메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 36, Issue 2, 2002, Pages 171-188

International trade law, political economy and rules of origin: A plea for a reform of the WTO regime on rules of origin

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

INTERNATIONAL TRADE; POLITICAL ECONOMY; REGULATORY APPROACH;

EID: 26044472464     PISSN: 10116702     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1023/A:1015558824815     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (24)

References (146)
  • 1
    • 26044478142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Two synonymous terms are widely employed in the literature to describe the branch of political economy that deals with international trade: "political economy of trade policy" and "political economy of international trade". This article employs these two terms interchangeably.
  • 2
    • 0011293416 scopus 로고
    • in John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, London, Macmillan
    • For various definitions of political economy and its evolution as a distinct discipline, see Peter Groennewegen, Political Economy and Economics, in John Eatwell, Murray Milgate and Peter Newman (eds), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Vol. III (London, Macmillan, 1987), p. 904.
    • (1987) Political Economy and Economics , vol.3 , pp. 904
    • Groennewegen, P.1
  • 3
    • 84936174635 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
    • For a general introduction to the political economy of trade policy, see Robert E. Baldwin, The Political Economy of US Import Policy (Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1985), p. 3;
    • (1985) The Political Economy of US Import Policy , pp. 3
    • Baldwin, R.E.1
  • 6
    • 0040294069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International political economy in the age of globalization
    • John Baylis and Steve Smith (eds), Oxford, Oxford University Press
    • Roger Tooze, "International Political Economy in the Age of Globalization", in John Baylis and Steve Smith (eds), The Globalization of World Politics (Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1997), pp. 212, 215.
    • (1997) The Globalization of World Politics , pp. 212
    • Tooze, R.1
  • 8
    • 26044480080 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 1-3
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 1-3;
  • 10
    • 22444454676 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Comparative advantage and the normative economics of international trade policies
    • Alan Sykes, Comparative Advantage and the Normative Economics of International Trade Policies, 1 Journal of International Economic Law (1998), 49, 57-63.
    • (1998) 1 Journal of International Economic Law , pp. 49
    • Sykes, A.1
  • 13
    • 26044477729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 8-10
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 8-10;
  • 15
    • 26044472338 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This prediction is dependent upon "factor specificity" (mobility or lack of mobility of the factors of production among sectors);
  • 16
    • 24744461933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The political economy of international trade: Enduring puzzles and agenda for inquiry
    • see, in detail, James E. Alt, Jeffry Frieden, Michael J. Gilligan, Dani Rodrik and Ronald Rogowski, The Political Economy of International Trade: Enduring Puzzles and Agenda for Inquiry, 29 Comparative Political Studies (1996), 689, 697-700.
    • (1996) 29 Comparative Political Studies , pp. 689
    • Alt, J.E.1    Frieden, J.2    Gilligan, M.J.3    Rodrik, D.4    Rogowski, R.5
  • 18
    • 77957234851 scopus 로고
    • Political economy of trade policy
    • Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Amsterdam, Elsevier
    • Dani Rodrik, "Political Economy of Trade Policy", in Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III (Amsterdam, Elsevier, 1995), pp. 1457, 1459.
    • (1995) Handbook of International Economics , vol.3 , pp. 1457
    • Rodrik, D.1
  • 19
    • 26044469879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These preferences are derived from the expected outcomes of each alternative trade policy for each domestic group; Rodrik, as note 9 above, p. 1459..
  • 20
    • 26044460534 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This stage requires an analysis of the relevant political organization and the forms of political influence (e.g., lobbying, campaign contributions, etc.); Rodrik, as note 9 above, pp. 1459-60.
  • 21
    • 26044467330 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rodrik, as note 9 above, p. 1460.
