메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 18, Issue 2, 2004, Pages

From good communists to even better capitalists? Entrepreneurial pathways in post-socialist Romania

Author keywords

Entrepreneurship; Politics; Post socialist transition; Romania

Indexed keywords


EID: 2442604114     PISSN: 08883254     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/0888325403259864     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (65)

References (142)
  • 2
    • 0003453120 scopus 로고
    • New York: Praeger
    • See Milovan Djilas, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System of Power (New York: Praeger, 1957); Leon Trostky, The Revolution Betrayed: What Is the Soviet Union and Where Is It Going? (New York: Pathfinder, 1972); George Konrad and Ivan Szelényi, The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1979).
    • (1957) The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System of Power
    • Djilas, M.1
  • 3
    • 0040029030 scopus 로고
    • New York: Pathfinder
    • See Milovan Djilas, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System of Power (New York: Praeger, 1957); Leon Trostky, The Revolution Betrayed: What Is the Soviet Union and Where Is It Going? (New York: Pathfinder, 1972); George Konrad and Ivan Szelényi, The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1979).
    • (1972) The Revolution Betrayed: What Is the Soviet Union and Where Is It Going?
    • Trostky, L.1
  • 4
    • 0003844292 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich
    • See Milovan Djilas, The New Class: An Analysis of the Communist System of Power (New York: Praeger, 1957); Leon Trostky, The Revolution Betrayed: What Is the Soviet Union and Where Is It Going? (New York: Pathfinder, 1972); George Konrad and Ivan Szelényi, The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1979).
    • (1979) The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power
    • Konrad, G.1    Szelényi, I.2
  • 7
    • 0003810810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford, UK: Clarendon
    • See Elemer Hankiss, East European Alternatives (Oxford, UK: Clarendon, 1990); Jadwiga Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism In Poland," East European Politics and Societies 5 (1991): 127-41; David Stark, "Privatization in Hungary: From Plan to Market or from Plan to Clan?" East European Politics and Societies 4 (1990): 351-92.
    • (1990) East European Alternatives
    • Hankiss, E.1
  • 8
    • 84973691303 scopus 로고
    • Political capitalism in Poland
    • See Elemer Hankiss, East European Alternatives (Oxford, UK: Clarendon, 1990); Jadwiga Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism In Poland," East European Politics and Societies 5 (1991): 127-41; David Stark, "Privatization in Hungary: From Plan to Market or from Plan to Clan?" East European Politics and Societies 4 (1990): 351-92.
    • (1991) East European Politics and Societies , vol.5 , pp. 127-141
    • Staniszkis, J.1
  • 9
    • 84973672844 scopus 로고
    • Privatization in Hungary: From plan to market or from plan to clan?
    • See Elemer Hankiss, East European Alternatives (Oxford, UK: Clarendon, 1990); Jadwiga Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism In Poland," East European Politics and Societies 5 (1991): 127-41; David Stark, "Privatization in Hungary: From Plan to Market or from Plan to Clan?" East European Politics and Societies 4 (1990): 351-92.
    • (1990) East European Politics and Societies , vol.4 , pp. 351-392
    • Stark, D.1
  • 11
    • 0007431449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Madison: University of Wisconsin Press
    • For an initial formulation of this thesis, see Ivan Szelényi, Socialist Entrepreneurs (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1988). For other works that deal with the second economy under state socialism, see Martha Lampland, "Pigs, Party Secretaries, and Private Lives in Hungary," American Ethnologist 3 (1991): 459-79; Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 21-47; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Maria Łoś, ed., The Second Economy in Marxist States (London: Macmillan, 1990). Following Lampland and Róna-Tas, by "second economy" I refer to economic activities organized outside the state sector, which were legally tolerated by communist regimes.
    • (1988) Socialist Entrepreneurs
    • Szelényi, I.1
  • 12
    • 84981926349 scopus 로고
    • Pigs, party secretaries, and private lives in Hungary
    • For an initial formulation of this thesis, see Ivan Szelényi, Socialist Entrepreneurs (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1988). For other works that deal with the second economy under state socialism, see Martha Lampland, "Pigs, Party Secretaries, and Private Lives in Hungary," American Ethnologist 3 (1991): 459-79; Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 21-47; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Maria Łoś, ed., The Second Economy in Marxist States (London: Macmillan, 1990). Following Lampland and Róna-Tas, by "second economy" I refer to economic activities organized outside the state sector, which were legally tolerated by communist regimes.
    • (1991) American Ethnologist , vol.3 , pp. 459-479
    • Lampland, M.1
  • 13
    • 0010995296 scopus 로고
    • The second economy as a subversive force: The erosion of party power in Hungary
    • Andrew Walder, ed. (Berkeley: University of California Press)
    • For an initial formulation of this thesis, see Ivan Szelényi, Socialist Entrepreneurs (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1988). For other works that deal with the second economy under state socialism, see Martha Lampland, "Pigs, Party Secretaries, and Private Lives in Hungary," American Ethnologist 3 (1991): 459-79; Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 21-47; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Maria Łoś, ed., The Second Economy in Marxist States (London: Macmillan, 1990). Following Lampland and Róna-Tas, by "second economy" I refer to economic activities organized outside the state sector, which were legally tolerated by communist regimes.
