메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 103, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 705-736

Neither Machiavellian Moment nor possessive individualism: Commercial society and the defenders of the English Commonwealth

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 33645509251     PISSN: 00028762     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/2650569     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (154)

References (305)
  • 1
    • 84963041652 scopus 로고
    • Republicanism: The Career of a Concept
    • June
    • Daniel T. Rodgers, "Republicanism: The Career of a Concept," Journal of American History 79. (June 1992): 11.
    • (1992) Journal of American History , vol.79 , pp. 11
    • Rodgers, D.T.1
  • 2
    • 0038896673 scopus 로고
    • Republicanism
    • Robert E. Goodin and Philip Pettit, eds., Oxford
    • See also Knud Haakonssen, "Republicanism," in Robert E. Goodin and Philip Pettit, eds., A Companion to Contemporary Political Philosophy (Oxford, 1993), 568. Haakonssen, unlike Rodgers, does not see any diminution in the fashion for republicanism.
    • (1993) A Companion to Contemporary Political Philosophy , pp. 568
    • Haakonssen, K.1
  • 8
    • 0003453453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macpherson, Political Theory of Possessive Individualism, 1. While I dissent from Macpherson's depiction of liberalism and from Pocock's emphasis on classical republicanism, I agree with both of them that an analysis of early modern British political and social thought is essential to understanding the nature of our own political presuppositions.
    • Political Theory of Possessive Individualism , pp. 1
    • Macpherson1
  • 10
    • 0346713036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Machiavellian Moment Revisited: A Study in History and Ideology
    • March
    • see also Pocock, "The Machiavellian Moment Revisited: A Study in History and Ideology," Journal of Modern History 53 (March 1981): 49-50. Some readers might be bewildered by the extent to which I have quoted Pocock. This is because Pocock has often claimed that his critics misrepresent him. In many cases, I think he is right. To avoid that pitfall, I have relied on Pocock's own words rather than paraphrasing him.
    • (1981) Journal of Modern History , vol.53 , pp. 49-50
    • Pocock1
  • 13
    • 0004260025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Skinner and his fellow defender of republicanism, Philip Pettit, have come to maintain that liberalism was only invented in the nineteenth century. Skinner, Liberty before Liberalism, ix;
    • Liberty before Liberalism
    • Skinner1
  • 14
    • 0040300024 scopus 로고
    • Liberalism and Republicanism
    • Philip Pettit, "Liberalism and Republicanism," Australian Journal of Political Science 28 [1993]: 163. This claim can only be defended if based on an extremely restrictive and ungenerous definition of liberalism.)
    • (1993) Australian Journal of Political Science , vol.28 , pp. 163
    • Pettit, P.1
  • 15
    • 27844544590 scopus 로고
    • Marchamont Nedham and the Beginnings of English Republicanism
    • David Wootton, ed., Stanford, Calif.
    • Blair Worden, "Marchamont Nedham and the Beginnings of English Republicanism," in David Wootton, ed., Republicanism, Liberty, and Commercial Society, 1649-1776 (Stanford, Calif., 1994), 45.
    • (1994) Republicanism, Liberty, and Commercial Society, 1649-1776 , pp. 45
    • Worden, B.1
  • 17
    • 0000749038 scopus 로고
    • The Cromwellian Protectorate and the Languages of Empire
    • David Armitage, "The Cromwellian Protectorate and the Languages of Empire," Historical Journal 35 (1992): 532-33;
    • (1992) Historical Journal , vol.35 , pp. 532-533
    • Armitage, D.1
  • 18
    • 3242770030 scopus 로고
    • John Milton: Poet against Empire
    • David Armitage, Armand Himy, and Quentin Skinner, eds., Cambridge
    • Armitage, "John Milton: Poet against Empire," in David Armitage, Armand Himy, and Quentin Skinner, eds., Milton and Republicanism (Cambridge, 1995), 206.
    • (1995) Milton and Republicanism , pp. 206
    • Armitage1
  • 19
    • 33750898179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For the purposes of this essay, I have elided some very important differences between Milton and Harrington and focused instead on their similar conceptions of political economy and their rejection of contingent politics of interest. Milton, I am convinced, was much more interested in politics as a means to godliness, while Harrington saw politics much more as an end in itself.
  • 20
    • 84939525360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I use this term throughout to describe the political ideology uncovered and celebrated by Pocock. While I am aware that Pocock has warned that "republicanism in England was a language, not a programme" (Political Works of James Harrington, 15), it is quite clear that he means this only in the revisionist sense that republicanism did not cause the English Civil War, the execution of the king, or the establishment of the English Republic in 1649. Throughout his voluminous writings, he insists on certain key ideological continuities, which I will explore below. It is these continuities that, Don Herzog has rightly insisted, account for "some of the zeal animating republican revisionism," for it makes it possible to claim "that civic humanism is a valuable possibility today."
    • Political Works of James Harrington , pp. 15
  • 21
    • 54149117063 scopus 로고
    • Some Questions for Republicans
    • August
    • Herzog, "Some Questions for Republicans," Political Theory 14 (August 1986): 474.
    • (1986) Political Theory , vol.14 , pp. 474
    • Herzog1
  • 22
    • 33750911894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • From Holy Cause to Economic Interest
    • Steve Pincus and Alan Houston, eds., (Cambridge, forthcoming)
    • I argue this point at length in "From Holy Cause to Economic Interest," in Steve Pincus and Alan Houston, eds., A Nation Transformed? The Modernity of Later Seventeenth Century England (Cambridge, forthcoming).
    • A Nation Transformed? The Modernity of Later Seventeenth Century England
  • 23
    • 77953691208 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.