  • 22
    • 84953747425 scopus 로고
    • The political economy of nontariff barriers: A cross-national analysis
    • On the implications of certain institutional features upon trade policy, see Edward D. Mansfield and Marc L. Bush, The Political Economy of Nontariff Barriers: A Cross-National Analysis, 49 International Organization (1995), 723, 729-731;
    • (1995) 49 International Organization , pp. 723
    • Mansfield, E.D.1    Bush, M.L.2
  • 25
    • 26044469041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • On the role of international factors in the shaping of trade policy, see, e.g., Friman, as note 13 above, pp. 698-699;
  • 28
    • 77956849005 scopus 로고
    • Strategic trade policy
    • Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Amsterdam, Elsevier
    • James A. Brander, "Strategic Trade Policy", in Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III (Amsterdam, Elsevier, 1995), p. 1395;
    • (1995) Handbook of International Economics , vol.3 , pp. 1395
    • Brander, J.A.1
  • 29
    • 0033011712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Strategic interest and international political economy
    • Stephen Greenwold, Strategic Interest and International Political Economy, 4 New Political Economy 1 (1997), 97.
    • (1997) 4 New Political Economy , vol.1 , pp. 97
    • Greenwold, S.1
  • 30
    • 26044475863 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for instance, the statement made by Rodrik: "While the manner in which political influence is exercised differs across models, the conclusion in common is: trade is not free because politically-influential groups can be made better off by policy intervention in trade." Rodrik, as note 9 above, p. 1470;
  • 31
    • 26044441895 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • see also p. 1476.
  • 32
    • 26044452060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a concise survey of the existing literature on this subject, see Milner, as note 7 above, pp. 95-107;
  • 33
    • 26044478410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Rodrik, as note 9 above, pp. 1463-1470.
  • 34
    • 26044434854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a broader survey, see Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 24-72;
  • 35
    • 26044456746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Baldwin, as note 2 above, pp. 6-32.
  • 36
    • 0008181490 scopus 로고
    • The return of the reciprocitarians: U.S. trade policy today
    • Jagdish Bhagwati (ed.), Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
    • See, e.g., Jagdish Bhagwati and Douglas A. Irwin, "The Return of the Reciprocitarians: U.S. Trade Policy Today", in Jagdish Bhagwati (ed.), Political Economy and International Economics (Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1991), pp. 84, 102;
    • (1991) Political Economy and International Economics , pp. 84
    • Bhagwati, J.1    Irwin, D.A.2
  • 37
    • 0004186070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
    • Jagdish Bhagwati, Protectionism (Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1988), p. 72;
    • (1988) Protectionism , pp. 72
    • Bhagwati, J.1
  • 38
    • 26044449997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Gilligan, as note 13 above, pp. 3-4.
  • 39
    • 26044441609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a survey of other explanations, see Milner, as note 7 above.
  • 40
    • 0003636206 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press
    • On the Prisoners' Dilemma, see James D. Morrow, Game Theory for Political Scientists (Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press, 1994), pp. 78-81, 262-268.
    • (1994) Game Theory for Political Scientists , pp. 78-81
    • Morrow, J.D.1
  • 41
    • 0008750624 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Game theory, international law, and environmental cooperation in the middle east
    • On the application of the Prisoners' Dilemma to international relations and international law, see Moshe Hirsch, Game Theory, International Law, and Environmental Cooperation in the Middle East, 27 Denver Journal of International Law & Policy (1999), 75, 88, 109-115;
    • (1999) 27 Denver Journal of International Law & Policy , pp. 75
    • Hirsch, M.1
  • 42
    • 0001222122 scopus 로고
    • Modern international relations theory: A prospectus for international lawyers
    • Kenneth W Abbott, Modern International Relations Theory: A Prospectus for International Lawyers, 14 Yale Journal of International Law (1989), 360-362;
    • (1989) 14 Yale Journal of International Law , pp. 360-362
    • Abbott, K.W.1
  • 43
    • 0003145319 scopus 로고
    • Prisoners' Dilemma and chicken models in international politics
    • Glenn H. Snyder, Prisoners' Dilemma and Chicken Models in International Politics, 15 International Studies Quarterly (1971), 66.
    • (1971) 15 International Studies Quarterly , pp. 66
    • Snyder, G.H.1
  • 45
    • 77956813804 scopus 로고
    • International rules and institutions for trade policy
    • Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Amsterdam, Elsevier
    • Robert W Staiger, "International Rules and Institutions for Trade Policy", in Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (eds), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. III (Amsterdam, Elsevier, 1995), pp. 1495, 1511-1515.
