메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 73, Issue 6, 1998, Pages 1943-1977

A new options theory for risk multipliers of attorney's fees in federal civil rights litigation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 22444454399     PISSN: 00287881     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (6)

References (182)
  • 1
    • 25844505846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • VH-1 television broadcast, Aug. 13
    • Madonna, Video Timeline (VH-1 television broadcast, Aug. 13, 1998).
    • (1998) Video Timeline
    • Madonna1
  • 2
    • 84865914285 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In this article, the term "federal civil rights laws" includes both Reconstruction-era and modern civil rights statutes. For examples of the latter, see, e.g., Voting Rights Act of 1965, 42 U.S.C. § 1971 (1994); 42 U.S.C. §§ 1981-1983 (1994); Title VII of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, 42 U.S.C. § 2000(e) (1994 & Supp. 1995); Americans with Disabilities Act of 1990, 42 U.S.C. § 3601 (1994)
    • In this article, the term "federal civil rights laws" includes both Reconstruction-era and modern civil rights statutes. For examples of the latter, see, e.g., Voting Rights Act of 1965, 42 U.S.C. § 1971 (1994); 42 U.S.C. §§ 1981-1983 (1994); Title VII of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, 42 U.S.C. § 2000(e) (1994 & Supp. 1995); Americans with Disabilities Act of 1990, 42 U.S.C. § 3601 (1994).
  • 3
    • 0040739504 scopus 로고
    • Explaining Constitutional Tort Litigation: The Influence of the Attorney Fees Statute and the Government as Defendant
    • n.178
    • Professors Stewart Schwab and Theodore Eisenberg have found that most civil rights litigation is undertaken by solo practitioners and small private law firms. See Stewart J. Schwab & Theodore Eisenberg, Explaining Constitutional Tort Litigation: The Influence of the Attorney Fees Statute and the Government as Defendant, 73 Cornell L. Rev. 719, 768 n.178 (1988)
    • (1988) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.73 , pp. 719
    • Schwab, S.J.1    Eisenberg, T.2
  • 5
    • 0012848559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Value of the EEOC: Reexamining the Agency's Role in Employment Discrimination Law
    • Professor Michael Selmi also presents empirical data on the importance of private representation in enforcing federal civil rights. See Michael Selmi, The Value of the EEOC: Reexamining the Agency's Role in Employment Discrimination Law, 57 Ohio St. L.J. 1, 22, 57 (1996).
    • (1996) Ohio St. L.J. , vol.57 , pp. 1
    • Selmi, M.1
  • 6
    • 0346511005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Civil Rights Practice in the 1990s: The Dichotomy between Reality and Theory
    • Julie Davies, Federal Civil Rights Practice in the 1990s: The Dichotomy Between Reality and Theory, 48 Hastings L.J. 197, 262-63 (1997) (arguing that Supreme Court decisions since 1976 harmfully reduce incentives for private attorneys to accept civil rights cases).
    • (1997) Hastings L.J. , vol.48 , pp. 197
    • Davies, J.1
  • 7
    • 25844509961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Several federal civil rights statutes contain fee-shifting provisions. See, e.g., Age Discrimination in Employment Act of 1967, 29 U.S.C. § 626(b) (1994); Clean Water Act, 33 U.S.C. § 1369(b)(3) (1994); Civil Rights Attorney's Fees Awards Act of 1976, 42 U.S.C. § 1988(b) (1994); Title VII of the Civil Rights Act of 1964, 42 U.S.C. § 2000e-5(k) (1994); Fair Housing Act, 42 U.S.C. § 3613(c)(2) (1994); Americans with Disabilities Act, 42 U.S.C. § 12205 (1994). In addition, different states have their own state civil rights laws; California, for example, still allows courts discretion to award risk multipliers in areas like employment discrimination. See Cal. Civ. Proc. Code § 1021.5 (West 1980 & Supp. 1996). Other federal statutes promoting the public interest also authorize fee-shifting. See Privacy Act of 1974, 5 U.S.C. § 552a(g)(2)(B), (g)(3)(B) (1994 & Supp. 1996); Government in the Sunshine Act, 5 U.S.C. § 552b(i) (1994 & Supp. 1996); Equal Access to Justice Act, 28 U.S.C. §§ 2412(b), (d) (1994); Clean Air Act, 42 U.S.C. § 7607(f) (1994); Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act of 1980, 42 U.S.C. § 9659(f) (1994). Each issue of the Attorney Fee Awards Reporter, which is published bimonthly, includes an updated list of federal statutes authorizing the awarding of reasonable attorney's fees. The options theory of litigation presented in this Article not only applies to civil rights actions, but also to public interest lawsuits generally. The Supreme Court has stated that its rulings on risk multipliers apply uniformly to all fee award statutes. See City of Burlington v. Dague, 505 U.S. 557, 562 (1992).
  • 8
    • 25844450972 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court on Attorney Fee Awards, 1985 and 1986 Terms: Economics, Ethics, and Ex Ante Analysis
    • Davies, supra note 4, at 209-10 & n.50
    • Indeed, the number of attorney's fee cases on the Supreme Court's docket has increased significantly in the last decade. See Davies, supra note 4, at 209-10 & n.50 (citing Thomas D. Rowe, Jr., The Supreme Court on Attorney Fee Awards, 1985 and 1986 Terms: Economics, Ethics, and Ex Ante Analysis, 1 Geo. J. Legal Ethics 621, 632-36 (1988)).
    • (1988) Geo. J. Legal Ethics , vol.1 , pp. 621
    • Rowe Jr., T.D.1
  • 9
    • 84865914318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 200 (arguing that damages for discrimination against poor or underemployed are "too low to offer much compensation to an attorney in the event of a settlement")
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 200 (arguing that damages for discrimination against poor or underemployed are "too low to offer much compensation to an attorney in the event of a settlement").
  • 10
    • 25844486102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 246, 264 (citing expert fees, length of time in taking case to trial, defense strategies involving delay, and amount of resources channeled into collateral litigation as reasons for high cost of lawsuits)
    • See id. at 246, 264 (citing expert fees, length of time in taking case to trial, defense strategies involving delay, and amount of resources channeled into collateral litigation as reasons for high cost of lawsuits).
  • 11
    • 0003678077 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The term "risk" comes from an early Italian word "risicare" meaning "to dare." For a fascinating history of the role of risk in human society, see Peter L. Bernstein, Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk 8 (1996).
    • (1996) Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk , pp. 8
    • Bernstein, P.L.1
  • 12
    • 33644583374 scopus 로고
    • Court Awarded Attorneys' Fees: What Is "Reasonable"?
    • For more on such a traditional multiplier calculation, see Samuel R. Berger, Court Awarded Attorneys' Fees: What Is "Reasonable"?, 126 U. Pa. L. Rev. 281, 324-26 (1977) (discussing reasonableness of court-awarded attorney's fees);
    • (1977) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.126 , pp. 281
    • Berger, S.R.1
  • 13
    • 84927456907 scopus 로고
    • Compensation Formulas for Court Awarded Attorney Fees
    • Marshall J. Breger, Compensation Formulas for Court Awarded Attorney Fees, 47 Law & Contemp. Probs. 249, 259 (1984) (analyzing alternative approaches to attorney compensation rates);
    • (1984) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.47 , pp. 249
    • Breger, M.J.1
  • 14
    • 4344580428 scopus 로고
    • The Courts and the Plaintiffs Bar: Awarding the Attorney's Fee in Class-Action Litigation
    • William J. Lynk, The Courts and the Plaintiffs Bar: Awarding the Attorney's Fee in Class-Action Litigation, 23 J. Legal Stud. 185, 187 (1994) (discussing risk multiplier approach);
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 185
    • Lynk, W.J.1
  • 15
    • 84883173744 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Affidavit of Frank H. Easterbrook & Robert A. Sherwin at 2-3, In re Burlington Northern, Inc., Employment Practices Litigation, Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269, 1985 WL 1808 (N.D. Ill. May 31, 1985)
    • see also Affidavit of Frank H. Easterbrook & Robert A. Sherwin at 2-3, In re Burlington Northern, Inc., Employment Practices Litigation, Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269, 1985 WL 1808 (N.D. Ill. May 31, 1985) (on file with the New York University Law Review) (discussing factors affecting multiplier).