    • While I agree with Joyce Appleby that England in the seventeenth century was experiencing "commercialization" and that this ultimately required "the endorsement of new values," her account of how that happened is too simple. Discussions of the economy in the seventeenth century are really discussions of political economy. English men and women were not so interested in the abstract questions of modern economists as in how economic developments related to the state's promotion of the common good. Economic change was not only mediated by ideas but also by the development and massive expansion of the English state. The quotations are from Appleby, Economic Thought and Ideology in Seventeenth-Century England (Princeton, N.J., 1978), 3-4.
    • (1978) Economic Thought and Ideology in Seventeenth-Century England , pp. 3-4
    • Appleby1
  • 25
    • 0042929961 scopus 로고
    • Oxford
    • see also Michael Wilding's narrow definition of Milton's "historical context" as being the "political and ecclesiastical revolution." Wilding, Dragon's Teeth: Literature in the English Revolution (Oxford, 1987), 234. Far from being a methodology unique to one particular discipline, this is the prevailing mode of analysis in early modern British studies.
    • (1987) Dragon's Teeth: Literature in the English Revolution , pp. 234
    • Wilding1
  • 26
    • 33750909936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While this essay calls for a rethinking of liberalism, it does not offer a fleshed-out new historical account. I am planning such an account in my forthcoming book The Glorious Revolution and the Origins of Liberalism. Both in this essay and in that book, I suggest that the liberal ideas that receive their more elegant and sophisticated statements in Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill begin to emerge as a coherent political position in the seventeenth century.
  • 28
    • 0005292975 scopus 로고
    • The Republican Ideal of Political Liberty
    • Gisela Bock, Quentin Skinner, and Maurizio Viroli, eds., Cambridge
    • It should be noted that Quentin Skinner has recently argued that republican liberty was negative, not positive: "The Republican Ideal of Political Liberty," in Gisela Bock, Quentin Skinner, and Maurizio Viroli, eds., Machiavelli and Republicanism (Cambridge, 1990);
    • (1990) Machiavelli and Republicanism
  • 29
    • 0004260025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skinner, Liberty before Liberalism, 82-83. I find myself in complete sympathy with Alan Patten, who claims that Skinner's new "instrumental republicanism" is unable to articulate any "interesting disagreement between liberals and republicans" in their depictions of liberty.
    • Liberty before Liberalism , pp. 82-83
    • Skinner1
  • 30
    • 21844491148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Republican Critique of Liberalism
    • Patten, "The Republican Critique of Liberalism," British Journal of Political Science 26 (1996): 26-27.
    • (1996) British Journal of Political Science , vol.26 , pp. 26-27
    • Patten1
  • 31
    • 84871046750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skinner's response, that liberals only fear coercive restraints on liberty whereas "neo-romans" insist that "to live in a condition of dependence is in itself a source and a form of constraint" (Liberty before Liberalism, 84), fails to convince on two grounds. First, he is unable to show that there was any historical debate between early modern neo-romans and their more commercially oriented critics over this issue. Second, many liberals seem to have the same concerns.
    • Liberty before Liberalism , pp. 84
  • 32
    • 3142765543 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephen Holmes, for example, insists that the "ideal-typical liberal" "was more distressed by poverty and personal dependency . . . than by inequality of income or wealth" (Passions and Constraint, 15.) Skinner, it seems, is only able to demonstrate this distinction by reducing liberalism to "utilitarian principles"
    • Passions and Constraint , pp. 15
  • 33
    • 84871046750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Liberty before Liberalism, 96-99). I hope to show in the final section that this is a historically unwarranted distinction. Early defenders of commercial society were deeply committed to notions of the common good.
    • Liberty before Liberalism , pp. 96-99
  • 37
    • 0040233744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • English Republicanism
    • J. H. Burns, ed., Cambridge
    • See also his elegant discussion in "English Republicanism," in J. H. Burns, ed., The Cambridge History of Political Thought, 1450-1700 (Cambridge, 1991), esp. 446.
    • (1991) The Cambridge History of Political Thought, 1450-1700 , pp. 446
  • 39
    • 0042315470 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Republican Synthesis: The Emergence of an Understanding of Republicanism in American Historiography
    • Robert E. Shalhope derides those scholars who "assumed that republicanism represented simply a form of government." Shalhope, "Toward a Republican Synthesis: The Emergence of an Understanding of Republicanism in American Historiography," William and Mary Quarterly 29 (1972): 51.
    • (1972) William and Mary Quarterly , vol.29 , pp. 51
    • Shalhope1
  • 42
    • 84973206168 scopus 로고
    • "A Defence of the People of England," 1651
    • Don M. Wolfe, gen. ed., 8 vols, in 10 New Haven, Conn.
    • John Milton, "A Defence of the People of England," 1651, Complete Prose Works of John Milton, Don M. Wolfe, gen. ed., 8 vols, in 10 (New Haven, Conn., 1952-82), 4: 535.
    • (1952) Complete Prose Works of John Milton , vol.4 , pp. 535
    • Milton, J.1
  • 43
    • 84865921442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "A Second Defence of the People of England," 1654
    • John Milton, "A Second Defence of the People of England," 1654, Complete Prose Works, 4: 561. Milton also took great pride that Queen Christina of Sweden affirmed that he "had uttered no word against kings, but only against tyrants - the pests and plagues of kings."
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.4 , pp. 561
    • Milton, J.1
  • 44
  • 47
    • 0346254492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted, as Rodgers has, that there were always two schools of republicanism: "Harvard republicanism . . . and St. Louis republicanism" with very different outlooks. Rodgers, "Republicanism: The Career of a Concept," 18. It would perhaps be helpful to widen Rodgers' focus to note divisions in the debates about Italian and English republicanism as well.