    • (1995) Handbook of International Economics , vol.3 , pp. 1495
    • Staiger, R.W.1
  • 46
    • 84936050692 scopus 로고
    • Public goods, Prisoners' Dilemmas and the international political economy
    • See in detail on international trade and the Prisoners' Dilemma, John A.C. Conybeare, Public Goods, Prisoners' Dilemmas and the International Political Economy, 28 International Studies Quarterly (1984), 5, 10-14.
    • (1984) 28 International Studies Quarterly , pp. 5
    • Conybeare, J.A.C.1
  • 47
    • 0004233688 scopus 로고
    • New York, Basic Books
    • On the importance of reciprocal measures as a means of solving the Prisoners' Dilemma and other collective action problems, see Robert Axelord, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York, Basic Books, 1984), pp. 27-54;
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation , pp. 27-54
    • Axelord, R.1
  • 48
    • 84965750204 scopus 로고
    • Strategies for eliciting cooperation from an adversary
    • Martin Patchen, Strategies for Eliciting Cooperation from an Adversary, 31 Journal of Conflict Resolution (1987), 171-181;
    • (1987) 31 Journal of Conflict Resolution , pp. 171-181
    • Patchen, M.1
  • 50
    • 26044435953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, e.g., Moser, as note 8 above, pp. 25, 39;
  • 52
    • 26044467582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hoekman and Kostecki, as note 20 above, pp. 27-30.
  • 53
    • 0004186070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • as note 17 above
    • For an analysis of the GATT/WTO system from this perspective, see Bhagwati, Protectionism, as note 17 above, pp. 35-37, 40;
    • Protectionism , pp. 35-37
    • Bhagwati1
  • 54
    • 26044441894 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 121-123.
  • 55
    • 26044465786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ROO function as a differentiating mechanism in preferential arrangements, but it should be noted that these arrangements might operate in both directions: providing for either trade preferences (e.g., tariff reduction) or restrictive measures (e.g., quantitative restrictions). Though the role of determining whether a particular product qualifies for a certain trade preference is more noticeable, the rationale underlying both roles is the same.
  • 56
    • 0009314847 scopus 로고
    • Implementing free trade areas: Rules of origin and hidden protection
    • Jim Levinson, Alan V. Deardroff, and Robert M. Stern (eds), Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press
    • ROO have an additional and distinctive role in free trade areas (FTAs). ROO are essential to maintaining FTAs with different external tariffs towards non-FTA members. In the absence of ROO, imported products from non-FTA countries would enter through the country with the lowest tariff and be re-exported to the other FTA members. After a certain period, such a pattern of trade flow is expected to exert pressure upon the states with the higher tariff rate to lower their tariff rate, nearing that of the state with lowest duty. Such a process is likely to put pressure on the FTA members to adopt the same external tariff rates, i.e., to form a customs union. The operation of ROO averts this undesirable development by not allowing products manufactured in non-FTA countries to enjoy duty-free movement among the FTA members. See on this feature, Kala Krishna and Anne Krueger, "Implementing Free Trade Areas: Rules of Origin and Hidden Protection", in Jim Levinson, Alan V. Deardroff, and Robert M. Stern (eds), New Directions in International Trade (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press, 1995), pp. 149, 150-151.
    • (1995) New Directions in International Trade , pp. 149
    • Krishna, K.1    Krueger, A.2
  • 57
    • 26044436507 scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin: An introduction
    • Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press
    • On this trend, see Jacques H.J. Bourgeois, "Rules of Origin: An Introduction", in Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Rules of Origin in International Trade (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press, 1994), pp. 1, 4-5.
    • (1994) Rules of Origin in International Trade , pp. 1
    • Bourgeois, J.H.J.1
  • 58
    • 65849095495 scopus 로고
    • European community rules of origin
    • Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer, and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press
    • The term "last substantial process" is often used in non-preferential contexts (e.g., the WTO Agreement on Rules of Origin) and the term "sufficient working or processing" is widely used in preferential agreements; see, e.g., with regard to EC preferential agreements, Paul Waer, "European Community Rules of Origin", in Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer, and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Rules of Origin in International Trade (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press, 1994), pp. 85, 146.