    • New York University Law Review
  • 16
    • 25844457746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See infra Part I (discussing Supreme Court treatment of risk multipliers)
    • See infra Part I (discussing Supreme Court treatment of risk multipliers).
  • 17
    • 25844460584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two U.S. Economists Win Nobel Prize: Merton and Scholes Share Award for Breakthrough in Pricing Stock Options
    • Oct. 15
    • Financial (call) options provide their holders with the right, but not the obligation, to buy a certain amount of an underlying financial instrument, such as a stock, bond, commodity (such as corn, soybeans, wheat, or gold) futures contract, foreign currency, or index at a certain price on or before a certain date. The awarding of the 1997 Nobel Prize in economics to two financial economists, Robert Merton and Myron Scholes, for their pathbreaking theoretical research about options is only the latest indication that options are an increasingly relevant economic tool. See, e.g., Michael M. Phillips, Two U.S. Economists Win Nobel Prize: Merton and Scholes Share Award for Breakthrough in Pricing Stock Options, Wall St. J., Oct. 15, 1997, at A2.
    • (1997) Wall St. J.
    • Phillips, M.M.1
  • 18
    • 4244009440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Message from Stockholm: Markets Work
    • Oct. 15
    • Not only are stock options now a $148 billion industry, but also, "[i]f you have a mortgage, for example, you are an options trader: You have the option to pay off that mortgage at any time." David R. Henderson, Message from Stockholm: Markets Work, Wall St. J., Oct. 15, 1997, at A22.
    • (1997) Wall St. J.
    • Henderson, D.R.1
  • 19
    • 0004179740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th ed.
    • For more about financial options, see generally Richard A. Brealey & Stewart C. Myers, Principles of Corporate Finance 557-88 (5th ed. 1996) (providing overview of financial options for corporate managers);
    • (1996) Principles of Corporate Finance , pp. 557-588
    • Brealey, R.A.1    Myers, S.C.2
  • 24
    • 0348162835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation
    • Roberta Romano, A Thumbnail Sketch of Derivative Securities and Their Regulation, 55 Md. L. Rev. 1, 40-46 (1996) (providing definition of options).
    • (1996) Md. L. Rev. , vol.55 , pp. 1
    • Romano, R.1
  • 25
    • 72649100991 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • How a Big Hedge Fund Marketed Its Expertise and Shrouded Its Risks
    • Sept. 25
    • Of course, the imminent collapse and recent bailout of Long-Term Capital Management (with Merton and Scholes as principals) suggests that "the elite of America's financial powerhouses - as well as a few dozen other global heavyweights, either didn't know about or were comfortable with the risks they were taking in their dealings in Long-Term Capital." How a Big Hedge Fund Marketed Its Expertise and Shrouded Its Risks, Wall St. J., Sept. 25, 1998, at A1.
    • (1998) Wall St. J.
  • 26
    • 0003958824 scopus 로고
    • Brealey & Myers, supra, at 589-616 (providing an overview of real options for corporate managers);
    • "Real options" refer to those that options managers have in capital investment projects, such as the option to abandon, to make follow-on investments, to wait (and learn) before investing, or to vary a firm's output or its production methods. See generally Brealey & Myers, supra, at 589-616 (providing an overview of real options for corporate managers); Avinash K. Dixit & Robert S. Pindyck, Investment Under Uncertainty 6-25 (1994) (describing options approach to investment);
    • (1994) Investment under Uncertainty , pp. 6-25
    • Dixit, A.K.1    Pindyck, R.S.2
  • 27
    • 0003553294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lenos Trigeorgis, Real Options 1-4, 9-20, 121-50 (1996) (providing an overview of conceptual framework for real options in capital budgeting). Commonplace options include leasing (or renting) with an option to buy a car, a home, furniture, or appliances; the option to refinance a home loan at a lower interest rate by prepaying a mortgage; the option to switch consumer credit card purchases to a new card with special introductory low interest rates on balance transfers; and "pawn shop" or no-recourse margin loans in which borrowers have the option to walk away from their loans without repaying them, but in so doing forfeit the items pawned or their margin amounts (and whatever items were purchased on margin). An example of an option which may be familiar to budding lawyers is the option to accept an offer for permanent employment as an associate in a law firm after working at that firm as a summer associate.
    • (1996) Real Options , pp. 1-4
    • Trigeorgis, L.1
  • 28
    • 84865912446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hensley v. Eckerhart, 461 U.S. 424, 433 (1983) ("The most useful starting point for determining the amount of a reasonable fee is the number of hours reasonably expended on the litigation multiplied by a reasonable hourly rate.")
    • See, e.g., Hensley v. Eckerhart, 461 U.S. 424, 433 (1983) ("The most useful starting point for determining the amount of a reasonable fee is the number of hours reasonably expended on the litigation multiplied by a reasonable hourly rate.").
  • 29
    • 25844486101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Lindy Bros. Builders of Philadelphia v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corp., 487 F.2d 161, 167-68 (3d Cir. 1976) (setting forth guidance for applying risk multipliers to lodestar); Detroit v. Grinnell Corp., 495 F.2d 448, 471 (2d Cir. 1974) (establishing standards for calculating risk multipliers); Johnson v. Georgia Highway Express, Inc., 488 F.2d 714, 717-19 (5th Cir. 1974) (providing list of twelve factors to guide courts' discretion to enhance lodestar figure)
    • See, e.g., Lindy Bros. Builders of Philadelphia v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corp., 487 F.2d 161, 167-68 (3d Cir. 1976) (setting forth guidance for applying risk multipliers to lodestar); Detroit v. Grinnell Corp., 495 F.2d 448, 471 (2d Cir. 1974) (establishing standards for calculating risk multipliers); Johnson v. Georgia Highway Express, Inc., 488 F.2d 714, 717-19 (5th Cir. 1974) (providing list of twelve factors to guide courts' discretion to enhance lodestar figure).
  • 30
    • 25844516618 scopus 로고
    • The Contingency Factor in Attorney Fee Awards
    • For the early history of risk multipliers, see John Leubsdorf, The Contingency Factor in Attorney Fee Awards, 90 Yale L.J. 473, 475-78 (1981).
    • (1981) Yale L.J. , vol.90 , pp. 473
    • Leubsdorf, J.1
  • 31
    • 25844483831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 461 U.S. 424 (1983)
    • 461 U.S. 424 (1983).
  • 32
    • 25844530221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 433
    • See id. at 433.
  • 33
    • 25844493711 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 449 (Brennan, J., concurring)
    • Id. at 449 (Brennan, J., concurring).
  • 34
    • 25844524781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 465 U.S. 886 (1984)
    • 465 U.S. 886 (1984).
  • 35
    • 25844440922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 897, 901
    • See id. at 897, 901.
  • 36
    • 25844485557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 898
    • See id. at 898.
  • 37
    • 25844489149 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 899-900
    • See id. at 899-900.
  • 38
    • 25844467883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 900
    • See id. at 900.
  • 39
    • 25844500944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 901
    • See id. at 901.
  • 40
    • 84865914322 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. 87, 94 (1989) (adopting "the lodestar approach as the centerpiece of attorney's fee awards," without any multiplier); see also King v. Palmer, 950 F.2d 771, 776 (D.C. Cir. 1991) (en banc) (noting that Supreme Court has been "steadily subsuming most other factors" into lodestar figure)
    • See, e.g., Blanchard v. Bergeron, 489 U.S. 87, 94 (1989) (adopting "the lodestar approach as the centerpiece of attorney's fee awards," without any multiplier); see also King v. Palmer, 950 F.2d 771, 776 (D.C. Cir. 1991) (en banc) (noting that Supreme Court has been "steadily subsuming most other factors" into lodestar figure).