    • Republicanism: The Career of a Concept , pp. 18
    • Rodgers1
  • 48
    • 33750914176 scopus 로고
    • Relocating the Vital Center
    • June
    • The exception seems to be among American labor historians. However, when pressed, Leon Fink concedes that "those of us who invoke labor republicanism as a category of nineteenth-century analysis must more carefully distinguish it from the more formal tradition of classical, civic republicanism." Fink, "Relocating the Vital Center," Journal of American History 75 (June 1988): 158. I am grateful to Bruce Nelson for calling this literature to my attention.
    • (1988) Journal of American History , vol.75 , pp. 158
    • Fink1
  • 50
    • 31444448543 scopus 로고
    • Between Gog and Magog: The Republican Thesis and the Ideologia Americana
    • April-June
    • J. G. A. Pocock, "Between Gog and Magog: The Republican Thesis and the Ideologia Americana," Journal of the History of Ideas 48 (April-June 1987): 339.
    • (1987) Journal of the History of Ideas , vol.48 , pp. 339
    • Pocock, J.G.A.1
  • 51
    • 0346713036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pocock counts himself among "the critics of the Marxian tradition," in "Machiavellian Moment Revisited," 59.
    • Machiavellian Moment Revisited , pp. 59
  • 54
    • 84939525360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is true that in his more cautious moments, Pocock says he is only critiquing a caricature of liberalism (see Political Works of James Harrington, 146;
    • Political Works of James Harrington , pp. 146
  • 55
    • 33750912352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Between Gog and Magog," 337), but he fails to provide his readers with a description of liberalism with which he would be sympathetic.
    • Between Gog and Magog , pp. 337
  • 58
    • 33750911893 scopus 로고
    • The English Republican Imagination
    • John Morrill, ed., London
    • Jonathan Scott, "The English Republican Imagination," in John Morrill, ed., Revolution and Restoration: England in the 1650s (London, 1992), 37-39;
    • (1992) Revolution and Restoration: England in the 1650s , pp. 37-39
    • Scott, J.1
  • 62
    • 1842756152 scopus 로고
    • Liberalism
    • Michael J. Sandel, ed., New York
    • Ronald Dworkin, "Liberalism," in Michael J. Sandel, ed., Liberalism and Its Critics (New York, 1984), 72-75;
    • (1984) Liberalism and Its Critics , pp. 72-75
    • Dworkin, R.1
  • 65
    • 84928838891 scopus 로고
    • Republicanism vs. Liberalism: A Reconsideration
    • Summer
    • Jeffrey C. Isaac, "Republicanism vs. Liberalism: A Reconsideration," History of Political Thought 9 (Summer 1988): 350.
    • (1988) History of Political Thought , vol.9 , pp. 350
    • Isaac, J.C.1
  • 71
    • 84974267666 scopus 로고
    • England's Cato: The Virtues and Fortunes of Algernon Sidney
    • J. G. A. Pocock, "England's Cato: The Virtues and Fortunes of Algernon Sidney," Historical Journal 37 (1994): 931, 933.
    • (1994) Historical Journal , vol.37 , pp. 931
    • Pocock, J.G.A.1
  • 72
    • 0042560306 scopus 로고
    • Toward a Republican Empire: Interest and Ideology in Revolutionary America
    • I quote from Pocock not because his is a lone voice but rather because his views have reached the level of orthodoxy. "The traditional view of political economy articulated by republican theorists at the time of the American Revolution," argue Cathy Matson and Peter Onuf, "was founded upon the premise that political right and personal virtue flowed from the ownership of hereditary and transmissible land." Republicans associated the accumulation of commercial wealth "with luxury and vice, the leading threats to good citizenship in their 'Christian Sparta.' " Matson and Onuf, "Toward a Republican Empire: Interest and Ideology in Revolutionary America," American Quarterly 37 (1985): 496, 498. In this brilliant article, Matson and Onuf argue for the breakdown of republican political economy. My only dissent is that the conditions they isolate for the breakdown occurred in the 1650s in England, and that the same ideological moves were made then, rendering the existence of such a republican synthesis concerning political economy in the late eighteenth century problematic.
    • (1985) American Quarterly , vol.37 , pp. 496
    • Matson1    Onuf2
  • 74
    • 33750913611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that, when criticized, Pocock denies that he ever said these things. He has "often been misrepresented," Pocock complains. He really said "that the republican attitude to the growth of commerce was not one of blanket opposition but one of critical evaluation." By this, he apparently means (and I hope I am being fair) that republicans "feared the 'trading interest' less than the 'monied interest,' the artisan or merchant less than the financial speculator in the availability of capital; when they criticized 'commercial society,' it was for favoring the growth of the soldier, the stockjobber, and the manipulative politician, though commercial society always found republican defenders who believed that these types could be assimilated or eliminated." Pocock, "Between Gog and Magog," 340, 343. It turns out, however, that the radical political economists of the 1650s (and beyond) defended the creation of a national bank and the development of national credit.
    • Between Gog and Magog , pp. 340
    • Pocock1
  • 77
    • 0004350787 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Unsurprisingly, "the neo-Harringtonian thesis became an instrument of radical reaction in an era of devastating economic change" (Machiavellian Moment, 422).
    • Machiavellian Moment , pp. 422
  • 78
    • 33750923243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is worth noting at this point, as I hope to show below, I find Pocock's understanding of Harrington's economic thought more persuasive than that offered by Isaac, "Liberalism versus Republicanism," 364-65;
    • Liberalism Versus Republicanism , pp. 364-365
    • Isaac1
  • 79
    • 0003773741 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and Shapiro, Political Criticism, 192-93. Both of these political theorists want to suggest that Harrington "took for granted the core tenets of the new political economy" (the phrase is Shapiro's). They are right to suggest that there were radical defenses of a new political economy; they are wrong to think that Harrington offered one.