    • (1995) The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China , pp. 21-47
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 14
    • 0003719838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • For an initial formulation of this thesis, see Ivan Szelényi, Socialist Entrepreneurs (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1988). For other works that deal with the second economy under state socialism, see Martha Lampland, "Pigs, Party Secretaries, and Private Lives in Hungary," American Ethnologist 3 (1991): 459-79; Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 21-47; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Maria Łoś, ed., The Second Economy in Marxist States (London: Macmillan, 1990). Following Lampland and Róna-Tas, by "second economy" I refer to economic activities organized outside the state sector, which were legally tolerated by communist regimes.
    • (1997) The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 15
    • 85007061035 scopus 로고
    • London: Macmillan
    • For an initial formulation of this thesis, see Ivan Szelényi, Socialist Entrepreneurs (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1988). For other works that deal with the second economy under state socialism, see Martha Lampland, "Pigs, Party Secretaries, and Private Lives in Hungary," American Ethnologist 3 (1991): 459-79; Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 21-47; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise of the Small Transformation: The Demise of Communism and the Rise of the Private Sector in Hungary (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1997); Maria Łoś, ed., The Second Economy in Marxist States (London: Macmillan, 1990). Following Lampland and Róna-Tas, by "second economy" I refer to economic activities organized outside the state sector, which were legally tolerated by communist regimes.
    • (1990) The Second Economy in Marxist States
    • Łoś, M.1
  • 16
    • 0033838248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Self-employment in post-communist eastern Europe: A refuge from poverty or a road to riches?
    • For an excellent overview of this thesis, see Eric Hanley, "Self-Employment in Post-communist Eastern Europe: A Refuge from Poverty or a Road to Riches?" Communist and Post-communist Studies 33 (2000): 379-402; see also T. Laky, "Characterization of Privatization in Hungary and Some of Its Effects," In Jacques Hersh and Johannes Dragsbaek Schmidt, eds., The Aftermath of 'Real Existing Socialism': People and Technology in the Process of Transition, vol. 2. (London: Macmillian, 1996); Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism," 127-41.
    • (2000) Communist and Post-communist Studies , vol.33 , pp. 379-402
    • Hanley, E.1
  • 17
    • 0033838248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Characterization of privatization in Hungary and some of its effects
    • Jacques Hersh and Johannes Dragsbaek Schmidt, eds. (London: Macmillian)
    • For an excellent overview of this thesis, see Eric Hanley, "Self-Employment in Post-communist Eastern Europe: A Refuge from Poverty or a Road to Riches?" Communist and Post-communist Studies 33 (2000): 379-402; see also T. Laky, "Characterization of Privatization in Hungary and Some of Its Effects," In Jacques Hersh and Johannes Dragsbaek Schmidt, eds., The Aftermath of 'Real Existing Socialism': People and Technology in the Process of Transition, vol. 2. (London: Macmillian, 1996); Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism," 127-41.
    • (1996) The Aftermath of 'Real Existing Socialism': People and Technology in the Process of Transition , vol.2
    • Laky, T.1
  • 18
    • 0033838248 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an excellent overview of this thesis, see Eric Hanley, "Self-Employment in Post-communist Eastern Europe: A Refuge from Poverty or a Road to Riches?" Communist and Post-communist Studies 33 (2000): 379-402; see also T. Laky, "Characterization of Privatization in Hungary and Some of Its Effects," In Jacques Hersh and Johannes Dragsbaek Schmidt, eds., The Aftermath of 'Real Existing Socialism': People and Technology in the Process of Transition, vol. 2. (London: Macmillian, 1996); Staniszkis, "Political Capitalism," 127-41.
    • Political Capitalism , pp. 127-141
    • Staniszkis1
  • 19
    • 84993748490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Path dependence and capital theory: Sociology of the post-communist economic transformation
    • For a theoretical analysis of forms of capital in transitional economies, see Akos Róna-Tas, "Path Dependence and Capital Theory: Sociology of the Post-communist Economic Transformation," East European Politics and Societies 12 (1998): 107-31.
    • (1998) East European Politics and Societies , vol.12 , pp. 107-131
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 20
    • 0024800380 scopus 로고
    • A theory of market transition
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1989) American Sociological Review , vol.54 , pp. 663-681
    • Nee, V.1
  • 21
    • 0026314969 scopus 로고
    • Social inequalities in reforming state socialism: Between redistribution and markets in China
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1991) American Sociological Review , vol.56 , pp. 267-282
    • Nee, V.1
  • 22
    • 0030552785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The economic sociology of the transitions from socialism
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 1074-1081
    • Fligstein, N.1
  • 23
    • 0030461973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The emergence of market society: Changing mechanisms of stratification in China
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 908-949
    • Nee, V.1
  • 24
    • 0030559020 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The great transition: China, Hungary, and sociology exit socialism into the market
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 1028-1041
    • Oberschall, A.1
  • 25
    • 0030463090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Recombinant property in east European capitalism
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 993-1027
    • Stark, D.1
  • 26
    • 0030558077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The market transition debate: Towards a synthesis?