  • 41
    • 25844514840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 478 U.S. 546 (1986)
    • 478 U.S. 546 (1986).
  • 42
    • 25844433924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 547
    • See id. at 547.
  • 43
    • 25844511759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 564
    • Id. at 564.
  • 44
    • 25844461419 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Despite hearing a reargument specifically about risk multipliers in Pennsylvania v. Delaware Valley Citizens' Council for Clean Air, 483 U.S. 711 (1987), the Court was not able to reach consensus. Due to the lack of a majority opinion, the most important legacy of Delaware Valley was Justice O'Connor's concurring opinion, which agreed with the dissent that Congress intended to allow for risk multipliers in computing the reasonable attorney fees authorized by fee-shifting statutes. See id. at 731 (O'Connor, J., concurring); see also id. at 735-42 (Blackmun, J., dissenting). Justice O'Connor's concurring opinion formulated a market approach to risk multipliers, which simply meant that courts should compute risk multipliers that are not case specific, but instead are determined for a class of cases reflecting the particular market for that case. See id. at 733 (O'Connor, J., concurring); see also id. at 745-47 (Blackmun, J., dissenting).
  • 45
    • 25844437968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 505 U.S. 557 (1992)
    • 505 U.S. 557 (1992).
  • 46
    • 25844483326 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 565. Such fee-shifting cases differ from common fund cases in which the plaintiff's attorney's fee comes from the plaintiff's recovery
    • See id. at 565. Such fee-shifting cases differ from common fund cases in which the plaintiff's attorney's fee comes from the plaintiff's recovery.
  • 47
    • 25844473488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 562-63
    • See id. at 562-63.
  • 48
    • 25844442879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 563. This particular fear has not been borne out by an empirical survey of civil rights practitioners in the 1990s. See Davies, supra note 4, at 250-51
    • Id. at 563. This particular fear has not been borne out by an empirical survey of civil rights practitioners in the 1990s. See Davies, supra note 4, at 250-51.
  • 49
    • 25844513208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dague, 505 U.S. at 565
    • See Dague, 505 U.S. at 565.
  • 50
    • 25844479869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 566
    • Id. at 566.
  • 51
    • 84865914320 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Hensley v. Eckhart, 461 U.S. 424, 435 (1983). Note, however, that the Court has never specified what would make a case "exceptional."
    • See Hensley v. Eckhart, 461 U.S. 424, 435 (1983). Note, however, that the Court has never specified what would make a case "exceptional."
  • 52
    • 25844448726 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 804 F. Supp. 69 (C.D. Cal. 1992)
    • 804 F. Supp. 69 (C.D. Cal. 1992).
  • 53
    • 25844494269 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 78-79
    • See id. at 78-79.
  • 54
    • 25844484780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 71
    • See id. at 71.
  • 55
    • 25844518696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In its most recent consideration of attorney's fees pursuant to the Civil Rights Attorney's Fees Awards Act of 1976, the same California district court noted that: In its lodestar calculation, the Court starts from the premise that in determining a reasonable hourly rate the proper focus is not upon what an appropriate or customary hourly rate should be for the particular lawyer who has done the work, but rather upon the nature of the services rendered, and what a reasonable commercial client would pay by the hour for those services if the client were free to choose its own counsel. Gillen v. Gates, 847 F. Supp. 1475, 1480 (C.D. Cal. 1994). It is unclear whether the Dague reasoning extends beyond statutory fee-shifting cases to common fund cases. A recent case suggesting this might be the case is Berg v. Gackenbach (In re Bolar), 800 F. Supp. 1091, 1095 (E.D.N.Y. 1992) (holding that limitations on multipliers in statutory fee-shifting cases extend fully to cases in equity).
  • 56
    • 25844432980 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Crawford & Sen, supra note 12, at 7-10 (describing oldest references to derivatives)
    • See Crawford & Sen, supra note 12, at 7-10 (describing oldest references to derivatives).
  • 57
    • 25844451678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • King James
    • This may have been an early instance of the type of monopolization that is illegal under § 2 of the Sherman Act. See 15 U.S.C. § 2 (1994) (prohibiting any "person who shall monopolize . . . combine or conspire . . . to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations"). Another historical example of an options contract is from the book of Genesis, in which Jacob acquired the option to marry Rachel by working for seven years in her father Laban's fields. See Genesis 29: 18-21 (King James);
    • Genesis 29: 18-21
  • 58
    • 0004159816 scopus 로고
    • 3d ed.
    • see also William F. Sharpe, Investments 470 (3d ed. 1985) (describing biblical options). Unfortunately, Laban insisted that Jacob marry Leah because she was older than Rachel. Jacob did marry Leah. However, he also acquired a second option to marry Rachel by working for another seven years in Laban's fields. This was perhaps the first instance of a fraudulent option and certainly not the last example of how an option investment may involve unforeseen risks.
    • (1985) Investments , pp. 470
    • Sharpe, W.F.1
  • 59
    • 25844513665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dixit & Pindyck, supra note 12, at 24-25 (noting costs and risk aspects of marriage, suicide, and legal reform)
    • See Dixit & Pindyck, supra note 12, at 24-25 (noting costs and risk aspects of marriage, suicide, and legal reform).
  • 60
    • 25844452066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 24
    • Id. at 24.
  • 61
    • 25844480903 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 24-25
    • Id. at 24-25.
  • 62
    • 25844440078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 25
    • Id. at 25.
  • 63
    • 0009035080 scopus 로고
    • The Incentive to Sue: An Option-Pricing Approach
    • See Bradford Cornell, The Incentive to Sue: An Option-Pricing Approach, 19 J. Legal Stud. 173, 174 (1990) (introducing options approach to analyzing litigation investments).
    • (1990) J. Legal Stud. , vol.19 , pp. 173
    • Cornell, B.1
  • 64
    • 0041463342 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legal Entitlements as Auctions: Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Beyond
    • For other applications of options theories to legal rules and institutions, see also Ian Ayres & J.M. Balkin, Legal Entitlements as Auctions: Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Beyond, 106 Yale L.J. 703, 704 (1996) (citing recent articles deconstructing difference between liability rules and property rules in terms of different prices of options);
    • (1996) Yale L.J. , vol.106 , pp. 703
    • Ayres, I.1    Balkin, J.M.2
  • 65
    • 84928507360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Approach to Corporate Reorganizations
    • Lucian Arye Bebchuk, A New Approach to Corporate Reorganizations, 101 Harv. L. Rev. 775 (same);
    • Harv. L. Rev. , vol.101 , pp. 775
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1
  • 66
    • 0011535420 scopus 로고
    • Sequential Versus Unitary Trials: An Economic Analysis
    • William M. Landes, Sequential Versus Unitary Trials: An Economic Analysis, 22 J. Legal Stud. 99, 100 (1993) (arguing that sequential trials may decrease expected cost of litigation);
    • (1993) J. Legal Stud. , vol.22 , pp. 99
    • Landes, W.M.1
  • 67
    • 0042579165 scopus 로고
    • Contract Remedies and Options Pricing
    • Paul G. Mahoney, Contract Remedies and Options Pricing, 24 J. Legal Stud. 139, 143-44 (1995) (considering money damages for contract breach as an option);
    • (1995) J. Legal Stud. , vol.24 , pp. 139
    • Mahoney, P.G.1
  • 70
    • 25844457011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Options Approach to Corporate Reorganization
    • March unpublished manuscript
    • Lucian Arye Bebchuk, The Options Approach to Corporate Reorganization (March 1998) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the New York University Law Review) (applying options approach to the division of value in corporate reorganization);
    • (1998) New York University Law Review
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1
  • 71
    • 25844504241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Taxes and Renewable Resources: The Impact on Exploration and Development
    • July unpublished manuscript
    • Jeff Strnad, Taxes and Renewable Resources: The Impact on Exploration and Development 5-10 (July 1996) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the New York University Law Review) (discussing impact of taxes on the options to drill for oil, to develop oil wells, and to begin oil production).