    • Political Criticism , pp. 192-193
    • Shapiro1
  • 80
    • 33750912873 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Commonplace Book, entry dated to 1651-52
    • John Milton, Commonplace Book, entry dated to 1651-52, Complete Prose Works, 1: 414-15.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.1 , pp. 414-415
    • Milton, J.1
  • 81
    • 33750896936 scopus 로고
    • Sonnet 17
    • John T. Shawcross, ed., New York
    • Some might see Milton's Sonnet 17, praising Sir Henry Vane the younger for his ability "to advise how war may best, upheld, / Move by her two main nerves, Iron and Gold / In all her equippage," as an admission that money did indeed constitute the sinews of war. John Milton, "Sonnet 17," in John T. Shawcross, ed., The Complete English Poetry of John Milton (New York, 1963), 230. But a careful reading of the sonnet reveals that Milton is praising Vane, whom "religion . . . reckons . . . her eldest son," as uniquely virtuous. It is only with such a virtuous man at the helm that England can make proper use of iron and gold. It is not the iron and gold that generate power but their proper deployment by a man of virtue. Significantly, Vane is figured in the poem as a Roman senator leading England/Rome against the commercial republics of the Netherlands/Carthage. I am grateful to Sharon Achinstein for drawing this sonnet to my attention.
    • (1963) The Complete English Poetry of John Milton , pp. 230
    • Milton, J.1
  • 83
    • 84865918435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Readie and Easie Way to Establish a Free Commonwealth, February 22-29," 1660
    • John Milton, "The Readie and Easie Way to Establish a Free Commonwealth," February 22-29, 1660, Complete Prose Works, 7: 387. Here Milton is attacking the monarchists' defense of political economy, but the same arguments for political economy and consumption were advanced by the radicals in the Rump Parliament not six months before. It is, of course, true that Milton praised the United Provinces as a free state. But wealth, he made quite clear, could only be praised if it were the by-product, not the end goal, of a commonwealth. See 7: 357, 386.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.7 , pp. 387
    • Milton, J.1
  • 90
    • 84976048636 scopus 로고
    • Dating Milton's History of Britain
    • find myself persuaded by Nicholas Von Maltzahn's dating, as against that of Austin Woolrych. See Woolrych, "Dating Milton's History of Britain," Historical Journal 36 (1993): 929-43;
    • (1993) Historical Journal , vol.36 , pp. 929-943
    • Woolrych1
  • 91
    • 84975994704 scopus 로고
    • Dating the Digression in Milton's History of Britain
    • Von Maltzahn, "Dating the Digression in Milton's History of Britain," Historical Journal 36 (1993): 945-56.
    • (1993) Historical Journal , vol.36 , pp. 945-956
    • Von Maltzahn1
  • 92
    • 33750911892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • However, I think Milton's contempt for merchants was a constant factor in his thought. For the second quote, see Milton, "Defence of the People of England," 4: 316-17. "Citizens" in this context refers to the merchant participants in urban governments.
    • Defence of the People of England , vol.4 , pp. 316-317
    • Milton1
  • 93
    • 84865933893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Areopagitica," 1644
    • Milton, "Areopagitica," 1644, Complete Prose Works, 2: 544-45
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.2 , pp. 544-545
    • Milton1
  • 94
    • 0347984567 scopus 로고
    • Milton and Class Identity: The Publication of Areopagitica and the 1645 Poems
    • Spring
    • . I do not share the view of Ann Baynes Coiro that "Areopagitica is typical of its historical moment in its assumption, at once fearful and exhilarated, that the marketplace could come to pervade everything." Coiro, "Milton and Class Identity: The Publication of Areopagitica and the 1645 Poems," Journal of Medieval and Renaissance Studies 22 (Spring 1992): 263. Milton was ambivalent, and would become more so, about the consequences of events in the 1640s and 1650s. He welcomed the growth of political and religious liberty. He absolutely condemned the commercialization of society and ultimately blamed it for the downfall of the Commonwealth.
    • (1992) Journal of Medieval and Renaissance Studies , vol.22 , pp. 263
    • Coiro1
  • 96
    • 0005614858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Smith, Literature and Revolution in England, 195. It should be clear from the above discussion that I dissent from David Armitage's claim that Milton's critique of empire "marks a stage in the gradual transformation of the strenuous classical republicanism of the 1650s into the Whig thought of the latter part of the century." Armitage, "John Milton," 223. There were many critics of England's possessions of colonies throughout the seventeenth century. Later seventeenth-century Whig thought, however, was commercial thought. That Milton rejected commercial society made it impossible for him to be part of that transformation. There are, however, a plethora of other candidates.
    • Literature and Revolution in England , pp. 195
    • Smith1
  • 102
    • 84871308006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harrington, "Oceana," 259. The lord archon is the sole legislator of Oceana and introduced the commonwealth as a form of government to it; in this context, he is also a character whose speeches I occasionally quote.
    • Oceana , pp. 259
    • Harrington1
  • 103
    • 84871308006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harrington, "Oceana," 158. Harrington is thus compelled to argue that Venetian political culture is not truly urban.
    • Oceana , pp. 158
    • Harrington1
  • 106
    • 19944365731 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • My reading of Harrington is in sympathy with that of Rawson, Spartan Tradition, 190-91.
    • Spartan Tradition , pp. 190-191
    • Rawson1
  • 113
    • 84871308006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harrington, "Oceana," 164-65, 295. Earlier, Harrington warns that Jews were a people that would "suck the nourishment which would sustain a natural and useful member"; p. 159.