    • (1994) Rules of Origin in International Trade , pp. 85
    • Waer, P.1
  • 59
    • 0003519168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
    • See on these tests in detail, John H. Jackson, The World Trading System (2nd edn, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1997), pp. 167-169;
    • (1997) The World Trading System 2nd Edn , pp. 167-169
    • Jackson, J.H.1
  • 60
    • 21144476223 scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin as commercial policy instruments - Revisited
    • December
    • Edwin A. Vermulst, Rules of Origin as Commercial Policy Instruments - Revisited, 26 J.W.T. 6 (December 1992), 61, 63-74;
    • (1992) 26 J.W.T. , vol.6 , pp. 61
    • Vermulst, E.A.1
  • 61
    • 0030507803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin and the uruguay round's effectiveness in harmonizing and regulating them
    • Joseph A. LaNasa III, Rules of Origin and the Uruguay Round's Effectiveness in Harmonizing and Regulating Them, 90 American Journal of International Law (1996), 625, 629-636.
    • (1996) 90 American Journal of International Law , pp. 625
    • LaNasa III, J.A.1
  • 62
    • 26044483538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It should be emphasized here that global agreements (such as the WTO agreements) are also considered as "preferential arrangements" in this sense, since trade preferences included in such agreements are accorded only to products manufactured in the contracting states.
  • 63
    • 0002940683 scopus 로고
    • Regionalism and multilateralism: An overview
    • Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya (eds), Cambridge, Cambridge University Press
    • This issue is also one of the essential preconditions to the establishment of FTAs or customs unions under Article XXIV(4) of the GATT; see, e.g., Jackson, as note 27 above, pp. 65-67; on the economic rationale for Article XXIV, see Jagdish Bhagwati, "Regionalism and Multilateralism: An Overview", in Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya (eds), New Dimensions in Regional Integration (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1995), pp. 22, 25-28.
    • (1995) New Dimensions in Regional Integration , pp. 22
    • Bhagwati, J.1
  • 64
    • 26044450558 scopus 로고
    • The economics of rules of origin
    • Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press
    • See, e.g., E. Ivan Kingston, "The Economics of Rules of Origin", in Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgois (eds), Rules of Origin in International Trade (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press, 1994), p. 7.
    • (1994) Rules of Origin in International Trade , pp. 7
    • Kingston, E.I.1
  • 65
    • 26044451189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regionalism and the WTO: Should the rules be changed?
    • Jeffrey J. Schott (ed.), Washington, DC, Institute of International Economics
    • See, e.g., the statement made by Lawrence: "The major abuses perpetrated by the emerging regional arrangements relate to their use of rules of origin and antidumping provisions." Robert Z. Lawrence, "Regionalism and the WTO: Should the Rules be Changed?", in Jeffrey J. Schott (ed.), The World Trading System: Challenges Ahead (Washington, DC, Institute of International Economics, 1996), pp. 41, 52.
    • (1996) The World Trading System: Challenges Ahead , pp. 41
    • Lawrence, R.Z.1
  • 66
    • 0347971127 scopus 로고
    • North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)
    • Article 404 of the
    • The terms "local" and "domestic" refer here to the territories of the contracting states, and "foreign" refers to the territories of non-contracting states. This terminology is based on the assumption that the preferential arrangements include rules of either "bilateral cumulation" or "multilateral cumulation". Cumulation rules allow each party to the arrangement to use factors of production originating in the territories of the other contracting parties without infringing upon the ROO. See, e.g., Article 404 of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), 32 International Legal Materials (1993), 289.