    • (1996) New York University Law Review , pp. 5-10
    • Strnad, J.1
  • 73
    • 0000468877 scopus 로고
    • The Economics of Legal Conflicts
    • Cornell, supra note 47, at 173.
    • Further, Professor Cornell's analysis extended an earlier literature in which litigation decisions were based solely on the present discounted value of costs and (expected) benefits. See Cornell, supra note 47, at 173. See generally John P. Gould, The Economics of Legal Conflicts, 2 J. Legal Stud. 279 (1973) (applying expected value approach to civil litigation);
    • (1973) J. Legal Stud. , vol.2 , pp. 279
    • Gould, J.P.1
  • 74
    • 0001858937 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of the Courts
    • William M. Landes, An Economic Analysis of the Courts, 14 J.L. & Econ. 61 (1971) (applying expected value approach to criminal litigation);
    • (1971) J.L. & Econ. , vol.14 , pp. 61
    • Landes, W.M.1
  • 75
    • 85050169518 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration
    • Richard A. Posner, An Economic Approach to Legal Procedure and Judicial Administration, 2 J. Legal Stud. 399 (1973) (applying expected value approach to civil and criminal litigation);
    • (1973) J. Legal Stud. , vol.2 , pp. 399
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 76
    • 0002844329 scopus 로고
    • Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs
    • Steven Shavell, Suit, Settlement, and Trial: A Theoretical Analysis Under Alternative Methods for the Allocation of Legal Costs, 11 J. Legal Stud. 55 (1982) (applying expected value approach to litigation under four legal systems).
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud. , vol.11 , pp. 55
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 77
    • 0345880360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A New Theory Concerning the Credibility and Success of Threats to Sue
    • There have been several recent extensions of this literature. See Lucian Arye Bebchuk, A New Theory Concerning the Credibility and Success of Threats to Sue, 25 J. Legal Stud. 1 (1996) (developing model of credibility and success of threats to bring negative expected value suits);
    • (1996) J. Legal Stud. , vol.25 , pp. 1
    • Bebchuk, L.A.1
  • 78
  • 80
    • 21344481162 scopus 로고
    • Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation
    • See James D. Dana, Jr. & Kathryn E. Spier, Expertise and Contingent Fees: The Role of Asymmetric Information in Attorney Compensation, 9 J.L. Econ. & Org. 349, 350 (1993) (discussing conflicts between incentives for clients and incentives for attorneys under contingency fee arrangements).
    • (1993) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.9 , pp. 349
    • Dana Jr., J.D.1    Spier, K.E.2
  • 81
    • 84928461719 scopus 로고
    • The Regulation of Entrepreneurial Litigation: Balancing Fairness and Efficiency in the Large Class Action
    • See, e.g., John C. Coffee, Jr., The Regulation of Entrepreneurial Litigation: Balancing Fairness and Efficiency in the Large Class Action, 54 U. Chi. L. Rev. 877, 883 (1987) (discussing agency cost problem in large class actions);
    • (1987) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.54 , pp. 877
    • Coffee Jr., J.C.1
  • 82
    • 84882010086 scopus 로고
    • The Plaintiff Attorney's Role in Class Action and Derivative Litigation: Economic Analysis and Recommendations for Reform
    • Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, The Plaintiff Attorney's Role in Class Action and Derivative Litigation: Economic Analysis and Recommendations for Reform, 58 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1, 41 (1991) (discussing incentive conflicts between representative plaintiffs and plaintiffs' attorneys in class actions).
    • (1991) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.58 , pp. 1
    • Macey, J.R.1    Miller, G.P.2
  • 83
    • 84927458379 scopus 로고
    • Winnowing Derivative Suits Through Attorney Fees
    • See A. F. Conard, Winnowing Derivative Suits Through Attorney Fees, 47 Law & Contemp. Probs. 269, 281-85 (1984) (discussing incentive conflicts in derivative suits).
    • (1984) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.47 , pp. 269
    • Conard, A.F.1
  • 84
    • 25844511357 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An alternative way to calculate her expected wealth is to realize that there is a probability of p that she will receive net earnings of $100,000, and there is a complementary probability of (1-p) that she will not get paid, meaning that she will receive net earnings of (-$100,000). Thus, her expected total wealth from undertaking this lawsuit is just the probability-weighted sum of her possible earnings, which is $100,000p + (1-p)(-$100,000). This expression simplifies to $200,000p-$100,000.
  • 85
    • 0346613498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Fundamental Divergence between the Private and Social Motive to Use the Legal System
    • It might seem that a socially desirable policy would look to streamline the legal system by discouraging lawsuits in which the plaintiff initially has a low probability of winning at trial. However, a low initial probability of the plaintiff winning at trial does not necessarily mean that the case is meritless. The plaintiff may uncover favorable information through discovery, for example. Additionally, the socially optimal amount of public interest litigation should take into account the effects of possible lawsuits on the incentives of potential defendants to engage in activities that generate harm or injury. For a model of these and other considerations in private litigation, see generally Steven Shavell, The Fundamental Divergence Between the Private and Social Motive to Use the Legal System, 26 J. Legal. Stud. 575 (1997).
    • (1997) J. Legal. Stud. , vol.26 , pp. 575
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 86
    • 25844519786 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fed. R. Civ. P. 55(d)
    • See Fed. R. Civ. P. 55(d).
  • 87
    • 84865914321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 1.180(j) (1997) (stating that plaintiff's attorney "shall not acquire proprietary interest in the cause of action except for a reasonable contingent fee contract")
    • See Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 1.180(j) (1997) (stating that plaintiff's attorney "shall not acquire proprietary interest in the cause of action except for a reasonable contingent fee contract").
  • 88
    • 84927454616 scopus 로고
    • The Second Set of Players: Lawyers, Fee Shifting, and the Limits of Professional Discipline
    • See Charles W. Wolfram, The Second Set of Players: Lawyers, Fee Shifting, and the Limits of Professional Discipline, 47 Law & Contemp. Probs. 293, 296-97 (1984) ("Scholars who study the legal profession have been reporting for some time that lawyers regularly depart from the professional model of client control and make critical decisions on their own in . . . civil representations.").
    • (1984) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.47 , pp. 293
    • Wolfram, C.W.1
  • 89
    • 25844495826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 295-96. The balance between attorney and plaintiff ownership of lawsuits is further complicated by the method of payment: Concern for reputation aside, if the attorney were paid either a fixed fee or an hourly fee, then she would have little financial incentive to reveal to her client that the case had a low expected return. Instead, she might lead the plaintiff blindly into litigation regardless of the case's merit. When the attorney is paid a contingent fee, however, then she will act in her clients' interest and pursue only those cases with a sufficiently high expected return. Dana & Spier, supra note 49, at 350
    • Id. at 295-96. The balance between attorney and plaintiff ownership of lawsuits is further complicated by the method of payment: Concern for reputation aside, if the attorney were paid either a fixed fee or an hourly fee, then she would have little financial incentive to reveal to her client that the case had a low expected return. Instead, she might lead the plaintiff blindly into litigation regardless of the case's merit. When the attorney is paid a contingent fee, however, then she will act in her clients' interest and pursue only those cases with a sufficiently high expected return. Dana & Spier, supra note 49, at 350.