    • Oceana , pp. 164-165
    • Harrington1
  • 114
    • 33750898362 scopus 로고
    • Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq., Member in the Parliaments of Oliver and Richard Cromwell from 1656-59... with an Account of the Parliament of 1654
    • Captain Adam Baynes, March 5, 1659, in John Towill Rutt, ed., 4 vols. London
    • I do not mean to suggest that there were not other republicans who shared the agrarian and anti-commercial sentiments of Milton and Harrington, only that the hegemony of their ideological position among the radicals has been vastly overstated. For views similar to those expressed in Harrington and Milton, see Captain Adam Baynes, March 5, 1659, in John Towill Rutt, ed., Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq., Member in the Parliaments of Oliver and Richard Cromwell from 1656-59 . . . With an Account of the Parliament of 1654; From the Journal of Guibon Goddard, 4 vols. (London, 1828), 4: 31;
    • (1828) Journal of Guibon Goddard , vol.4 , pp. 31
  • 116
    • 0003803168 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge
    • I have argued this point elsewhere, as have others. Richard Tuck has also isolated "the creation of a new military organisation" as vital in forcing a shift in English political thought. See his extremely stimulating Philosophy and Government, 1572-1651 (Cambridge, 1993), 226.
    • (1993) Philosophy and Government, 1572-1651 , pp. 226
  • 117
    • 33750920988 scopus 로고
    • Anthony a Wood
    • Helen Darbishire, ed., London
    • Anthony a Wood, in Helen Darbishire, ed., The Early Lives of Milton (London, 1932), 44.
    • (1932) The Early Lives of Milton , pp. 44
  • 122
    • 33750916276 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London, 1671
    • Bethel, The Present Interest of England Stated (London, 1671), 8, 1-2. Bethel's commitment to trade, which permeates all his writings, should inform our reading of his ostensible Harringtonian defense of balance: "That as the house of Lords had anciently a natural right to a superior jurisdiction, in that their propriety was five parts of six, in the whole nation: so is it now more natural for the commons, to have that superiority; their proportion of propriety being ninety nine parts or more, of a hundred. And therefore moved, that if they would have another house, it might be so bounded as might suit with the people's interest."
    • The Present Interest of England Stated , pp. 8
    • Bethel1
  • 123
    • 33750905192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London, 1659
    • Slingsby Bethel, A True and Impartial Narrative (London, 1659), 8. Given Bethel's consistent ideological defense of commerce, we must read "propriety" and "interest" to include movable goods as well as real property.
    • A True and Impartial Narrative , pp. 8
    • Bethel, S.1
  • 127
    • 33750906500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • January 27, 1658 (1658), postscript
    • Samuel Lambe, Seasonable Observations, January 27, 1658 (1658), postscript, pp. 1-2.
    • Seasonable Observations , pp. 1-2
    • Lambe, S.1
  • 130
  • 131
    • 33750896185 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London, 1659
    • The Grand Concernments of England Ensured (London, 1659), 32. This pamphlet was originally conceived as a commonwealthsman's response to royalist pamphleteering, especially that of John Fell. See also Long Parliament-Work (London, 1659), 13-14.
    • Long Parliament-Work , pp. 13-14
  • 137
    • 33750905364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Henry Neville, February 21, 1659, in Rutt, Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq., 3: 388; Charles Lloyd, February 21, 1659, in Rutt, 3: 392. See also Major Beake, February 24, 1659, Rutt, 3: 472
    • Henry Neville, February 21, 1659, in Rutt, Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq., 3: 388; Charles Lloyd, February 21, 1659, in Rutt, 3: 392. See also Major Beake, February 24, 1659, Rutt, 3: 472.
  • 141
    • 33750920765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I have found a rather fuller defense of Athens than Rawson allows, Spartan Tradition, 199-200
    • I have found a rather fuller defense of Athens than Rawson allows, Spartan Tradition, 199-200.
  • 143
    • 33750919364 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nedham specifically contrasts the exclusivity of the Council of the Areopagus with the Athenian popular assemblies. He also celebrates Holland: Excellencie of a Free-State, 14;
    • Excellencie of a Free-State , pp. 14
  • 146
    • 33750917186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hans W. Blom, Eco Haitsma Mulier, and Ronald Janse, eds., Cambridge
    • Algernon Sidney, in Hans W. Blom, Eco Haitsma Mulier, and Ronald Janse, eds., Court Maxims: Sidney (Cambridge, 1996), 74-75.
    • (1996) Court Maxims: Sidney , pp. 74-75
    • Sidney, A.1
  • 147
    • 0039852886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sidney's attitude toward trade is admittedly equivocal - he does heap praise on martial valor. Yet Pocock's categorical dismissal of Sidney's interest in commerce as merely a nostalgic longing for "a post-Elizabethan deployment of naval intervention in Europe" appears to have gone too far. It cannot make sense of Sidney's praise for Dutch state thinking or of his deep and abiding friendliness toward Nieuwpoort and other Dutch commercial advocates. See Pocock, "England's Cato," 920.
    • England's Cato , pp. 920
    • Pocock1
  • 159
    • 33750928893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • He had in mind their political and military as well as their commercial power. Bethel, Present Interest, 10-11.
    • Present Interest , pp. 10-11
    • Bethel1
  • 161
    • 33645000468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Potter, Key of Wealth, 2. Potter, it should be noted, expressly argued that the best means to improve the economy was to increase consumption.
    • Key of Wealth , pp. 2
    • Potter1
  • 162
    • 33750924906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for example, Key of Wealth, 6.
    • Key of Wealth , pp. 6
  • 165
    • 33749438248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blom, et al.
    • Sidney, in Blom, et al., Court Maxims, 74.