    • (1993) 32 International Legal Materials , pp. 289
  • 68
    • 26044458499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Pan European rules of origin: The beginning of a new Era in European free trade
    • On the cumulation rules in the EC preferential agreements, see Hans-Joachim Priess and Ralph Pethke, The Pan European Rules of Origin: The Beginning of a New Era in European Free Trade, 34 Common Market Law Review (1997), 772, 782-786;
    • (1997) 34 Common Market Law Review , pp. 772
    • Priess, H.-J.1    Pethke, R.2
  • 69
    • 26044476871 scopus 로고
    • London, Chancery Law Publishing
    • Nicholas A. Zaimis, EC Rules of Origin (London, Chancery Law Publishing, 1992), pp. 175-214.
    • (1992) EC Rules of Origin , pp. 175-214
    • Zaimis, N.A.1
  • 70
    • 22044447645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The asymmetric incidence of rules of origin: Will progressive and cumulation rules resolve the problem?
    • August
    • On this impact of ROO, and its inefficient consequences (in terms of reallocation of resources) in detail, see Moshe Hirsch, The Asymmetric Incidence of Rules of Origin: Will Progressive and Cumulation Rules Resolve the Problem?, 32 J.W.T. 4 (August 1998), 41, 44-45.
    • (1998) 32 J.W.T. , vol.4 , pp. 41
    • Hirsch, M.1
  • 71
    • 11544342100 scopus 로고
    • Wiley & Sons
    • The above negative effects of ROO upon foreign suppliers are similar to those that are generally generated to third parties by the establishment of preferential arrangements in general. This is the well-known effect of "trade diversion" in favour of preferential arrangements' parties. It should be emphasized that the extent of the diversion in favour of the contracting parties is dependent, inter alia, on the level of restrictiveness of the ROO included in a particular preferential arrangement. Thus, excessive ROO increase the negative impacts of preferential agreements for manufacturers located in the territories of third parties. For an analysis of the economic effects of preferential arrangements for third parties, see James C. Ingram and Robert M. Dunn, International Economics (3rd edn, Wiley & Sons, 1993), pp. 163-169;
    • (1993) International Economics 3rd Edn , pp. 163-169
    • Ingram, J.C.1    Dunn, R.M.2
  • 74
    • 26044441137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In such a case, however, other NTBs may still be relevant.
  • 75
    • 26044472642 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These calculations should also take into account the costs of transferring production in the case of shifting the production line into the preferential area, and transportation costs in the case of production outside the preferential area.
  • 76
    • 26044481971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Here it is also necessary to examine the administrative costs involved in compliance with ROO (e.g., the costs of providing appropriate documentation to determine origin). Krishna and Krueger, as note 24 above, p. 157, n. 16;
  • 77
    • 26044460182 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Waer, as note 26 above, p. 158;
  • 78
    • 21844511975 scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin and the Asia-Pacific economic cooperation
    • April
    • Stephenson and James, Rules of Origin and the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation, 29 J.W.T. 2 (April 1995), 77, 89.
    • (1995) 29 J.W.T. , vol.2 , pp. 77
    • Stephenson1    James2
  • 79
    • 26044468406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin in regional trade agreements
    • Paul Demaret, Jean-Francois Bellis and Gonzalo Garcia Jimenez (eds), Brussels, European Inter-University Press
    • David Palmeter, "Rules of Origin in Regional Trade Agreements", in Paul Demaret, Jean-Francois Bellis and Gonzalo Garcia Jimenez (eds), Regionalism and Multilateralism After the Uruguay Round (Brussels, European Inter-University Press, 1997), pp. 341, 343-345.
    • (1997) Regionalism and Multilateralism after the Uruguay Round , pp. 341
    • Palmeter, D.1
  • 80
    • 85050170692 scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin under the North American free trade agreement: A substantial transformation into objectively transparent protectionism
    • Joseph A. LaNasa III, Rules of Origin under the North American Free Trade Agreement: A Substantial Transformation into Objectively Transparent Protectionism, 34 Harvard International Law Journal (1993), 381, 397-399.