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 1082-1086
    • Ivan, I.S.1    Kostello, E.2
  • 27
    • 0030559943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Markets and inequality in transitional economies: Towards testable theories
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (1996) American Journal of Sociology , vol.101 , pp. 1060-1073
    • Walder, A.1
  • 28
    • 0036245118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Markets and income inequalities in rural China: Political advantage in an expanding economy
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (2002) American Sociological Review , vol.67 , pp. 231-253
    • Walder, A.1
  • 29
    • 0036600916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Income determination and market opportunity in rural China, 1978-1996
    • Victor Nee, "A Theory of Market Transition" American Sociological Review 54 (1989): 663-81. For subsequent contributions to the so-called market transition debate, see Victor Nee, "Social Inequalities in Reforming State Socialism: Between Redistribution and Markets in China," American Sociological Review 56 (1991): 267-82; Neil Fligstein, "The Economic Sociology of the Transitions from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1074-81; Victor Nee, "The Emergence of Market Society: Changing Mechanisms of Stratification in China," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 908-49; Anthony Oberschall, "The Great Transition: China, Hungary, and Sociology Exit Socialism into the Market," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1028-41; David Stark, "Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 993-1027; Ivan Szelényi Ivan and Eric Kostello, "The Market Transition Debate: Towards a Synthesis?" American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1082-86; Andrew Walder, "Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Towards Testable Theories," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996): 1060-73. For the most recent contributions to this debate, see Andrew Walder, "Markets and Income Inequalities in Rural China: Political Advantage in an Expanding Economy," American Sociological Review 67 (2002): 231-53; Andrew Walder, "Income Determination and Market Opportunity in Rural China, 1978-1996," Journal of Comparative Economics 30 (2002): 354-75.
    • (2002) Journal of Comparative Economics , vol.30 , pp. 354-375
    • Walder, A.1
  • 33
    • 84861112511 scopus 로고
    • The first shall be the last? Entrepreneurship and communist cadres in the transition from socialism
    • Needless to say, the classification I present in the following pages is by no means the only possible way of grouping various theoretical approaches to post-socialist entrepreneurship. See, for instance, Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last? Entrepreneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transition from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 100 (1994): 40-69; Akos Róna-Tas, "Path Dependence and Capital Theory." Depending on their theoretical interest, other readers might construct other and/or more refined categories and might attach them other labels. Taking into account the questions I intend to answer in the Romanian case, this classification serves my purpose.
    • (1994) American Journal of Sociology , vol.100 , pp. 40-69
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 34
    • 84862360850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Needless to say, the classification I present in the following pages is by no means the only possible way of grouping various theoretical approaches to post-socialist entrepreneurship. See, for instance, Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last? Entrepreneurship and Communist Cadres in the Transition from Socialism," American Journal of Sociology 100 (1994): 40-69; Akos Róna-Tas, "Path Dependence and Capital Theory." Depending on their theoretical interest, other readers might construct other and/or more refined categories and might attach them other labels. Taking into account the questions I intend to answer in the Romanian case, this classification serves my purpose.
    • Path Dependence and Capital Theory
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 35
    • 84976926662 scopus 로고
    • Path dependence and privatization strategies in east central Europe
    • David Stark, "Path Dependence and Privatization Strategies in East Central Europe," East European Politics and Societies 6 (1992): 17-54.
    • (1992) East European Politics and Societies , vol.6 , pp. 17-54
    • Stark, D.1
  • 44
    • 3042612060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Underground activity and institutional change
    • Joan M. Nelson, Charles Tilly, and Lee Walker, eds., (Washington, DC: National Academy Press)
    • Edgar L. Feige, "Underground Activity and Institutional Change," in Joan M. Nelson, Charles Tilly, and Lee Walker, eds., Transforming Post-communist Political Economies (Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1997), 29.
    • (1997) Transforming Post-communist Political Economies , pp. 29
    • Feige, E.L.1
  • 47
    • 0039715293 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Capitalism with a Comrade's Face
    • Roman Frydman, Kenneth Murphy, and Andrejz Rapaczynski, "Capitalism with a Comrade's Face," Transition 2 (1996): 5-11.
    • (1996) Transition , vol.2 , pp. 5-11
    • Frydman, R.1    Murphy, K.2    Rapaczynski, A.3
  • 50
    • 2442560524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., 117-18; see also Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe."
    • Making Capitalism , pp. 117-118
  • 53
    • 2442486936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • David Stark, "Recombinant Property." See also Lawrence King, The Basic Features of Postcommunist Capitalism: Firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Westport, CT: Praerger, 2001). For other "mutant" capitalist strategies, see Michael Burawoy and Pavel Krotov, "The Soviet Transition from Socialism to Capitalism: Worker Control and Economic Bargaining in the Wood Industry," American Sociological Review 57 (1992); 16-38; Michael Burawoy, Pavel Krotov, and Tatyana Lytkina, "Involution and Destitution in Capitalist Russia," Ethnography 1 (2000): 43-56.
    • Recombinant Property
    • Stark, D.1
  • 54
    • 0003505191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Westport, CT: Praerger
    • David Stark, "Recombinant Property." See also Lawrence King, The Basic Features of Postcommunist Capitalism: Firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Westport, CT: Praerger, 2001). For other "mutant" capitalist strategies, see Michael Burawoy and Pavel Krotov, "The Soviet Transition from Socialism to Capitalism: Worker Control and Economic Bargaining in the Wood Industry," American Sociological Review 57 (1992); 16-38; Michael Burawoy, Pavel Krotov, and Tatyana Lytkina, "Involution and Destitution in Capitalist Russia," Ethnography 1 (2000): 43-56.