    • Court Maxims , pp. 74
    • Sidney1
  • 176
    • 0004459819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (London, 1657) epistle dedicatory
    • James Howel [Howell], Londinopolis (London, 1657), epistle dedicatory, 397.
    • Londinopolis , pp. 397
    • Howel, J.1
  • 177
    • 33750920224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • February 21, 1659
    • For other critiques of Cromwellian foreign policy with specific reference to trade, see Thomas Scot, February 21, 1659, Rutt, Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq., 3: 394;
    • Rutt, Diary, of Thomas Burton, Esq. , vol.3 , pp. 394
    • Scot, T.1
  • 183
    • 33750922280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Popular Republicanism in the 1650s: John Streater's 'heroick mechanics
    • See also Nigel Smith, "Popular Republicanism in the 1650s: John Streater's 'heroick mechanics,'" in Armitage, Himy, and Skinner, Milton and Republicanism, 142, 153.
    • Armitage, Himy, and Skinner, Milton and Republicanism , pp. 142
    • Smith, N.1
  • 184
    • 0039852964 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge
    • Jonathan Scott, Algernon Sidney and the English Republic, 1623-1677 (Cambridge, 1988), 115-16. The differences between Goodgroom and Harrington are sufficiently large, despite the similarities in their historical model, that Harrington cannot have been guilty of plagiarism.
    • (1988) Algernon Sidney and the English Republic, 1623-1677 , pp. 115-116
    • Scott, J.1
  • 193
    • 0009911642 scopus 로고
    • Republicanism and Early American Historiography
    • Robert E. Shalhope, "Republicanism and Early American Historiography," William and Mary Quarterly 39 (1982): 335;
    • (1982) William and Mary Quarterly , vol.39 , pp. 335
    • Shalhope, R.E.1
  • 196
    • 84865917982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I am suggesting that classical republicans did in fact defend a politics of interest - the interest of landed proprietors, which they defined narrowly as virtue. They resisted the language of interests because it often seemed to them that "interest" connoted a much broader definition
    • I am suggesting that classical republicans did in fact defend a politics of interest - the interest of landed proprietors, which they defined narrowly as virtue. They resisted the language of interests because it often seemed to them that "interest" connoted a much broader definition.
  • 200
    • 33750902665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brief Notes upon a Late Sermon
    • April, 1660
    • John Milton, "Brief Notes upon a Late Sermon," April 1660, Complete Prose Works, 7: 481-82.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.7 , pp. 481-482
    • Milton, J.1
  • 202
    • 0001957672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Civil Society Argument
    • Mouffe
    • Michael Walzer has argued that typically "republican theorists" imagine that "citizens should not have to work," a position Walzer believes is incompatible with a commercial society. Walzer, "The Civil Society Argument," in Mouffe, Dimensions of Radical Democracy, 92.
    • Dimensions of Radical Democracy , pp. 92
    • Walzer1
  • 205
    • 33750899411 scopus 로고
    • History and Reform in Milton's Readie and Easie Way
    • Kevin Gilmartin, "History and Reform in Milton's Readie and Easie Way," in Milton Studies 24 (1988): 17-41;
    • (1988) Milton Studies , vol.24 , pp. 17-41
    • Gilmartin, K.1
  • 206
    • 33750901738 scopus 로고
    • Milton's the Readie and Easie Way and the English Jeremiad
    • David Loewenstein and James Grantham Turner, eds., Cambridge
    • Laura Knoppers, "Milton's The Readie and Easie Way and the English Jeremiad," in David Loewenstein and James Grantham Turner, eds., Politics, Poetics, and Hermeneutics in Milton's Prose (Cambridge, 1990), 213-25;
    • (1990) Politics, Poetics, and Hermeneutics in Milton's Prose , pp. 213-225
    • Knoppers, L.1
  • 209
    • 3242795316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Milton: Political Beliefs and Polemical Methods, 1659-1660
    • June
    • Barbara Kiefer Lewalski, "Milton: Political Beliefs and Polemical Methods, 1659-1660," Publications of the Modern Language Association 74 (June 1959): 198, 202;
    • (1959) Publications of the Modern Language Association , vol.74 , pp. 198
    • Lewalski, B.K.1
  • 213
    • 0041752062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge
    • William Kolbrener, Milton's Warring Angels: A Study of Critical Engagements (Cambridge, 1997), 29-30. I should note that Tuck sees Milton's devotion to aristocracy as "perfectly in line with much republican thought in both the United Provinces and England" (p. 253). This is true if one's frame of reference is the sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries. However, in both England and the United Provinces, the middle and later seventeenth centuries saw an increasing commitment to commercial society, hence allowing the possibility of more democratic notions of governance.
    • (1997) Milton's Warring Angels: A Study of Critical Engagements , pp. 29-30
    • Kolbrener, W.1
  • 215
    • 84865933066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "The Tenure of Kings and Magistrates," 1649
    • John Milton, "The Tenure of Kings and Magistrates," 1649, Complete Prose Works, 3: 192.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.3 , pp. 192
    • Milton, J.1
  • 216
  • 217
  • 221
    • 33750905788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Milton to Leo Van Aitzema, February 5, 1655
    • John Milton to Leo Van Aitzema, February 5, 1655, Complete Prose Works, 4: 871-72;
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.4 , pp. 871-872
  • 222
    • 33750910112 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Milton, "Readie and Easie Way," 7: 356-57, 364-65. Responding to Milton's increasing pessimism about the English people, Milton's friend Moses Wall explained Milton's insensitivity to material issues, his inability to consider that "whilst people are not free but straightened in accommodations for life, their spirits will be dejected and servile." The only way to promote a true state, Wall advised Milton, was to improve English manufactures, increase trade, and capitalize agriculture. Wall understood precisely the relationship between Milton's elitist politics and his opposition to commercial society.