    • (1993) 34 Harvard International Law Journal , pp. 381
    • LaNasa III, J.A.1
  • 81
    • 26044442520 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vermulst, as note 27 above, pp. 66-67
    • Vermulst, as note 27 above, pp. 66-67;
  • 84
    • 84993805223 scopus 로고
    • Trade battles as investment wars: The coming rules of origin debate
    • Jeri Jensen-Moran, Trade Battles as Investment Wars: The Coming Rules of Origin Debate, 19 The Washingtonian Quarterly (1995), 239, 242-243;
    • (1995) 19 the Washingtonian Quarterly , pp. 239
    • Jensen-Moran, J.1
  • 86
    • 26044438173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International harmonization of rules of origin
    • Philip Ruttley, Iain MacVay and Carol George (eds), London, Cameron May
    • Norio Koniuro, "International Harmonization of Rules of Origin", in Philip Ruttley, Iain MacVay and Carol George (eds), The WTO and International Trade Regulation (London, Cameron May, 1998), p. 86.
    • (1998) The WTO and International Trade Regulation , pp. 86
    • Koniuro, N.1
  • 87
    • 26044437128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jensen-Moran, as note 42 above, p. 244
    • Jensen-Moran, as note 42 above, p. 244.
  • 88
    • 26044459900 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the impressive figures cited in Jensen-Moran, ibid., p. 245.
  • 89
    • 23044517916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Negotiating preferential market access: The case of the North American free trade agreement
    • February
    • Antoni Estevadeordal, Negotiating Preferential Market Access: The Case of the North American Free Trade Agreement, 34 J.W.T. 1 (February 2000), 141, 151.
    • (2000) 34 J.W.T. , vol.1 , pp. 141
    • Estevadeordal, A.1
  • 91
    • 26044465050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The author concludes at p. 161: "In other words, borrowing the language of the endogenous protection literature, one could conclude that the same forces that push for tariff protection also push for more restrictive ROO."
  • 92
  • 93
    • 26044449994 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also Mansfield and Bush, as note 13 above, p. 734
    • see also Mansfield and Bush, as note 13 above, p. 734.
  • 94
    • 26044456380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The authors of the study found considerable evidence of an inverse relationship between the employment of tariffs and NTBs. Consequently, they concluded that "tariffs and NTBs seem to be substitutes"; Mansfield and Bush, as note 13 above, pp. 739-740.
  • 95
    • 26044440855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Hillman, as note 2 above, pp. 73-74.
  • 96
    • 26044480332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ibid.
  • 97
    • 26044457291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid
    • Ibid.
  • 98
    • 26044447417 scopus 로고
    • North American free trade agreement - Rules of origin
    • February
    • As cited in John P. Simpson, North American Free Trade Agreement - Rules of Origin, 28 J.W.T. 1 (February 1994), 33.
    • (1994) 28 J.W.T. , vol.1 , pp. 33
    • Simpson, J.P.1
  • 100
    • 26044471816 scopus 로고
    • Rules of origin in the GATT
    • Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgeois (eds), Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press
    • On the 1994 Agreement on Rules of Origin, see Edurne Navarro Varona, "Rules of Origin in the GATT", in Edwin Vermulst, Paul Waer and Jacques Bourgeois (eds), Rules of Origin in International Trade (Ann Arbor, MI, University of Michigan Press, 1994), pp. 355, 359-363;
    • (1994) Rules of Origin in International Trade , pp. 355
    • Varona, E.N.1
  • 102
    • 26044469882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trebilcock and House, as note 34 above, pp. 127-128
    • Trebilcock and House, as note 34 above, pp. 127-128.
  • 103
    • 0033420085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • WTO negotiations on the harmonization of rules or origin: A first critical appraisal
    • June
    • On the work of the WTO Committee on ROO following the conclusion of the 1994 Agreement, see Philippe G. Nell, WTO Negotiations on the Harmonization of Rules or Origin: A First Critical Appraisal, 33 J.W.T. 3 (June 1999), 45.
    • (1999) 33 J.W.T. , vol.3 , pp. 45
    • Nell, P.G.1
  • 104
    • 26044466712 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Article 1(1) of the Agreement on Rules of Origin, ibid.;
    • (1999) 33 J.W.T. , vol.3 , pp. 45
  • 105
    • 26044448568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Komuro, as note 41 above, pp. 100-108
    • Komuro, as note 41 above, pp. 100-108.
