
Cost Containment and the Standard of Medical Care
-
For a modern analysis, 1719
-
For a modern analysis, see E. Haavi Morreim, Cost Containment and the Standard of Medical Care, 75 Cal. L. Rev. 1719, 1724-25 (1987),
-
(1987)
Cal. L. Rev.
, vol.75
, pp. 1724-1725
-
-
Haavi Morreim, E.1
-
138
-
-
1542413206
-
Wealth, Equity, and the Unitary Medical Malpractice Standard
-
439
-
and John A. Siliciano, Wealth, Equity, and the Unitary Medical Malpractice Standard, 77 Va. L. Rev. 439, 441 (1991).
-
(1991)
Va. L. Rev.
, vol.77
, pp. 441
-
-
Siliciano, J.A.1
-
139
-
-
33947407805
-
Tunkl v. Regents of University of California
-
441, (Cal.)
-
Tunkl v. Regents of University of California, 383 P.2d 441, 448 (Cal. 1963);
-
(1963)
P.2d
, vol.383
, pp. 448
-
-
-
140
-
-
0007153097
-
Fiduciary Contracting: Limitations on Bargaining Between Patients and Health Care Providers
-
365
-
Maxwell J. Mehlman, Fiduciary Contracting: Limitations on Bargaining Between Patients and Health Care Providers, 51 U. Pitt. L. Rev. 365, 401-14 (1990);
-
(1990)
U. Pitt. L. Rev.
, vol.51
, pp. 401-414
-
-
Mehlman, M.J.1
-
141
-
-
33947428919
-
Validity and Construction of Contract Exempting Hospital or Doctor from Liability for Negligence to Patient
-
Annotation
-
A.M. Swarthout, Annotation, Validity and Construction of Contract Exempting Hospital or Doctor from Liability for Negligence to Patient, 6 A.L.R.3D 704 (1966).
-
(1966)
A.L.R.3D
, vol.6
, pp. 704
-
-
Swarthout, A.M.1
-
142
-
-
33947396910
-
President and Dirs. of Georgetown Coll. v. Hughes
-
See, e.g., 810, (D.C. Cir.) (rejecting complete immunity for charitable hospitals)
-
See, e.g., President and Dirs. of Georgetown Coll. v. Hughes, 130 F.2d 810,827 (D.C. Cir. 1942) (rejecting complete immunity for charitable hospitals).
-
(1942)
F.2d
, vol.130
, pp. 827
-
-
-
143
-
-
0028509186
-
Universal Health Care and the Continued Reliance on Custom in Determining Medical Malpractice
-
1382, (noting that courts "covertly" adjust the standard of care to resource-dependent professional customs)
-
James H. Henderson & John A. Siliciano, Universal Health Care and the Continued Reliance on Custom in Determining Medical Malpractice, 79 Cornell L. Rev. 1382, 1403 (1994) (noting that courts "covertly" adjust the standard of care to resource-dependent professional customs);
-
(1994)
Cornell L. Rev.
, vol.79
, pp. 1403
-
-
Henderson, J.H.1
Siliciano, J.A.2
-
144
-
-
33947376630
-
Hall v. Hilbun
-
856, (Miss. Ct. App.) (considering resources in determining which localities are similar)
-
see also Hall v. Hilbun, 466 So. 2d 856, 872-73 (Miss. Ct. App. 1985) (considering resources in determining which localities are similar).
-
(1985)
So. 2d
, vol.466
, pp. 872-873
-
-
-
146
-
-
33646410588
-
-
(surveying various authorities) Courts have not faced this issue for several reasons. One is that defense lawyers are reluctant to raise resource constraints as a defense because financial motivation for substandard care would likely be used by plaintiffs as a sword, even to the extent of justifying punitive damages
-
Courts have not faced this issue for several reasons. One is that defense lawyers are reluctant to raise resource constraints as a defense because financial motivation for substandard care would likely be used by plaintiffs as a sword, even to the extent of justifying punitive damages. Id at 325-26.