    • (2001) The Basic Features of Postcommunist Capitalism: Firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia
    • King, L.1
  • 55
    • 0026471749 scopus 로고
    • The soviet transition from socialism to capitalism: Worker control and economic bargaining in the wood industry
    • David Stark, "Recombinant Property." See also Lawrence King, The Basic Features of Postcommunist Capitalism: Firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Westport, CT: Praerger, 2001). For other "mutant" capitalist strategies, see Michael Burawoy and Pavel Krotov, "The Soviet Transition from Socialism to Capitalism: Worker Control and Economic Bargaining in the Wood Industry," American Sociological Review 57 (1992); 16-38; Michael Burawoy, Pavel Krotov, and Tatyana Lytkina, "Involution and Destitution in Capitalist Russia," Ethnography 1 (2000): 43-56.
    • (1992) American Sociological Review , vol.57 , pp. 16-38
    • Burawoy, M.1    Krotov, P.2
  • 56
    • 84993683924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Involution and destitution in capitalist Russia
    • David Stark, "Recombinant Property." See also Lawrence King, The Basic Features of Postcommunist Capitalism: Firms in Hungary, the Czech Republic, and Slovakia (Westport, CT: Praerger, 2001). For other "mutant" capitalist strategies, see Michael Burawoy and Pavel Krotov, "The Soviet Transition from Socialism to Capitalism: Worker Control and Economic Bargaining in the Wood Industry," American Sociological Review 57 (1992); 16-38; Michael Burawoy, Pavel Krotov, and Tatyana Lytkina, "Involution and Destitution in Capitalist Russia," Ethnography 1 (2000): 43-56.
    • (2000) Ethnography , vol.1 , pp. 43-56
    • Burawoy, M.1    Krotov, P.2    Lytkina, T.3
  • 57
    • 0007431449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of previous studies on proletarianization and "peasant-workers" theory, see Szelényl, Socialist Entrepreneurs, 45-50.
    • Socialist Entrepreneurs , pp. 45-50
    • Szelényl1
  • 59
    • 84862359395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For other studies on the second economy, see Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise. For the Chinese case, see David Wank, Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999); David Wank, "Producing Property Rights: Strategies, Networks, and Efficiency in Urban China," in Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999), 248-76.
    • The First Shall Be the Last?
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 60
    • 4243664709 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For other studies on the second economy, see Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise. For the Chinese case, see David Wank, Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999); David Wank, "Producing Property Rights: Strategies, Networks, and Efficiency in Urban China," in Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999), 248-76.
    • The Great Surprise
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 61
    • 0003581206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • For other studies on the second economy, see Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise. For the Chinese case, see David Wank, Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999); David Wank, "Producing Property Rights: Strategies, Networks, and Efficiency in Urban China," in Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999), 248-76.
    • (1999) Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City
    • Wank, D.1
  • 62
    • 0002909719 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Producing property rights: Strategies, networks, and efficiency in urban China
    • Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press
    • For other studies on the second economy, see Akos Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Akos Róna-Tas, The Great Surprise. For the Chinese case, see David Wank, Commodifying Communism: Business, Trust, and Politics in a Chinese City (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999); David Wank, "Producing Property Rights: Strategies, Networks, and Efficiency in Urban China," in Jean Oi and Andrew Walder, eds., Property Rights and Economic Reform in China (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 1999), 248-76.
    • (1999) Property Rights and Economic Reform in China , pp. 248-276
    • Wank, D.1
  • 63
    • 0010995296 scopus 로고
    • The second economy as a subversive force: The erosion of party power in Hungary
    • Andrew Walder, ed., Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Akos Róna-Tas, "The Second Economy as a Subversive Force: The Erosion of Party Power in Hungary," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 61-84.
    • (1995) The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China , pp. 61-84
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 64
    • 0001818014 scopus 로고
    • The quiet revolution from within: Economic reform as a source of political decline
    • Andrew Walder, ed., Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Andrew Walder, "The Quiet Revolution from Within: Economic Reform as a Source of Political Decline," in Andrew Walder, ed., The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 1-24.
    • (1995) The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in Hungary and China , pp. 1-24
    • Walder, A.1
  • 65
    • 85171512390 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: University of California Press
    • Besides the former socialist entrepreneurs, there are other individuals who might possess the cultural capital required to successfully function as businesspersons during market transition. These individuals are those who, being unemployed or "without an occupation," operated full-time on the black market or in the gray economy under state socialism. Labeled "social parasites" by the communist regime (i.e., individuals who did not work according to [their] abilities), these people were mainly involved in illicit trade. Gall Kligman, The Politics of Duplicity: Controlling Reproduction in Ceauşescu's Romania (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998), 33. This entrepreneurial type is similar to the one discussed by Wank in the case of China before the reform era, that is, the "speculator" entrepreneurial type. See Wank, Commodtfying Communism, 116-20. Although some of the former speculators are probably at an advantage in post-socialism, the survey data I employ in this article do not contain any information about an individual's (full-time) involvement in illegal economic activities before the fall of Ceausescu's regime.
    • (1998) The Politics of Duplicity: Controlling Reproduction in Ceauşescu's Romania , pp. 33
    • Kligman, G.1
  • 66
    • 2442552038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Besides the former socialist entrepreneurs, there are other individuals who might possess the cultural capital required to successfully function as businesspersons during market transition. These individuals are those who, being unemployed or "without an occupation," operated full-time on the black market or in the gray economy under state socialism. Labeled "social parasites" by the communist regime (i.e., individuals who did not work according to [their] abilities), these people were mainly involved in illicit trade. Gall Kligman, The Politics of Duplicity: Controlling Reproduction in Ceauşescu's Romania (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1998), 33. This entrepreneurial type is similar to the one discussed by Wank in the case of China before the reform era, that is, the "speculator" entrepreneurial type. See Wank, Commodtfying Communism, 116-20. Although some of the former speculators are probably at an advantage in post-socialism, the survey data I employ in this article do not contain any information about an individual's (full-time) involvement in illegal economic activities before the fall of Ceausescu's regime.