    • Readie and Easie Way , vol.7 , pp. 356-357
    • Milton1
  • 223
    • 84860374457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moses Wall to John Milton, May 26, 1659
    • Moses Wall to John Milton, May 26, 1659, Complete Prose Works, 7: 511. I am grateful to David Loewenstein for calling this letter to my attention.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.7 , pp. 511
  • 224
    • 33750926394 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Life of John Milton
    • Darbishire
    • John Toland, "Life of John Milton," in Darbishire, Early Lives of Milton, 166.
    • Early Lives of Milton , pp. 166
    • Toland, J.1
  • 227
    • 33750907443 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Throughout his career, Milton had displayed an interest in Trajan as the best of leaders. See Milton, "Tenure of Kings and Magistrates," 3: 205-06;
    • Tenure of Kings and Magistrates , vol.3 , pp. 205-206
    • Milton1
  • 229
    • 33750910286 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Second Defence of the People of England: Andrew Marvell to John Milton 1654
    • June 2
    • Andrew Marvell was quick to understand the Trajanic nature of the panegyric to Cromwell in the Second Defence of the People of England: Andrew Marvell to John Milton, June 2, 1654, Complete Prose Works, 4: 864.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.4 , pp. 864
  • 230
    • 84865919015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Proposals of Certain Expedients," 1659
    • John Milton, "Proposals of Certain Expedients," 1659, Complete Prose Works, 7: 336.
    • Complete Prose Works , vol.7 , pp. 336
    • Milton, J.1
  • 232
    • 84871308006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harrington, "Oceana," 172, 182. Harrington did allow for the inclusion of the new concept of "interest" but only as the "interest of the whole," not "of the parts." As a result, interest was rendered a static and exclusively agrarian concept. Harrington's notion of interest was too thin to allow it to be a transformative concept in his work. "Oceana," 171.
    • Oceana , pp. 172
    • Harrington1
  • 238
    • 33750895794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • They did have a range of supporters: see Spriggs, Modest Plea, 80;
    • Modest Plea , pp. 80
    • Spriggs1
  • 240
    • 33750915194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • December 23, 1659 (London, 1659)
    • George Wither, A Cordial Confection, December 23, 1659 (London, 1659), 8-10.
    • A Cordial Confection , pp. 8-10
    • Wither, G.1
  • 241
    • 33750926738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The defenders of the Commonwealth, and modern liberals, do not I think reject virtue, but reject it in the classical republican sense. They believe society should be virtuous, but virtuousness need not be incompatible with the interests of those beyond the landed classes. For classical republicans, "virtue" is a timeless concept with a precise set of classical or Christian meanings. For liberals and the defenders of the English Commonwealth, "virtue" is a contingent concept, contingent on social, economic, and geopolitical considerations. That contingency can only be discovered through dialectic. This is not to say that liberal "virtue" is relative, but, rather, in a skeptical sense, liberals and defenders of the English Commonwealth do not believe that the totality of "virtue" is yet known. This is a point I hope to flesh out in subsequent work.
  • 242
    • 33750913990 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2 vols. (London, 1655)
    • Charles Herle, Wisdomes Tripos, 2 vols. (London, 1655), 169;
    • Wisdomes Tripos , pp. 169
    • Herle, C.1
  • 246
    • 33750914174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This understanding was based on his reading of the modern politician Henry Duc de Rohan. See also Nedham, Interest Will Not Lie, 3.
    • Interest Will Not Lie , pp. 3
    • Nedham1
  • 252
    • 33749438248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blom, et al.
    • Sidney, in Blom, et al., Court Maxims, 27.
    • Court Maxims , pp. 27
    • Sidney1
  • 253
    • 33750903628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a more complete and much more sophisticated discussion of Sidney's interest theory that supports and elaborates the contention I am making here, see Houston, Algernon Sidney and the Republican Heritage, 165-67, 198-99.
    • Algernon Sidney and the Republican Heritage , pp. 165-167
    • Houston1
  • 256
    • 33750922975 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I am not suggesting that interest analysis led ineluctably to arguments for democracy. They did not. It was certainly possible to suggest, and many did, that only a small number of people had an interest in the nation, and hence only they should rule. I am suggesting, however, that the language of interest allowed for the possibility of democracy in a way that the language of virtue did not. Interest analysis was necessary but absolutely not sufficient for a commitment to democracy.
  • 258
    • 84959805699 scopus 로고
    • The Virtues of Liberalism: Christianity, Republicanism, and Ethics in Early American Political Discourse
    • June
    • therefore find it hard to accept James T. Kloppenberg's assessment that "the doctrine of popular sovereignty" was "the decisive achievement of the American political imagination," which could only develop from "the colonial experience of self-government." See Kloppenberg, "The Virtues of Liberalism: Christianity, Republicanism, and Ethics in Early American Political Discourse," Journal of American History 74 (June 1987): 24. There was a long and distinguished European tradition of such arguments upon which the Americans drew. However, as I will make clear below, I am sympathetic to some of the sophisticated theoretical claims Kloppenberg makes in that article.
    • (1987) Journal of American History , vol.74 , pp. 24
    • Kloppenberg1
  • 262
    • 33750910111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • To His Excellency the Lord General Monck: The Unanimous Representation of the Apprentices and Young Men Inhabiting the City of London, February 2, 1660 (London, [1660]), broadside
    • To His Excellency the Lord General Monck: The Unanimous Representation of the Apprentices and Young Men Inhabiting the City of London, February 2, 1660 (London, [1660]), broadside.