-
(2005)
Medical Liability and Treatment Relationships
, pp. 325-326
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Bobinski, M.A.2
Orentlicher, D.3
-
147
-
-
33947391433
-
-
Another is that medical practices in HMOs or other resource-constrained settings do not in fact vary much from full-payment settings. See (reviewing empirical studies of HMO impacts)
-
Another is that medical practices in HMOs or other resource-constrained settings do not in fact vary much from full-payment settings. See Mark A. Hall, Mary Anne Bobinski & David Orentlicher, The Law of Health Care Finance and Organization 220-21 (2005) (reviewing empirical studies of HMO impacts).
-
(2005)
The Law of Health Care Finance and Organization
, pp. 220-221
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Bobinski, M.A.2
Orentlicher, D.3
-
148
-
-
33947378882
-
Compare Moss v. Miller
-
Research has turned up only two cases broadly on point. One suggests financial resources should matter and the second holds they should not. 1044, (Ill. App. Ct.) with Rogers v. Okin, 478 F. Supp. 1342, 1384 (D. Mass. 1979), rev'd on other grounds, Rogers v. Okin, 634 F.2d 650 (1st Cir. 1980)
-
Research has turned up only two cases broadly on point. One suggests financial resources should matter and the second holds they should not. Compare Moss v. Miller, 625 N.E.2d 1044, 1051 (Ill. App. Ct. 1993) with Rogers v. Okin, 478 F. Supp. 1342, 1384 (D. Mass. 1979), rev'd on other grounds, Rogers v. Okin, 634 F.2d 650 (1st Cir. 1980).
-
(1993)
N.E.2d
, vol.625
, pp. 1051
-
-
-
149
-
-
33947393752
-
-
Neither addresses patient cost-sharing. Instead, they both consider care provided for free by institutions with limited budgets. The first case reversed a defense verdict against a prisoner who alleged negligent failure to refer him to a specialist, reasoning that the jury instructions improperly suggested that "those practicing the medical arts in the penitentiary are held to [a different] standard of care." Moss
-
Neither addresses patient cost-sharing. Instead, they both consider care provided for free by institutions with limited budgets. The first case reversed a defense verdict against a prisoner who alleged negligent failure to refer him to a specialist, reasoning that the jury instructions improperly suggested that "those practicing the medical arts in the penitentiary are held to [a different] standard of care." Moss, 625 N.E.2d at 1051.
-
N.E.2d
, vol.625
, pp. 1051
-
-
-
150
-
-
33947431130
-
-
The second case, however, ruled in a challenge to conditions at a state mental hospital that it was "relevant... to consider the medical resources and support facilities available" to the psychiatrists at the hospital in determining whether they used psychotropic medication reasonably. Rogers
-
The second case, however, ruled in a challenge to conditions at a state mental hospital that it was "relevant... to consider the medical resources and support facilities available" to the psychiatrists at the hospital in determining whether they used psychotropic medication reasonably. Rogers, 478 F. Supp. at 1384.
-
F. Supp.
, vol.478
, pp. 1384
-
-
-
152
-
-
0022940911
-
Coverage and Care for the Medically Indigent: Public and Private Options
-
857
-
Randall R. Bovbjerg & William G. Kopit, Coverage and Care for the Medically Indigent: Public and Private Options, 19 Ind. L. Rev. 857, 916 (1986);
-
(1986)
Ind. L. Rev.
, vol.19
, pp. 916
-
-
Bovbjerg, R.R.1
Kopit, W.G.2
-
153
-
-
0025443928
-
Health Care Cost Containment and the Stratification of Malpractice Law
-
Mark A. Hall, Health Care Cost Containment and the Stratification of Malpractice Law, 30 Jurimetrics J. 501-08 (1990);
-
(1990)
Jurimetrics J.
, vol.30
, pp. 501-508
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
154
-
-
1542413206
-
Wealth,Equity and the Unitary Medical Malpratice Standard
-
Siliciano, supra note 83, at 482;
-
(1991)
Va L. Rev.
, vol.77
, pp. 482
-
-
Siliciano, J.A.1
-
155
-
-
84937303381
-
Medical Malpractice Law and Health Care Cost Containment
-
Note, 1297
-
Jonathan J. Frankel, Note, Medical Malpractice Law and Health Care Cost Containment, 103 Yale L.J. 1297, 1325-26 (1994).