    • Commodtfying Communism , pp. 116-120
    • Wank1
  • 67
    • 2442464950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This section heavily draws on Eric Hanley's excellent discussion of theoretical approaches to self-employment. See Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe."
    • Self-Employment in Eastern Europe
    • Hanley1
  • 70
    • 2442543548 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • I refer here to the market transition debate in the American Journal of Sociology and American Sociological Review, a debate that has been triggered by Victor Nee's article "A Theory of Market Transition" (1989). For contributions to this debate, see footnote 10 in this article.
    • American Journal of Sociology and American Sociological Review
  • 71
    • 0039474327 scopus 로고
    • I refer here to the market transition debate in the American Journal of Sociology and American Sociological Review, a debate that has been triggered by Victor Nee's article "A Theory of Market Transition" (1989). For contributions to this debate, see footnote 10 in this article.
    • (1989) A Theory of Market Transition
    • Nee, V.1
  • 72
    • 84863187594 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Privatization and elite mobility: Rural China, 1979-1996
    • Stanford, CA: Institute for International Studies, Stanford University
    • Andrew Walder, "Privatization and Elite Mobility: Rural China, 1979-1996," Asia/Pacific Research Center Working Papers Series. (Stanford, CA: Institute for International Studies, Stanford University, 2002), 8.
    • (2002) Asia/Pacific Research Center Working Papers Series , pp. 8
    • Walder, A.1
  • 74
    • 84993748490 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Path dependence and capital theory: Sociology of the post-communist economic transformation
    • Akos Róna-Tas, "Path Dependence and Capital Theory: Sociology of the Post-communist Economic Transformation," East European Politics and Societies 12 (1998): 107-131.
    • (1998) East European Politics and Societies , vol.12 , pp. 107-131
    • Róna-Tas, A.1
  • 75
    • 0034397148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cadre capitalism in Hungary and Poland: Property accumulation among communist-era elites
    • Eric Hanley, "Cadre Capitalism in Hungary and Poland: Property Accumulation among Communist-Era Elites," East European Politics and Societies 14 (2000): 176-77.
    • (2000) East European Politics and Societies , vol.14 , pp. 176-177
    • Hanley, E.1
  • 77
    • 0041762063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The determinants of economic reform in the postcommunist world
    • According to Fish, the best predictor of economic reforms - from a list that includes numerous economic, political, and sociocultural factors - is the outcome of the first post-communist competitive elections. See Steven Fish, "The Determinants of Economic Reform in the Postcommunist World," East European Politics and Societies 12 (1998): 31-78. That is, economic reforms were more likely to be introduced in those countries where the former communists lost the first free elections. For a critique of Fish, see Jeffrey Kopstein and David Reilly, "Explaining the Why of Why: A Comment on Fish's 'Determinants of Economic Reform in the Post-communist World'." East European Politics and Societies, 13 (1999): 613-24.
    • (1998) East European Politics and Societies , vol.12 , pp. 31-78
    • Fish, S.1
  • 78
    • 0033468420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining the why of why: A comment on fish's 'determinants of economic reform in the post-communist world
    • According to Fish, the best predictor of economic reforms - from a list that includes numerous economic, political, and sociocultural factors - is the outcome of the first post-communist competitive elections. See Steven Fish, "The Determinants of Economic Reform in the Postcommunist World," East European Politics and Societies 12 (1998): 31-78. That is, economic reforms were more likely to be introduced in those countries where the former communists lost the first free elections. For a critique of Fish, see Jeffrey Kopstein and David Reilly, "Explaining the Why of Why: A Comment on Fish's 'Determinants of Economic Reform in the Post-communist World'." East European Politics and Societies, 13 (1999): 613-24.
    • (1999) East European Politics and Societies , vol.13 , pp. 613-624
    • Kopstein, J.1    Reilly, D.2
  • 79
    • 0242648700 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Postsocialisms
    • in Sorin Antohi and Vladimir Tismǎneanu, eds., Budapest, Hungary: Central European University Press
    • For a more detailed discussion of this interpretation, see Valerie Bunce, "Postsocialisms," in Sorin Antohi and Vladimir Tismǎneanu, eds., Between Past and Future: The Revolutions of 1989 and Their Aftermath (Budapest, Hungary: Central European University Press, 2000), 122-52.
    • (2000) Between Past and Future: The Revolutions of 1989 and Their Aftermath , pp. 122-152
    • Bunce, V.1
  • 80
    • 84890678774 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • See Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995); Peter Evans and James E. Rauch, "Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of 'Weberian' State Structures on Economic Growth," American Sociological Review 64 (1999): 748-65.
    • (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation
    • Evans, P.1
  • 81
    • 0033398128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bureaucracy and growth: A cross-national analysis of the effects of 'Weberian' state structures on economic growth
    • See Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy. States and Industrial Transformation (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1995); Peter Evans and James E. Rauch, "Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of 'Weberian' State Structures on Economic Growth," American Sociological Review 64 (1999): 748-65.