  • 265
    • 84871046750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that Nedham's notion of epochal change runs counter to a classical republican commitment to timeless virtue. I thus find myself in disagreement with Nigel Smith's claim, which is similar to Skinner's (Liberty before Liberalism, 31-32), that "Nedham's republic is as meritocratic as Milton's"
    • Liberty before Liberalism , pp. 31-32
  • 266
    • 84866909950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (Literature and Revolution in England, 185), and closer to Worden's that "Nedham is perhaps socially the most radical of the republicans"
    • Literature and Revolution in England , pp. 185
  • 267
    • 33750896578 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ("English Republicanism," 449). However, I wonder whether, given Nedham's commitment to interest, epochal change, and commercial society, he should still be considered a classical republican in the Pocockian sense.
    • English Republicanism , pp. 449
  • 272
    • 33749438248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blom, et al.
    • Sidney, in Blom, et al., Court Maxims, 23.
    • Court Maxims , pp. 23
    • Sidney1
  • 276
    • 0003453453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Macpherson, Political Theory of Possessive Individualism, 3. Remarkably, Skinner also reduces the liberal tradition to "classical utilitarianism" (Liberty before Liberalism, 96-97). I have read this passage to mean that those living in a "polite and commercial age" are somehow incapable of sharing the "moral vision" of Skinner's neo-romans. As I have emphasized throughout this essay, many of the neo-romans thought they were living in a polite and commercial age. While they rejected Harrington's political economy and conceptions of interest, they shared his moral vision.
    • Political Theory of Possessive Individualism , pp. 3
    • Macpherson1
  • 277
    • 0041910516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Appleby, Liberalism and Republicanism, 24 , 51, 56. I find myself persuaded by Donald Winch's observations that "Adam Smith serves as the ideological goal of Appleby's teleological treatment of English liberal ideology," and that "the idea that man was ruled by one passion alone, even in his economic dealings, and one that was based on rational calculation, would not have been regarded by Smith as a discovery or insight, but rather as a pervasive error which had prevented many important questions of politics and economics from being given serious treatment by philosophers."
    • Liberalism and Republicanism , pp. 24
    • Appleby1
  • 278
    • 84980232730 scopus 로고
    • Economic Liberalism as Ideology: The Appleby Version
    • 2d ser.
    • Winch, "Economic Liberalism as Ideology: The Appleby Version," Economic History Review, 2d ser., 38 (1985): 290, 292.
    • (1985) Economic History Review , vol.38 , pp. 290
    • Winch1
  • 279
    • 84997930842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While I remain unconvinced by the normative claims advanced by Philip Pettit and endorsed by Quentin Skinner, for my purposes it is sufficient to suggest the faulty historical assumptions on which their distinction between liberalism and republicanism is based. "Liberalism" for Pettit is an ideology appropriate "for the modern, commercial, and increasingly democratic world." As such, it could not emerge until "early in the nineteenth century." Pettit, "Liberalism and Republicanism," 163;
    • Liberalism and Republicanism , pp. 163
    • Pettit1
  • 280
    • 0004260025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Skinner, Liberty before Liberalism, 96-97. The point of this essay is to show that in the 1650s many were developing a political theory for just such a modern, commercial, and increasingly democratic society. Neither Skinner nor Pettit has presented any evidence to suggest that these people had a different conception of liberty or a different moral vision than those committed to a politics of unitary virtue or a predominantly agrarian political economy. They rely on a non-contextualized comparison between nineteenth-century utilitarians and seventeenth-century defenders of the Commonwealth.
    • Liberty before Liberalism , pp. 96-97
    • Skinner1
  • 285
    • 33750930393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hawkins, Discourse of the National Excellencies, 246. Hawkins also suggested that those nations that paid the highest taxes attained the greatest liberty (p. 177).
    • Discourse of the National Excellencies , pp. 246
    • Hawkins1
  • 286
    • 0003691257 scopus 로고
    • Peter Laslett, ed., 2d edn. Cambridge
    • John Locke, Two Treatises of Government, Peter Laslett, ed., 2d edn. (Cambridge, 1967), 287.
    • (1967) Two Treatises of Government , pp. 287
    • Locke, J.1
  • 293
    • 33750900122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be clear at this point how much I have learned from Matson and Onuf, "Toward a Republican Empire," 496-99, 515-16. English republicans in the 1650s were confronted with the same expansion of international commerce and the same problems of maintaining a wartime economy that the Americans were in the 1780s, and they made some of the same ideological adjustments. I do not think, however, that those who did so remained classical republicans.
    • Toward a Republican Empire , pp. 496-499
    • Matson1    Onuf2
  • 302
    • 0039852894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It should be noted that Zera Fink did not see republicanism and liberalism as incompatible. That was clearly Pocock's great innovation. See Z. Fink, Classical Republicans, 189-90.
    • Classical Republicans , pp. 189-190
    • Fink, Z.1
  • 303
    • 0003624191 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • The 1650s Commonwealth support for a republican conception of liberty alongside a new commercial political economy is equivalent to John Rawls' suggestion that classical republicanism is largely consistent with political liberalism while civic humanism is not, precisely because in the latter
    • (1993) Political Liberalism , pp. 205-206
    • Rawls1
  • 304
    • 3242751487 scopus 로고
    • Contextualizing Milton's Nascent Republicanism
    • P. G. Stanwood, ed., Binghamton, N.Y.
    • Janel Mueller, "Contextualizing Milton's Nascent Republicanism," in P. G. Stanwood, ed., Of Poetry and Politics: New Essays on Milton and His World (Binghamton, N.Y., 1995), esp. 265-66.
    • (1995) Of Poetry and Politics: New Essays on Milton and His World , pp. 265-266
    • Mueller, J.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.