-
(1994)
Yale L.J.
, vol.103
, pp. 1325-1326
-
-
Frankel, J.J.1
-
156
-
-
33947392687
-
-
See sources cited supra note 90
-
See sources cited supra note 90.
-
-
-
-
157
-
-
33947420995
-
-
Some support can be found in Hall v. Hilbun, which held that the skill component is uniform but that the resource component varies by similar locality. 856, (Miss. Ct. App.)
-
Some support can be found in Hall v. Hilbun, which held that the skill
-
(1985)
So. 2d
, vol.466
, pp. 872
-
-
-
158
-
-
33947379784
-
Primus v. Galgano
-
see also 236, (1st Cir.) (stating that it is permissible to consider local resources as a relevant circumstance in determining the standard of care under a uniform national standard)
-
see also Primus v. Galgano, 329 F.3d 236, 241 (1st Cir. 2003) (stating that it is permissible to consider local resources as a relevant circumstance in determining the standard of care under a uniform national standard);
-
(2003)
F.3d
, vol.329
, pp. 241
-
-
-
159
-
-
33947384688
-
Brune v. Belinkoff
-
793, (Mass.) (same). Support is also found in a federal statute that adjusts the standard of care according to whether treatment is consistent with Medicare payment guidelines while still requiring physicians to "exercise[] due care." 42 U.S.C. § 1320c-6(c) (2000)
-
Brune v. Belinkoff, 235 N.E.2d 793, 798 (Mass. 1968) (same). Support is also found in a federal statute that adjusts the standard of care according to whether treatment is consistent with Medicare payment guidelines while still requiring physicians to "exercise[] due care." 42 U.S.C. § 1320c-6(c) (2000);
-
(1968)
N.E.2d
, vol.235
, pp. 798
-
-
-
160
-
-
0026274668
-
The Defensive Effect of Medical Practice Policies in Malpractice Litigation
-
119, (Spring) (discussing the statute)
-
see Mark A. Hall, The Defensive Effect of Medical Practice Policies in Malpractice Litigation, 54 Law & Contemp. Probs. 119, 136-40 (Spring 1991) (discussing the statute);
-
(1991)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.54
, pp. 136-140
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
161
-
-
33947397760
-
Professional Standards Review and the Limitation of Services
-
Note, (same)
-
Leah S. Crothers, Note, Professional Standards Review and the Limitation of Services, 54 B.U. L. Rev. 931 (1974) (same).
-
(1974)
B.U. L. Rev.
, vol.54
, pp. 931
-
-
Crothers, L.S.1
-
162
-
-
0022680210
-
Private Reform of Tort Law Dogma: Market Opportunities and Legal Obstacles
-
E.g., (Spring)
-
E.g., Clark C. Havighurst, Private Reform of Tort Law Dogma: Market Opportunities and Legal Obstacles, 49 Law & Contemp. Probs. 143 (Spring 1986).
-
(1986)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.49
, pp. 143
-
-
Havighurst, C.C.1
-
163
-
-
33947370024
-
-
Some courts have also refused to enforce agreements to arbitrate malpractice disputes, but most courts have approved these. (surveying various authorities)
-
Some courts have also refused to enforce agreements to arbitrate malpractice disputes, but most courts have approved these. Hall, Bobinski & Orentlicher, supra note 87, at 427.
-
(2005)
Medical and Treatment Relationships
, pp. 427
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
Bobinski, M.A.2
Orentlicher, D.3
-
164
-
-
0022674763
-
Contractual Revisions to Medical Malpractice Liability
-
(Spring) (reviewing relevant cases)
-
See William H. Ginsburg, Steven J. Kahn, Michael C. Thornhill & Steven C. Gambardella, Contractual Revisions to Medical Malpractice Liability, 49 Law & Contemp. Probs. 253 (Spring 1986) (reviewing relevant cases).
-
(1986)
Law & Contemp. Probs.