  • 90
    • 0000522354 scopus 로고
    • Some Agency Problems in Settlement
    • Wolfram, supra note 56, at 297. In addition, plaintiffs' attorneys have the option to withdraw from representing the plaintiff, although the exercise of this option requires court approval. See Model Code of Professional Responsibility DR 2-110 (1980); Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 1.16 (1997). Withdrawal is "something that is granted in the great majority of cases but that occasionally may be denied, especially if opposed by the client, or else granted with an unwelcome public tongue-lashing. Moreover, the attorney may want to avoid getting a reputation as someone who abandons clients in midcase." Geoffrey P. Miller, Some Agency Problems in Settlement, 16 J. Legal Stud. 189, 212 (1987).
    • (1987) J. Legal Stud. , vol.16 , pp. 189
    • Miller, G.P.1
  • 91
    • 0023297565 scopus 로고
    • The Effect of Message Framing on Breast Self-Examination: Attitudes, Intentions, and Behavior
    • There are well-known "framing effects" that cognitive psychologists have discovered in human decisionmaking. See, e.g., Beth E. Meyerowitz & Shelly Chaiken, The Effect of Message Framing on Breast Self-Examination: Attitudes, Intentions, and Behavior, 52 J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. 500, 505-07 (1987) (finding in study of breast self-examinations that pamphlets describing positive effects of self-examinations are ineffective, while pamphlets stressing negative effects of failing to undertake self-examinations lead to behavioral change).
    • (1987) J. Personality & Soc. Psychol. , vol.52 , pp. 500
    • Meyerowitz, B.E.1    Chaiken, S.2
  • 92
    • 0346249973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Context-Dependence in Legal Decision Making
    • For two recent applications of framing effects to the law, see generally Mark Kelman et al., Context-Dependence in Legal Decision Making, 25 J. Legal Stud. 287 (1996) (presenting experimental evidence of context dependence in legal judgments);
    • (1996) J. Legal Stud. , vol.25 , pp. 287
    • Kelman, M.1
  • 93
    • 21844506476 scopus 로고
    • Framing the Jury: Cognitive Perspectives on Pain and Suffering Awards
    • Edward J. McCaffery et al., Framing the Jury: Cognitive Perspectives on Pain and Suffering Awards, 81 Va. L. Rev. 1341 (1995) (finding gain versus loss framing has large impact on size of nonpecuniary damage awards).
    • (1995) Va. L. Rev. , vol.81 , pp. 1341
    • McCaffery, E.J.1
  • 94
    • 0347837852 scopus 로고
    • The Courts and the Market: An Economic Analysis of Contingent Fees in Class-Action Litigation
    • See, e.g., Lynk, supra note 10, at 187 (contrasting percentage-of-recovery agreements often made between plaintiffs and attorneys with lodestar formula ordinarily used by courts in awarding attorney's fees); William J. Lynk, The Courts and the Market: An Economic Analysis of Contingent Fees in Class-Action Litigation, 19 J. Legal Stud. 247, 256-59 (1990) (summarizing calculation of federal class action fee awards).
    • (1990) J. Legal Stud. , vol.19 , pp. 247
    • Lynk, W.J.1
  • 95
    • 25844462457 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B (analyzing litigation as series of discrete stages)
    • See supra Part II.B (analyzing litigation as series of discrete stages).
  • 96
    • 0001113367 scopus 로고
    • Some Effects of Uncertainty on Compliance with Legal Standards
    • See supra note 10 and accompanying text. A similar damage multiplier that offsets the probability of nonenforcement has a long history. For various reasons why the damage multiplier should not be simply the reciprocal of the probability of enforcement, see John E. Calfee & Richard Craswell, Some Effects of Uncertainty on Compliance with Legal Standards, 70 Va. L. Rev. 965, 994-97 (1984) (arguing that strict relationship oversimplifies calculation);
    • (1984) Va. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 965
    • Calfee, J.E.1    Craswell, R.2
  • 97
    • 0346089950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Damage Multipliers in Market Relationships
    • Richard Craswell, Damage Multipliers in Market Relationships, 25 J. Legal Stud. 463, 465-66, 468, 473 (1996) (arguing that other factors, such as risk aversion of defendant, need to be considered);
    • (1996) J. Legal Stud. , vol.25 , pp. 463
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 98
    • 0000525496 scopus 로고
    • Deterrence and Uncertain Legal Standards
    • Richard Craswell & John E. Calfee, Deterrence and Uncertain Legal Standards, 2 J.L. Econ. & Org. 279, 292-97 (1986) (showing that multiplier may be inappropriate even when enforcement costs are fixed or absent);
    • (1986) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.2 , pp. 279
    • Craswell, R.1    Calfee, J.E.2
  • 99
    • 25844510294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • When is a Willful Breach 'Willful'? General vs. Specific Deterrence in Contract Remedies
    • May 11, unpublished manuscript
    • Richard Craswell, When is a Willful Breach 'Willful'? General vs. Specific Deterrence in Contract Remedies 53-55 (May 11, 1996) (unpublished manuscript on file with New York University Law Review).
    • (1996) New York University Law Review , pp. 53-55
    • Craswell, R.1
  • 100
    • 25844469346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B
    • See supra Part II.B.
  • 101
    • 25844490501 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part II.B
    • See supra Part II.B.
  • 102
    • 25844502563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Settlement
    • B. Bouckaert & G. DeGeest eds., forthcoming
    • For further analysis of economic approaches to settlement, see Andrew F. Daughety, Settlement, in Encyclopedia of Law and Economics (B. Bouckaert & G. DeGeest eds., forthcoming 1998) (surveying asymmetric information game-theoretic models of pretrial settlement);
    • (1998) Encyclopedia of Law and Economics
    • Daughety, A.F.1
  • 103
    • 25844519784 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Settlement of Litigation: A Critical Retrospective
    • Larry Kramer ed.
    • Geoffrey P. Miller, Settlement of Litigation: A Critical Retrospective, in Reforming the Civil Justice System 13, 14-19 (Larry Kramer ed., 1996) (reviewing law and economics literature on settlement and litigation in general).
    • (1996) Reforming the Civil Justice System , pp. 13
    • Miller, G.P.1
  • 104
    • 84935413548 scopus 로고
    • Mediation with a Mugger: The Shortage of Adjudicative Services and the Need for a Two-Tier Trial System in Civil Cases
    • Two main arguments have been made against settlement. The first is based on concerns that justice requires the process of a public trial. See Albert W. Alschuler, Mediation with a Mugger: The Shortage of Adjudicative Services and the Need for a Two-Tier Trial System in Civil Cases, 99 Harv. L. Rev. 1808, 1820 (1986) (arguing that "Americans currently settle many of their disputes for the wrong reasons");
    • (1986) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.99 , pp. 1808
    • Alschuler, A.W.1
  • 105
    • 84971947666 scopus 로고
    • Justice in Settlements
    • Jules Coleman & Charles Silver, Justice in Settlements, Soc. Phil. & Pol'y 102, 106-08 (1986) (arguing that settlements are undesirable because they may strain justice in our society);
    • (1986) Soc. Phil. & Pol'y , pp. 102
    • Coleman, J.1    Silver, C.2
  • 106
    • 34548637846 scopus 로고
    • Against Settlement
    • Owen M. Fiss, Against Settlement, 93 Yale L.J. 1073, 1075 (1984) (arguing that settlement is "a highly problematic technique for streamlining dockets").
    • (1984) Yale L.J. , vol.93 , pp. 1073
    • Fiss, O.M.1
  • 107
    • 0011665871 scopus 로고
    • The second set of arguments is based on economic concerns over judicial precedents being public goods, see Richard A. Posner, The Federal Courts: Crisis and Reform 10 (1985) (arguing that judicial precedents have significant external benefits as public goods),
    • (1985) The Federal Courts: Crisis and Reform , pp. 10
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 108
    • 0000369885 scopus 로고
    • The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis
    • and efficiency concerns about the under-enforcement of laws, see Louis Kaplow, The Value of Accuracy in Adjudication: An Economic Analysis, 23 J. Legal Stud. 307, 323 (1994) (arguing that socially optimal system of regulation must internalize process of enforcement itself);
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 307
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 109
    • 0001268086 scopus 로고
    • The Deterrent Effects of Settlements and Trials
    • A. Mitchell Polinsky & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Deterrent Effects of Settlements and Trials, 8 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 109, 110 (1988) (suggesting disparate effects of trials and settlements on deterrence).