    • (1999) American Sociological Review , vol.64 , pp. 748-765
    • Evans, P.1    Rauch, J.E.2
  • 85
    • 2442604645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The surveys were conducted by two private research agencies: Metro-Media Transylvania (May 2000) and the Center for Urban and Regional Sociology (November 2000).
  • 88
    • 4244099547 scopus 로고
    • Small leap forward: Emergence of new economic elites
    • In general, to the best of my knowledge, event history data have been less frequently used in studies of transition in Eastern Europe. For studies that employ data about individuals' sociodemographic characteristics before and three of fours years after the collapse of the communist regimes, see Joszef Böröcz and Akos Róna-Tas, "Small Leap Forward: Emergence of New Economic Elites," Theory and Society 24 (1995); 751-81; Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Eyal et al., Making Capitalism; Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe." My surveys are similar to those employed by Róna-Tas in his study of post-socialist entrepreneurship in Hungary. Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?" Yet the Romanian surveys did not ask respondents about their income before 1990. Lacking this information, I could not address the issue of income inequality before and after 1990, as Róna-Tas did in his study.
    • (1995) Theory and Society , vol.24 , pp. 751-781
    • Böröcz, J.1    Róna-Tas, A.2
  • 89
    • 84862359395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In general, to the best of my knowledge, event history data have been less frequently used in studies of transition in Eastern Europe. For studies that employ data about individuals' sociodemographic characteristics before and three of fours years after the collapse of the communist regimes, see Joszef Böröcz and Akos Róna-Tas, "Small Leap Forward: Emergence of New Economic Elites," Theory and Society 24 (1995); 751-81; Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Eyal et al., Making Capitalism; Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe." My surveys are similar to those employed by Róna-Tas in his study of post-socialist entrepreneurship in Hungary. Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?" Yet the Romanian surveys did not ask respondents about their income before 1990. Lacking this information, I could not address the issue of income inequality before and after 1990, as Róna-Tas did in his study.
    • The First Shall Be the Last?
    • Róna-Tas1
  • 90
    • 2442430633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In general, to the best of my knowledge, event history data have been less frequently used in studies of transition in Eastern Europe. For studies that employ data about individuals' sociodemographic characteristics before and three of fours years after the collapse of the communist regimes, see Joszef Böröcz and Akos Róna-Tas, "Small Leap Forward: Emergence of New Economic Elites," Theory and Society 24 (1995); 751-81; Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Eyal et al., Making Capitalism; Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe." My surveys are similar to those employed by Róna-Tas in his study of post-socialist entrepreneurship in Hungary. Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?" Yet the Romanian surveys did not ask respondents about their income before 1990. Lacking this information, I could not address the issue of income inequality before and after 1990, as Róna-Tas did in his study.
    • Making Capitalism
    • Eyal1
  • 91
    • 2442464950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In general, to the best of my knowledge, event history data have been less frequently used in studies of transition in Eastern Europe. For studies that employ data about individuals' sociodemographic characteristics before and three of fours years after the collapse of the communist regimes, see Joszef Böröcz and Akos Róna-Tas, "Small Leap Forward: Emergence of New Economic Elites," Theory and Society 24 (1995); 751-81; Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Eyal et al., Making Capitalism; Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe." My surveys are similar to those employed by Róna-Tas in his study of post-socialist entrepreneurship in Hungary. Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?" Yet the Romanian surveys did not ask respondents about their income before 1990. Lacking this information, I could not address the issue of income inequality before and after 1990, as Róna-Tas did in his study.
    • Self-Employment in Eastern Europe
    • Hanley1
  • 92
    • 84862357743 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Poverty, inequality, and social protection
    • Paper presented at the
    • In 1998 in Romania, the average monthly income was less than US$100, and about 34 percent of the population (or almost 8 million people) lived below the poverty line. See Cornelia Tesliuc and Lucian Pop, "Poverty, Inequality, and Social Protection" (Paper presented at the World Bank's Conference "Romania 2000: 10 Years of Transition - Past, Present, Future," 1999), 7. As compared to Hungary, Poland, Czech Republic, and Bulgaria, Romania had the highest poverty rate in 1998. Data from 2000 indicate that the situation further deteriorated: more than 40 percent of the Romanian population lived below the poverty line at the time of the surveys, while the average monthly income still was less than US$100.
    • (1999) World Bank's Conference "Romania 2000: 10 Years of Transition - Past, Present, Future," , pp. 7
    • Tesliuc, C.1    Pop, L.2
  • 93
    • 0039436863 scopus 로고
    • Stratification research in a changing world
    • J. Szmatka, Z. Mach, and J. Mucha, eds., Lewiston, NY: Edwin Mellen Press
    • Mikk Titma and Nancy Brandon Tuma, "Stratification Research in a Changing World," In J. Szmatka, Z. Mach, and J. Mucha, eds., Eastern European Societies on the Threshold of Change (Lewiston, NY: Edwin Mellen Press, 1993), 231-54.
    • (1993) Eastern European Societies on the Threshold of Change , pp. 231-254
    • Titma, M.1    Tuma, N.B.2
  • 94
    • 0033467738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The sociology of entrepreneurship
    • Patricia H. Thronton, "The Sociology of Entrepreneurship," Annual Review of Sociology 25 (1999): 19-46.