  • 106
    • 26044460535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Article 2(b) of the Agreement on Rules of Origin provides that the contracting parties are not allowed to use "their rules of origin ... as instruments to pursue trade objectives". And Article 2(c) provides that the member states are not permitted to use ROO to "create restrictive, distorting, or disruptive effects on international trade".
  • 107
    • 26044480856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The above prohibition (cited in the former note) is not included in the Common Declaration with Regard to the Preferential Rules of Origin.
  • 108
    • 26044481690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hoekman and Kostecki, as note 20 above, p. 104
    • Hoekman and Kostecki, as note 20 above, p. 104.
  • 110
    • 26044458199 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ingram and Dunn, as note 34 above, pp. 37-72
    • Ingram and Dunn, as note 34 above, pp. 37-72.
  • 111
    • 26044464215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Section V
    • See Section V.
  • 112
    • 26044481685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Section III
    • See Section III.
  • 113
    • 26044477728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Section V
    • See Section V.
  • 114
    • 26044448307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • as note 33 above
    • See in detail on this impact of ROO, Hirsch, The Asymmetric Incidence of ROO, as note 33 above, p. 44.
    • The Asymmetric Incidence of ROO , pp. 44
  • 115
    • 26044441893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Revealing this information may in itself constitute a trigger to the building of some pressure upon policy-makers to reduce the extent of protection accorded to a particular sector.
  • 116
    • 26044446420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Section II
    • See Section II.
  • 117
    • 26044482692 scopus 로고
    • Agreement on trade in agricultural products
    • Geneva, GATT
    • Articles IV, V and Annex 5 of the 1994 WTO Agreement on Trade in Agricultural Products, in The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations (Geneva, GATT, 1994), p. 39.
    • (1994) The Results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations , pp. 39
  • 118
    • 26044457650 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this agreement, see Trebilcock and House, as note 34 above, pp. 259-264
    • On this agreement, see Trebilcock and House, as note 34 above, pp. 259-264.
  • 119
    • 26044446671 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., LaNasa, as note 27 above, pp. 632-633
    • See, e.g., LaNasa, as note 27 above, pp. 632-633.
  • 120
    • 26044481431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Palmeter, as note 38 above, pp. 344-347
    • See, e.g., Palmeter, as note 38 above, pp. 344-347.
  • 121
    • 26044464493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Palmeter, as note 38 above, p. 347, and the examples described therein
    • See, e.g., Palmeter, as note 38 above, p. 347, and the examples described therein.
  • 122
    • 26044437414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This conclusion does not rule out any resort to the Harmonized System for the purposes of origin determination. One of the main advantages of the tariff-shift test is that it is based upon the Harmonized System, which provides an almost universal framework for the determination of origin in international trade. It is important to note, however, that trade agreements that expressly adopt the tariff-shift test as the primary method to determine origin (such as NAFTA and the EEA) employ, in reality, the local content test in numerous cases. Consequently, it is possible to employ the Harmonized System as an overall framework to organize the numerous origin requirements. Still, the analysis made in the text above directs us to the conclusion that it is highly desirable that the concrete origin requirements, included in the Harmonized System or in any other framework, employ the local content test.
  • 123
    • 26044449316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See the discussion at the first part of Section VI.
  • 124
    • 26044438461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the surveys in Vermulst, as note 26 above, pp. 82-86
    • See the surveys in Vermulst, as note 26 above, pp. 82-86;
  • 125
    • 26044435403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Waer, as note 25 above, pp. 149-151
    • Waer, as note 25 above, pp. 149-151;
  • 126
    • 26044463719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephenson and James, as note 36 above, pp. 85-87
    • Stephenson and James, as note 36 above, pp. 85-87;
  • 127
    • 26044458570 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Palmeter, as note 37 above, pp. 349-351
    • Palmeter, as note 37 above, pp. 349-351.