, vol.49
, pp. 253
-
-
Ginsburg, W.H.1
Kahn, S.J.2
Thornhill, M.C.3
Gambardella, S.C.4
-
166
-
-
33947415859
-
Truman v. Thomas
-
Note, though, that some courts require treatment refusals to meet legal standards of informed consent. E.g., 902, (Cal.) (requiring a physician to better inform a patient of why she needed a cancer screening test that she refused on multiple occasions)
-
Note, though, that some courts require treatment refusals to meet legal standards of informed consent. E.g., Truman v. Thomas, 611 P.2d 902, 906-07 (Cal. 1980) (requiring a physician to better inform a patient of why she needed a cancer screening test that she refused on multiple occasions).
-
(1980)
P.2d
, vol.611
, pp. 906-907
-
-
-
167
-
-
0036319340
-
Discharge Against Medical Advice: Sociodemographic, Clinical and Financial Perspectives
-
Z.Y. Aliyu, Discharge Against Medical Advice: Sociodemographic, Clinical and Financial Perspectives, 56 Int'l J. Clinical Practice 325 (2002);
-
(2002)
Int'l J. Clinical Practice
, vol.56
, pp. 325
-
-
Aliyu, Z.Y.1
-
168
-
-
2942670021
-
Why Patients Sign out Against Medical Advice (AMA): Factors Motivating Patients to Sign out AMA
-
Patricia Green, Diane Watts, Sabrina Poole & Vasant Dhopesh, Why Patients Sign out Against Medical Advice (AMA): Factors Motivating Patients to Sign out AMA, 30 Am. J. Drug & Alcohol Abuse 489 (2004);
-
(2004)
Am. J. Drug & Alcohol Abuse
, vol.30
, pp. 489
-
-
Green, P.1
Watts, D.2
Poole, S.3
Dhopesh, V.4
-
169
-
-
0025968596
-
Discharges Against Medical Advice at Regional Acute Care Hospitals
-
David B. Smith & Joel L. Telles, Discharges Against Medical Advice at Regional Acute Care Hospitals, 81 Am. J. Public Health 212 (1991);
-
(1991)
Am. J. Public Health
, vol.81
, pp. 212
-
-
Smith, D.B.1
Telles, J.L.2
-
170
-
-
0031718383
-
Patients Discharged Against Medical Advice from a General Medicine Service
-
Saul N. Weingart, Roger B. Davis & Russell S. Phillips, Patients Discharged Against Medical Advice from a General Medicine Service, 13 J. Gen. Internal Med. 568 (1998).
-
(1998)
J. Gen. Internal Med.
, vol.13
, pp. 568
-
-
Weingart, S.N.1
Davis, R.B.2
Phillips, R.S.3
-
171
-
-
33947415019
-
Baxley v. Rosenblum
-
E.g., 502, (S.C. Ct. App.) (upholding assumption-of-risk instruction when a patient, who also was a physician, refused a treatment option recommended by his doctor)
-
E.g., Baxley v. Rosenblum, 400 S.E.2d 502,508 (S.C. Ct. App. 1991) (upholding assumption-of-risk instruction when a patient, who also was a physician, refused a treatment option recommended by his doctor).
-
(1991)
S.E.2d
, vol.400
, pp. 508
-
-
-
172
-
-
33947371814
-
Contributory Negligence, Comparative Negligence, or Assumption of Risk, Other than Failing to Reveal Medical History or Follow Instructions, as Defense in Action Against Physician or Surgeon for Medical Malpractice
-
Other examples arise in cases of Jehovah's Witnesses who refuse blood transfusions. See generally Annotation
-
Other examples arise in cases of Jehovah's Witnesses who refuse blood transfusions. See generally Kurtis A. Kemper, Annotation, Contributory Negligence, Comparative Negligence, or Assumption of Risk, Other than Failing to Reveal Medical History or Follow Instructions, as Defense in Action Against Physician or Surgeon for Medical Malpractice, 108 A.L.R.5TH 385 (2005).
-
(2005)
A.L.R.5TH
, vol.108
, pp. 385
-
-
Kemper, K.A.1
-
173
-
-
0036054041
-
The Legal Liability Regime: How Well Is It Doing in Assuring Quality, Accounting for Costs, and Coping with an Evolving Reality in the Health Care Marketplace?