    • (1999) Annual Review of Sociology , vol.25 , pp. 19-46
    • Thronton, P.H.1
  • 95
    • 27844476925 scopus 로고
    • Bucuresti: Ed. Humanitas
    • The source for these variables was an open-ended question about a respondent's occupation before 1990. The answers entered In the database did not allow me to further distinguish between private farmers and those in collective farms before 1990. In contrast to Poland and Hungary, in socialist Romania, 96 percent of the agriculture was collectivized. Vlad Georgescu, Istoria românilor: de la origini pÎn? ̂n zilele noastre (Bucuresti: Ed. Humanitas, 1992). However, almost all peasants in collective farms were allowed to own and cultivate small plots of land, and - despite restrictions - some peasants engaged in limited production for the (gray) market.
    • (1992) Istoria Românilor: de la Origini Pîn? în Zilele Noastre
    • Georgescu, V.1
  • 96
    • 0003984746 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1979); SzelÉnyi, Socialist Entrepreneurs.
    • (1979) Outline of a Theory of Practice
    • Bourdieu, P.1
  • 97
    • 0007431449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Pierre Bourdieu, Outline of a Theory of Practice (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1979); SzelÉnyi, Socialist Entrepreneurs.
    • Socialist Entrepreneurs
    • Szelényi1
  • 100
    • 0041343462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Sage
    • Ideally, I should have employed a multinomial logistic regression. As compared to a binary logistic regression, the multinomial logistic regression has the advantage of simultaneously estimating all of the logits, which makes regression coefficients comparable across categories. Scott Long, Regression Models for Categorical and limited Dependent Variables (London: Sage, 1997), 150. Unfortunately, due to lack of cases (perfect determination) or to lack of variation in some of the categories of my independent variables, I could not employ a multinomial logistic regression. (See the note at the bottom of Table 3; see the appendix for an alternative modeling strategy.)
    • (1997) Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables , pp. 150
    • Long, S.1
  • 101
    • 85050422566 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moşna - Un sat care se reinventeaz?
    • My availability sample consisted of thirty-five current and former entrepreneurs, ex-cadres and ordinary people turned entrepreneurs, from owners of large businesses to self-employed individuals to individual farmers. My findings are fairly consistent with those reported by other studies conducted in Romania. See Manuela StǍnculescu and Ionica Berevoescu, "Moşna - un sat care se reinventeaz?" ["Moşna - A Village That Reinvents Itself] Sociologie româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] 1 (1999): 79-106; Sebastian Lǎzǎroiu, "Reţele de capital social şi antreprenori in Comişani" [Networks of Social Capital and Entrepreneurship in the Village of Comişani], Sociologie româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] 2 (1999): 31-56.
    • (1999) Sociologie Româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] , vol.1 , pp. 79-106
    • Stǎnculescu, M.1    Berevoescu, I.2
  • 102
    • 85055401314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reţele de capital social şi antreprenori in Comişani
    • My availability sample consisted of thirty-five current and former entrepreneurs, ex-cadres and ordinary people turned entrepreneurs, from owners of large businesses to self-employed individuals to individual farmers. My findings are fairly consistent with those reported by other studies conducted in Romania. See Manuela StǍnculescu and Ionica Berevoescu, "Moşna - un sat care se reinventeaz?" ["Moşna - A Village That Reinvents Itself] Sociologie româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] 1 (1999): 79-106; Sebastian Lǎzǎroiu, "Reţele de capital social şi antreprenori in Comişani" [Networks of Social Capital and Entrepreneurship in the Village of Comişani], Sociologie româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] 2 (1999): 31-56.
    • (1999) Sociologie Româneascǎ [Romanian Sociology] , vol.2 , pp. 31-56
    • Lǎzǎroiu, S.1
  • 103
  • 106
    • 27844531217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Georgescu, Istoria românilor, 310. Seemingly, in the late 1980s, 26 percent of the Romanian Communist Party members had a college degree or a diploma from other institutions of higher learning. In contrast, in 1990, around 9 percent of Romanians had a college degree. Also, in the late 1980s, 90.7 percent of activists in county, municipal, and town party committees were graduates of, or were attending, state institutions of higher education (cf. Library of Congress, "Country Studies: Romania Area Handbook Studies, 1989, available at http://memory.loc.gov/frd/cs/rotoc.html). Based on figures scarcely published in the party press in the 1980s, the same source estimates that Romanian Communist Party members represented 33 percent of Romania's working population, In my samples, around 30 percent of respondents were party members.
    • Istoria Românilor , pp. 310
    • Georgescu1
  • 107
    • 84862362883 scopus 로고
    • Library of congress
    • Georgescu, Istoria românilor, 310. Seemingly, in the late 1980s, 26 percent of the Romanian Communist Party members had a college degree or a diploma from other institutions of higher learning. In contrast, in 1990, around 9 percent of Romanians had a college degree. Also, in the late 1980s, 90.7 percent of activists in county, municipal, and town party committees were graduates of, or were attending, state institutions of higher education (cf. Library of Congress, "Country Studies: Romania Area Handbook Studies, 1989, available at http://memory.loc.gov/frd/cs/rotoc.html). Based on figures scarcely published in the party press in the 1980s, the same source estimates that Romanian Communist Party members represented 33 percent of Romania's working population, In my samples, around 30 percent of respondents were party members.