    • (1988) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.8 , pp. 109
    • Mitchell Polinsky, A.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 110
    • 37149031564 scopus 로고
    • Law's Republic
    • For a discussion of both the justice based and economic critiques of settlement, see generally Miller, supra note 65, at 21-25. In addition, there are process concerns about settlement. See Frank Michelman, Law's Republic, 97 Yale L.J. 1493 (1988) (arguing that settlement prevents civic engagement and formation of community relationships);
    • (1988) Yale L.J. , vol.97 , pp. 1493
    • Michelman, F.1
  • 111
    • 21344438090 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Individuals within the Aggregate: Relationships, Representation, and Fees
    • Judith Resnik et al., Individuals within the Aggregate: Relationships, Representation, and Fees, 71 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 296, 320 (1996) (expressing concerns about preventing victims and accused from publicly telling their respective stories);
    • (1996) N.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 296
    • Resnik, J.1
  • 112
    • 0042144228 scopus 로고
    • Liability-Based Fee-Shifting Rules and Settlement Mechanisms under Incomplete Information
    • Eric Talley, Liability-Based Fee-Shifting Rules and Settlement Mechanisms Under Incomplete Information, 71 Chi.-Kent L. Rev. 461, 498 (1995) (arguing that "process" concerns make normative value of settlement questionable). All of these concerns apply to civil rights litigation, and indeed may be more important for civil rights than for private litigation.
    • (1995) Chi.-Kent L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 461
    • Talley, E.1
  • 113
    • 84865913808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 42 U.S.C. § 1988 (1994)
    • See, e.g., 42 U.S.C. § 1988 (1994).
  • 114
    • 25844530966 scopus 로고
    • Voluntary Fee Waivers during Simultaneous Negotiation of Merits and Attorney's Fees in Title VII Class Actions: Moore v. National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc
    • Comment
    • See Evans v. Jeff D., 475 U.S. 717, 742-43 (1986) (holding that "District Court did not abuse its discretion in upholding a fee waiver"); Moore v. National Ass'n of Sec. Dealers, 762 F.2d 1093, 1110 (D.C. Cir. 1985) (emphasizing voluntariness as prerequisite to fee waivers); Cynthia M. Culton, Comment, Voluntary Fee Waivers During Simultaneous Negotiation of Merits and Attorney's Fees in Title VII Class Actions: Moore v. National Association of Securities Dealers, Inc., 7 U. Bridgeport L. Rev. 361, 370 (1986) (discussing policies of and problems created by fee waiver opinion in Moore).
    • (1986) U. Bridgeport L. Rev. , vol.7 , pp. 361
    • Culton, C.M.1
  • 115
    • 25844451227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 473 U.S. 1 (1985)
    • 473 U.S. 1 (1985).
  • 116
    • 25844499225 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fed. R. Civ. P. 68
    • Fed. R. Civ. P. 68.
  • 117
    • 25844513207 scopus 로고
    • The Supreme Court's Denial of Reasonable Attorney's Fees to Prevailing Civil Rights Plaintiffs
    • Marek, 473 U.S. at 10-11
    • See Marek, 473 U.S. at 10-11; Jean R. Sternlight, The Supreme Court's Denial of Reasonable Attorney's Fees to Prevailing Civil Rights Plaintiffs, 17 N.Y.U. Rev. L. & Soc. Change 535, 566-68 (1989-1990) (discussing Marek);
    • (1989) N.Y.U. Rev. L. & Soc. Change , vol.17 , pp. 535
    • Sternlight, J.R.1
  • 118
    • 0242289208 scopus 로고
    • Improving Settlement Devices: Rule 68 and Beyond
    • see also David A. Anderson, Improving Settlement Devices: Rule 68 and Beyond, 23 J. Legal Stud. 225, 229 (1994) (analyzing bargaining game under Rule 68);
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 225
    • Anderson, D.A.1
  • 119
    • 0347936340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Settlement of Litigation under Rule 68: An Economic Analysis
    • Tai-Yeong Chung, Settlement of Litigation Under Rule 68: An Economic Analysis, 25 J. Legal Stud. 261, 265, 279-80 (1996) (analyzing incentives under Rule 68);
    • (1996) J. Legal Stud. , vol.25 , pp. 261
    • Chung, T.-Y.1
  • 120
    • 0009943154 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Rule 68
    • Geoffrey P. Miller, An Economic Analysis of Rule 68, 15 J. Legal Stud. 93, 121-23 (1986) (discussing distributional and settlement effects of combining Rule 68 with fee-shifting statutes);
    • (1986) J. Legal Stud. , vol.15 , pp. 93
    • Miller, G.P.1
  • 121
    • 21344490328 scopus 로고
    • Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee-Shifting Rules
    • Kathryn E. Spier, Pretrial Bargaining and the Design of Fee-Shifting Rules, 25 Rand J. Econ. 197, 200-02 (1994) (same).
    • (1994) Rand J. Econ. , vol.25 , pp. 197
    • Spier, K.E.1
  • 122
    • 62449114206 scopus 로고
    • Understanding the Plaintiff's Attorney: The Implications of Economic Theory for Private Enforcement of Law Through Class and Derivative Actions
    • The effects of fee-shifting and settlement rules on the attorney-client relationship are well documented. See, e.g., John C. Coffee, Jr., Understanding the Plaintiff's Attorney: The Implications of Economic Theory for Private Enforcement of Law Through Class and Derivative Actions, 86 Colum. L. Rev. 669, 691, 717-19 (1986) (explaining how lodestar formula precipitates collusion between defendants and plaintiffs' attorneys because it decouples settlement figure and fee award); Grundfest & Huang, supra note 48, at 15, 17 (noting that settlement option can be decoupled into two separate options, an option based on merits and another based on litigation costs). Attorney's fee awards based on the lodestar figure mean that plaintiffs' attorneys share their clients' downside risk, but not their potential for upside gain of recovery from trial. See Coffee, supra, at 717-18. This option creates an incentive for plaintiffs' attorneys to accept settlements that plaintiffs would not accept themselves. For an analysis of the effects on settlement of alternative fee arrangements and allocations of settlement power between plaintiffs and plaintiffs' attorneys, see Miller, supra note 58, at 204-15.
    • (1986) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.86 , pp. 669
    • Coffee Jr., J.C.1
  • 123
    • 25844519785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 56-59 and accompanying text (discussing decision whether to go to trial in situations where plaintiffs' attorneys control that decision de facto).
  • 124
    • 25844448105 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an analysis of the situation in which the plaintiff is actually in control of the decision to settle, see Grundfest & Huang, supra note 48, at 17 (developing general real options model of litigation). Note that, in most cases, neither the plaintiff nor the plaintiff's attorney completely controls the settlement decision.
  • 125
    • 25844446008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 1.2(a) (1997)
    • Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 1.2(a) (1997).
  • 126
    • 25844523886 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wolfram, supra note 56, at 297
    • Wolfram, supra note 56, at 297.
  • 127
    • 25844516616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Additionally, there is always the possibility of unethical plaintiffs' attorneys who fail to inform plaintiffs of defendants' settlement offers. Such unscrupulous conduct is hard for defendants' attorneys to detect because of the requirement that defendants' attorneys can only communicate with the plaintiff via the plaintiffs' attorneys. See Model Code of Professional Responsibility DR 7-104 (1980); Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 4.2 (1997)
    • Additionally, there is always the possibility of unethical plaintiffs' attorneys who fail to inform plaintiffs of defendants' settlement offers. Such unscrupulous conduct is hard for defendants' attorneys to detect because of the requirement that defendants' attorneys can only communicate with the plaintiff via the plaintiffs' attorneys. See Model Code of Professional Responsibility DR 7-104 (1980); Model Rules of Professional Conduct Rule 4.2 (1997).