  • 128
    • 26044431904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also, LaNasa, as note 38 above, pp. 399-400
    • See also, LaNasa, as note 38 above, pp. 399-400;
  • 129
    • 26044473915 scopus 로고
    • Special trade law issues in the EC for assembly products
    • August
    • Tim McNamara and Edwin Vermulst, Special Trade Law Issues in the EC for Assembly Products, 28 J.W.T. 4 (August 1994), 83, 87-89;
    • (1994) 28 J.W.T. , vol.4 , pp. 83
    • McNamara, T.1    Vermulst, E.2
  • 130
    • 26044461640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • APEC and preferential rules of origin: Stumbling blocks for liberalization of trade?
    • June 1993
    • William E. James, APEC and Preferential Rules of Origin: Stumbling Blocks for Liberalization of Trade?, 31 J.W.T. 3 (June 1993), 113, 126-127;
    • 31 J.W.T. , vol.3 , pp. 113
    • James, W.E.1
  • 131
    • 26044432462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zaimis, as note 31 above, pp 43-45
    • Zaimis, as note 31 above, pp 43-45;
  • 132
    • 26044469881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Komuro, as note 40 above, pp. 88-98
    • Komuro, as note 40 above, pp. 88-98;
  • 133
    • 26044481148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Restructuring rules of origin in the US-Israel free trade agreement
    • Allan S. Galper, Restructuring Rules of Origin in the US-Israel Free Trade Agreement, 19 Fordham International Law Journal (1996), 2028, 2042-2043, 2055-2067.
    • (1996) 19 Fordham International Law Journal , pp. 2028
    • Galper, A.S.1
  • 134
    • 26044464763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The rate of 62.5 percent is applied to certain automobiles under NAFTA and is considered "highly restrictive";
  • 135
    • 26044435132 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LaNasa, as note 26 above, p. 399
    • LaNasa, as note 26 above, p. 399;
  • 136
    • 26044454568 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • on the (protectionist) process that led to the establishment of this rule, see pp. 399-402.
  • 137
    • 26044442771 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The 35 percent rate is provided for in the 1985 Israel-US FTA, in various US assistance programs (e.g., the GSP and Caribbean Initiative Basin), and in South Korea's legislation; Galper, as note 69 above, pp. 2055-2058, 2065-2067;
  • 138
    • 26044463165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Vermulst, as note 26 above, p. 88
    • Vermulst, as note 26 above, p. 88;
  • 139
    • 26044441316 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Komuro, as note 40 above, p. 98
    • Komuro, as note 40 above, p. 98.
  • 140
    • 26044451446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • LaNasa, as note 26 above, pp. 633-634
    • LaNasa, as note 26 above, pp. 633-634;
  • 141
    • 26044443740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stephenson and James, as note 36 above, pp. 85-87
    • Stephenson and James, as note 36 above, pp. 85-87;
  • 142
    • 26044480628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zaimis, as note 31 above, p. 46
    • Zaimis, as note 31 above, p. 46.
  • 143
    • 26044472092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an in-depth analysis of the asymmetric impact of ROO, see Hirsch, as note 31 above, p. 45
    • For an in-depth analysis of the asymmetric impact of ROO, see Hirsch, as note 31 above, p. 45.
  • 144
    • 0003541756 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA, MIT Press
    • The size of the factor pool available to each party is not easily measurable. Still, the existence of a substantial gap is noticeable in numerous settings (although not precisely measurable). This is the case, for instance, with regard to trade agreements between most states and the European Community or the US. For a comprehensive analysis of the measurement and impact of factor endowments upon patterns of trade, see Edward E. Leamer, Sources of International Comparative Advantage: Theory and Evidence (Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 1984), pp. 90-94, 220-236;
    • (1984) Sources of International Comparative Advantage: Theory and Evidence , pp. 90-94
    • Leamer, E.E.1
  • 145
    • 0002931416 scopus 로고
    • Measures of openness
    • Robert E. Baldwin (ed.), Chicago, University of Chicago Press
    • Edward E. Learner, "Measures of Openness", in Robert E. Baldwin (ed.), Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis (Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1988), pp. 147, 179-199;
    • (1988) Trade Policy Issues and Empirical Analysis , pp. 147
    • Learner, E.E.1
  • 146


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.