    • (1989) Country Studies: Romania Area Handbook Studies
  • 108
    • 84862368053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Illuminating analyses
    • In 1962, in an attempt to distance himself from his Stalinistic predecessor and to increase Hungarians' support for socialism, Kádár advocated a "politics of alliance" summarized by his now famous dictum "he who is not against us is with us." For details regarding the political histories of Central and Eastern European communist regimes, see Vladimir Tismǎneanu's illuminating analyses in Reinventing Politics. For readers interested in the Romanian case, Tismǎneanu remains by far the most authoritative voice on the trials and tribulations of Romanian communism. See, for instance, Stalinism for all Seasons: A Political History of Romanian Communism (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 2003), to name here but one of his many contributions to this topic.
    • Reinventing Politics
    • Tismǎneanu, V.1
  • 109
    • 20744460644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berkeley, CA: University of California Press
    • In 1962, in an attempt to distance himself from his Stalinistic predecessor and to increase Hungarians' support for socialism, Kádár advocated a "politics of alliance" summarized by his now famous dictum "he who is not against us is with us." For details regarding the political histories of Central and Eastern European communist regimes, see Vladimir Tismǎneanu's illuminating analyses in Reinventing Politics. For readers interested in the Romanian case, Tismǎneanu remains by far the most authoritative voice on the trials and tribulations of Romanian communism. See, for instance, Stalinism for all Seasons: A Political History of Romanian Communism (Berkeley, CA: University of
    • (2003) Stalinism for all Seasons: A Political History of Romanian Communism
  • 110
    • 33745852860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Walder, "Markets and Income Inequality"; Litao Zhao, "Human Capital, Political Capital, and Family Business: The Market Transition Debate Revisited" (Paper presented at the Third Graduate Student Retreat, Center for Comparative Social Research, Yale University, New Haven, CT, 2001).
    • Markets and Income Inequality
    • Walder1
  • 111
    • 2442478673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Human capital, political capital, and family business: The market transition debate revisited
    • Paper presented at the, Center for Comparative Social Research, Yale University, New Haven, CT
    • Walder, "Markets and Income Inequality"; Litao Zhao, "Human Capital, Political Capital, and Family Business: The Market Transition Debate Revisited" (Paper presented at the Third Graduate Student Retreat, Center for Comparative Social Research, Yale University, New Haven, CT, 2001).
    • (2001) Third Graduate Student Retreat
    • Zhao, L.1
  • 117
    • 2442430633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hanley, "Self-Employment in Eastern Europe"; Róna-Tas, "The First Shall Be the Last?"; Eyal et al., Making Capitalism.
    • Making Capitalism
    • Eyal1
  • 123
    • 84996220388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Seeing like a Mayor,' or how local officials obstructed romanian land restitution
    • Katherine Verdery, "'Seeing Like a Mayor,' Or How Local Officials Obstructed Romanian Land Restitution," Ethnography 3 (2002): 5-33.
    • (2002) Ethnography , vol.3 , pp. 5-33
    • Verdery, K.1
  • 128
    • 2442530943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Results of analyses not reported here for reasons of space indicate that farming is the least rewarding entrepreneurial career in Romania. In terms of average monthly income, the most rewarding strategies are, in ascending order, self-employment, part-time entrepreneurship, and being an employer. Among employers, the ex-cadres make on average approximately 1.7 times more money (measured by personal monthly income) than do employers who were not cadres.
  • 130
    • 0004188675 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See my previous discussion of Evans, Embedded Autonomy; for the original formulation of the effects of types of domination on the economy, see Weber, Economy and Society, 164-66.
    • Embedded Autonomy
    • Evans1
  • 131
    • 0003953213 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See my previous discussion of Evans, Embedded Autonomy; for the original formulation of the effects of types of domination on the economy, see Weber, Economy and Society, 164-66.
    • Economy and Society , pp. 164-166
    • Weber1
  • 133
    • 2442516478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Max Weber's vision of economic sociology
    • Mark Granovetter and Richard Swedberg, eds., Boulder, CO: Westview, esp. 88-92
    • Notable exceptions are Szelényi and his students Eyal, Townsley, and King, who have seriously embarked on an institutional analysis of postcommunist capitalism, very much in line with the Weberian tradition. By focusing on emerging forms of capitalism and taking into account factors ignored by other forms of "institutionalism," these authors, to their credit, also overcome some of the shortcomings of current developments in the new economic sociology. For such shortcomings of the new economic sociology, see Richard Swedberg, "Max Weber's Vision of Economic Sociology," in Mark Granovetter and Richard Swedberg, eds., The Sociology of Economic Life (Boulder, CO: Westview, 2001), esp. 88-92.
    • (2001) The Sociology of Economic Life
    • Swedberg, R.1
  • 135
  • 138
    • 84862361090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Change rules' review symposium
    • Joszef Böröcz, "'Change Rules' Review Symposium," American Journal of Sociology 106 (2001): 1163.
    • (2001) American Journal of Sociology , vol.106 , pp. 1163
    • Böröcz, J.1
  • 141
    • 0003802760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
    • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Transition Report (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 2001).
    • (2001) Transition Report
  • 142
    • 0039245258 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weber's last theory of capitalism: A systematization
    • Mark Granovetter and Richard Swedberg, eds., Boulder, CO: Westview, 2001, 390 (emphasis added)
    • Randall Collins, "Weber's Last Theory of Capitalism: A Systematization," In Mark Granovetter and Richard Swedberg, eds., The Sociology of Economic Life (Boulder, CO: Westview, 2001), 390 (emphasis added).
    • (2001) The Sociology of Economic Life
    • Collins, R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.