  • 128
    • 84865913809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Prandini v. National Tea Co., 557 F.2d 1015, 1021 (3d Cir. 1977) ("Only after court approval of the damage settlement should discussion and negotiation of appropriate compensation for the attorneys begin.")
    • See Prandini v. National Tea Co., 557 F.2d 1015, 1021 (3d Cir. 1977) ("Only after court approval of the damage settlement should discussion and negotiation of appropriate compensation for the attorneys begin.").
  • 129
    • 25844458525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Folsom v. Butte County Ass'n of Gov'ts, 652 P.2d 437, 446 (Cal. 1982) (rejecting bifurcation of fee and settlement discussions)
    • See, e.g., Folsom v. Butte County Ass'n of Gov'ts, 652 P.2d 437, 446 (Cal. 1982) (rejecting bifurcation of fee and settlement discussions).
  • 130
    • 25844450970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b). Generally, modern liberal rules of pleading are designed to allow the survival of a fairly broad class of claims
    • See Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b). Generally, modern liberal rules of pleading are designed to allow the survival of a fairly broad class of claims.
  • 131
    • 25844503858 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (M-1)L > 0 because M > 1 as long as the initial probability the plaintiff would prevail was less than one
    • (M-1)L > 0 because M > 1 as long as the initial probability the plaintiff would prevail was less than one.
  • 132
    • 84865912437 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Under Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(b)(1), the scope of discovery is quite broad and includes information not admissible at trial, so long as the information requested "appears reasonably calculated to lead to the discovery of admissible evidence." Id.
    • Under Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(b)(1), the scope of discovery is quite broad and includes information not admissible at trial, so long as the information requested "appears reasonably calculated to lead to the discovery of admissible evidence." Id.
  • 133
    • 25844451677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(b)(2)(iii) limits discovery to requests whereby compliance does not impose a burden that is likely to outweigh the benefits, while Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(g)(3) allows courts to impose appropriate sanctions for violations
    • Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(b)(2)(iii) limits discovery to requests whereby compliance does not impose a burden that is likely to outweigh the benefits, while Fed. R. Civ. P. 26(g)(3) allows courts to impose appropriate sanctions for violations.
  • 134
    • 0009073625 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Model of Legal Discovery
    • For an in-depth analysis of the discovery game, see generally Robert D. Cooter & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, An Economic Model of Legal Discovery, 23 J. Legal Stud. 435, 438 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 435
    • Cooter, R.D.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 135
    • 0003082964 scopus 로고
    • A Model in Which Suits are Brought for Their Nuisance Value
    • See D. Rosenberg & S. Shavell, A Model in Which Suits are Brought for Their Nuisance Value, 5 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 3, 4-6 (1985) (explaining nuisance suits where defendant incurs substantial costs before plaintiff incurs any costs).
    • (1985) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.5 , pp. 3
    • Rosenberg, D.1    Shavell, S.2
  • 136
    • 84934452640 scopus 로고
    • Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power over Price
    • The cost of complying with discovery requests is an example of how the litigation process can mirror the phenomenon known in the economics literature as raising rivals' costs. See, e.g., Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Achieve Power over Price, 96 Yale L.J. 209, 230-31 (1986).
    • (1986) Yale L.J. , vol.96 , pp. 209
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 138
    • 25844471153 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 263 (suggesting need for Congress and federal courts to narrow their focus when considering reforms)
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 263 (suggesting need for Congress and federal courts to narrow their focus when considering reforms).
  • 139
    • 84865904167 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 261 ("Payment of an hourly rate following five to seven years of difficult litigation, and then only if one prevails, is not the equivalent of an hourly rate paid monthly regardless of the litigation outcome.")
    • See id. at 261 ("Payment of an hourly rate following five to seven years of difficult litigation, and then only if one prevails, is not the equivalent of an hourly rate paid monthly regardless of the litigation outcome.").
  • 140
    • 25844505166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 738 F.2d 188 (7th Cir. 1984)
    • 738 F.2d 188 (7th Cir. 1984).
  • 141
    • 25844488197 scopus 로고
    • Incoherence and Irrationality in the Law of Attorneys' Fees
    • Id. at 195. Professor Silver agrees, stating that "[f]ees equal to those that lawyers ordinarily receive from paying clients further the goal of enabling parties to secure counsel sufficiently well." Charles Silver, Incoherence and Irrationality in the Law of Attorneys' Fees, 12 Rev. Litig. 301, 310 (1993).
    • (1993) Rev. Litig. , vol.12 , pp. 301
    • Silver, C.1
  • 142
    • 0007528485 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Legal Theory of Attorney Fee Shifting: A Critical Overview
    • See generally Thomas D. Rowe, Jr., The Legal Theory of Attorney Fee Shifting: A Critical Overview, 1982 Duke L.J. 651, 652 (analyzing rationales for adopting fee shifting system).
    • Duke L.J. , vol.1982 , pp. 651
    • Rowe Jr., T.D.1
  • 143
    • 25844455613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Affidavit of Steven M. Shavell at 2-3, In re Burlington Northern, Inc., Employment Practices Litigation, Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269, 1985 WL 1808 (N.D. Ill. May 31, 1985)
    • See Affidavit of Steven M. Shavell at 2-3, In re Burlington Northern, Inc., Employment Practices Litigation, Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269, 1985 WL 1808 (N.D. Ill. May 31, 1985).
  • 144
    • 25844470431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 6
    • See id. at 6.
  • 145
    • 25844498918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 146
    • 25844502562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 9-12
    • See id. at 9-12.
  • 147
    • 25844526584 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 11
    • See id. at 11.
  • 148
    • 25844438429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part IV
    • See supra Part IV.
  • 149
    • 25844527701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 16-17, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269)
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 16-17, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269).
  • 150
    • 25844484648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See City of Burlington v. Dague, 505 U.S. 557, 562-63 (1992) (relying heavily on this argument)
    • See City of Burlington v. Dague, 505 U.S. 557, 562-63 (1992) (relying heavily on this argument).
  • 151
    • 25844490053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part III (outlining benefits of encouraging attorneys to take high risk cases)
    • See supra Part III (outlining benefits of encouraging attorneys to take high risk cases).
  • 152
    • 84928450080 scopus 로고
    • Nonpayment Risk Multipliers: Incentives or Windfalls?
    • Comment
    • There may be social benefits which exceed the private returns to individual litigants in civil rights litigation. These public goods include the resolution of statutory ambiguity, increased judicial experience, and the symbolic message that justice will prevail, which might deter other future violations. See Kirchoff v. Flynn 786 F.2d 320, 327 (7th Cir. 1986) ("Much civil rights litigation is designed to obtain injunctions or precedents. These may be exceptionally valuable but have no ready monetary equivalent."); see also James D. Kole, Comment, Nonpayment Risk Multipliers: Incentives or Windfalls?, 53 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1074, 1090 (1986) (arguing that fee arrangements can "give no indication of the appropriate fee in cases with primarily injunctive or precedent-creating motivations, which cannot be reduced to monetary terms" (citing Kirchoff, 786 F.2d at 328)).
    • (1986) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 1074
    • Kole, J.D.1
  • 153
    • 25844515779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Dague, 505 U.S. at 563 (noting this perverse incentive effect); Affidavit of Shavell at 18, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269)
    • See Dague, 505 U.S. at 563 (noting this perverse incentive effect); Affidavit of Shavell at 18, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269).