-
125, (discussing various ways in which the law accommodates "medical pluralism")
-
See James F. Blumsein, The Legal Liability Regime: How Well Is It Doing in Assuring Quality, Accounting for Costs, and Coping with an Evolving Reality in the Health Care Marketplace?, 11 Annals Health L. 125, 133-34 (2002) (discussing various ways in which the law accommodates "medical pluralism").
-
(2002)
Annals Health L.
, vol.11
, pp. 133-134
-
-
Blumsein, J.F.1
-
174
-
-
1242287573
-
Winners and Losers
-
See, for example, the following account by a physician who was sued for following a conservative approach to screening for prostate cancer, as recommended by national guidelines. 15, ("The jury sent a message... that they didn't believe in the national guidelines")
-
See, for example, the following account by a physician who was sued for following a conservative approach to screening for prostate cancer, as recommended by national guidelines. Daniel Merenstein, Winners and Losers, 291 JAMA 15, 16 (2004) ("The jury sent a message... that they didn't believe in the national guidelines.").
-
(2004)
JAMA
, vol.291
, pp. 16
-
-
Merenstein, D.1
-
175
-
-
33947393751
-
Schneider v. Revici
-
Cf., e.g., 987, (2d Cir.) (signing an informed consent form for unorthodox cancer treatment created a jury question regarding patient's assumption of risk)
-
Cf., e.g., Schneider v. Revici, 817 F.2d 987, 996 (2d Cir. 1987) (signing an informed consent form for unorthodox cancer treatment created a jury question regarding patient's assumption of risk).
-
(1987)
F.2d
, vol.817
, pp. 996
-
-
-
176
-
-
33947393751
-
Schneider v. Revici
-
See, e.g., (permitting jury to find that unorthodox treatment was acceptable despite testimony that the practitioner was a "quack" and "one of the cruelest killers in the United States")
-
See, e.g., id at 993 (permitting jury to find that unorthodox treatment was acceptable despite testimony that the practitioner was a "quack" and "one of the cruelest killers in the United States").
-
(1987)
F.2d
, vol.817
, pp. 993
-
-
-
178
-
-
0025443958
-
Hard Choices: Patient Autonomy in an Era of Health Care Cost Containment
-
483
-
Mathew Gregory, Hard Choices: Patient Autonomy in an Era of Health Care Cost Containment, 30 Jurimetrics J. 483, 499 (1990);
-
(1990)
Jurimetrics J.
, vol.30
, pp. 499
-
-
Gregory, M.1
-
179
-
-
0000426727
-
A Theory of Economic Informed Consent
-
511
-
Mark A. Hall, A Theory of Economic Informed Consent, 31 U. Ga. L. Rev. 511, 528-33 (1997).
-
(1997)
U. Ga. L. Rev.
, vol.31
, pp. 528-533
-
-
Hall, M.A.1
-
180
-
-
33947427258
-
-
Chapter 1, in 1, (Frank A. Sloan, James Blumstein & James Perrin eds.)
-
Uwe Reinhardt, Chapter 1, in Uncompensated Hospital Care: Rights and Responsibilities 1, 8 (Frank A. Sloan, James Blumstein & James Perrin eds., 1986).
-
(1986)
Uncompensated Hospital Care: Rights and Responsibilities
, pp. 8
-
-
Reinhardt, U.1
-
181
-
-
33947431765
-
Hurley v. Eddingfield
-
For instance, the leading case on a physician's freedom to refuse patients is a century old. (Ind.) (holding that a physician need not give any justification for refusing to treat a patient who subsequently died). The core of medical malpractice doctrine remains largely unchanged from the nineteenth century, other than the locality component of the standard of care
-
For instance, the leading case on a physician's freedom to refuse patients is a century old. Hurley v. Eddingfield, 59 N.E. 1058 (Ind. 1901) (holding that a physician need not give any justification for refusing to treat a patient who subsequently died). The core of medical malpractice doctrine remains largely unchanged from the nineteenth century, other than the locality component of the standard of care.
-
(1901)
N.E.
, vol.59
, pp. 1058
-
-
|