  • 154
    • 25844460583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One possibility is to compute traditional multipliers where the relevant probabilities are not particular to a given case, but instead are relevant to a general class of cases. This is the market approach to risk multipliers Justice O'Connor proposed in Pennsylvania v. Delaware Valley Citizens' Council for Clean Air, 483 U.S. 711, 731 (1987) (O'Connor, J., concurring); see also Leubsdorf, supra note 15, at 501-10 (arguing for "across-the-board" approach to risk multipliers). However, the question then becomes what the relevant set of cases should be: 1) all cases; 2) that particular attorney's historical portfolio of cases; 3) a broad category of cases (for example, civil rights cases); or 4) a more restricted classification of cases (for example, cases involving employment discrimination). In addition, if the multiplier is not based on the particular case in question, it will lead to overcompensation for all of the inframarginal cases, which involve probabilities of the plaintiff winning that exceed the threshold cutoff level.
  • 155
    • 25844441084 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 17-19, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269)
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 17-19, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269).
  • 156
    • 85050371393 scopus 로고
    • Unloading the Lodestar: Toward a New Fee Award Procedure
    • It is unclear whether the objective is or should be to attract into civil rights litigation lawyers of any quality, lawyers of quality comparable to those involved in other areas of litigation, or only the "cream of the crop." See Charles Silver, Unloading the Lodestar: Toward a New Fee Award Procedure, 70 Tex. L. Rev. 865, 931 (1992) ("The law will continue to be a jumble unless and until the term 'competent counsel' is authoritatively defined.").
    • (1992) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 865
    • Silver, C.1
  • 157
    • 25844507516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Part I (discussing Court's treatment of risk multiplier)
    • See supra Part I (discussing Court's treatment of risk multiplier).
  • 158
    • 84865914319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 228-29 (relating one attorney's belief that Dague will have a "chilling effect on the practice of civil rights law" and will deter " 'cutting edge' cases and, thus, slow development of the law" (discussing City of Burlington v. Dague, 505 U.S. 557 (1992))); Sternlight, supra note 71, at 584 ("[F]rom the perspective of the plaintiffs' civil rights attorneys, the lodestar is both insufficient and unobtainable.")
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 228-29 (relating one attorney's belief that Dague will have a "chilling effect on the practice of civil rights law" and will deter " 'cutting edge' cases and, thus, slow development of the law" (discussing City of Burlington v. Dague, 505 U.S. 557 (1992))); Sternlight, supra note 71, at 584 ("[F]rom the perspective of the plaintiffs' civil rights attorneys, the lodestar is both insufficient and unobtainable.").
  • 159
    • 25844437122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 18-19, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269). This is because, for example, the multiplier for cases with a value of p=1/2 is two, while the multiplier for cases with a value of p=99/100 is only 100/99, which is barely more than one and substantially less than two
    • See Affidavit of Shavell at 18-19, In re Burlington (Nos. MDL 374, 78 C 269). This is because, for example, the multiplier for cases with a value of p=1/2 is two, while the multiplier for cases with a value of p=99/100 is only 100/99, which is barely more than one and substantially less than two.
  • 160
    • 25844518694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Silver, supra note 106, at 874
    • See Silver, supra note 106, at 874.
  • 161
    • 0042408208 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Efficiency vs. Distributional Equity in Legal Rulemaking: Should Distributional Equity Matter Given Optimal Income Taxation?
    • See Steven Shavell, A Note on Efficiency vs. Distributional Equity in Legal Rulemaking: Should Distributional Equity Matter Given Optimal Income Taxation?, 71 Am. Econ. Rev. 414 (1981). The traditional law and economics approach indicates that using taxes to redistribute income is less costly than using legal rules that shift wealth from the rich to the poor. This is because the former only distorts work incentives, while the latter also distorts the incentives to engage in activities which may lead to being sued.
    • (1981) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 414
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 162
    • 84865913806 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 251 ("The plaintiffs' attorneys interviewed repeatedly noted that their economic survival demands high selectivity and careful investigation before undertaking representation of a client.")
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 251 ("The plaintiffs' attorneys interviewed repeatedly noted that their economic survival demands high selectivity and careful investigation before undertaking representation of a client.").
  • 163
    • 0011552017 scopus 로고
    • Emotional Responses in Litigation
    • See id. at 251-52 ("Employment lawyers, for example, volunteered the following motivations: commitment to bringing about positive organizational change, a belief that employment litigation is necessary to make organizations deal with the problems, and commitment to help people without power who are hurt by those with power." (citations omitted)). Davies also noted that "[a] prison conditions attorney said that despite small salaries, the attorneys in her office stay because they are committed to the type of work they do." Id. at 252 (citation omitted). For formal models of the implications of anger for the incentives of litigation participants to sue, settle, or go to trial, see Peter H. Huang & Ho-Mou Wu, Emotional Responses in Litigation, 12 Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. 31, 32 (1992) (demonstrating that plaintiffs may sue more and settle less when emotions are motivating factors).
    • (1992) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.12 , pp. 31
    • Huang, P.H.1    Wu, H.-M.2
  • 164
    • 21844523497 scopus 로고
    • More Order Without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms and Organizational Cultures
    • See Davies, supra note 4, at 251-52. For formal models of effects of shame and guilt on corruption and professional ethics, see generally Peter H. Huang & Ho-Mou Wu, More Order Without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms and Organizational Cultures, 10 J.L. Econ. & Org. 390 (1994).
    • (1994) J.L. Econ. & Org. , vol.10 , pp. 390
    • Huang, P.H.1    Wu, H.-M.2
  • 165
    • 0004229270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Margaret Jane Radin, Contested Commodities 104-05 (1996) (arguing that commodified and noncommodified exchanges pervade our market society and most individuals experience work as partially defining their identities).
    • (1996) Contested Commodities , pp. 104-105
    • Radin, M.J.1
  • 166
    • 25844501572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Observe that the level of plaintiff's recovery does not appear in this analysis and may even be nonmonetary in nature if the plaintiff is, for example, seeking injunctive relief instead of damages.
  • 167
    • 84897724076 scopus 로고
    • The Effects of Fee Shifting on the Settlement Rate: Theoretical Observations on Costs, Conflicts, and Contingency Fees
    • As Professor Donohue pointed out, "attorneys do not have an opinion about the probability of success of a client's case from the minute the client walks in the door. Research, fact-finding, and lengthy discovery are all prerequisites to the formulation of an opinion." John J. Donohue, III, The Effects of Fee Shifting on the Settlement Rate: Theoretical Observations on Costs, Conflicts, and Contingency Fees, 54 Law & Contemp. Probs. 195, 217 (1991).
    • (1991) Law & Contemp. Probs. , vol.54 , pp. 195
    • Donohue III, J.J.1
  • 168
    • 25844484136 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Revised expected net wealth = p[(M-1)L]+(1-p)(-D) = pML-pL-D+pD = pML-p(D+T)-D+pD = pML-pT-D.
  • 169
    • 25844473259 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • REW = p(M-1)T+(pM-1)D = pMT-pT+pMD-D = pM(D+T)-pT-D = pML-pT-D-T+T = pML-pT-L+T = pML-L-pT+T = EW+(1-p)T.
  • 170
    • 25844509418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Using an equivalent expression for REW, this means solving for p when p(M-1)L = (1-p)D, or pD+p(M-1)L = D, or p[D+(M-1)L] = D, or p[D+(M-1)D+(M-1)T] = D, or p[MD+(M-1)T] = D, or p(MD+MT-T) = D, or p(ML-T) = D.
  • 171
    • 25844461915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Notice that p** > 0 because D > 0 and (ML-T) > 0, which is true because ML = MD + MT > MT > T as M > 1 and D > 0. Also, notice that p** < 1 because D < ML-T, or equivalently, D+T < ML = MD+MT = M(D+T) because M > 1. Thus, p** is a bona fide probability that resides in the open interval (0, 1).
  • 172
    • 25844462455 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • M > 1 means that M-1 > 0, and T > 0 means that (M-1)T > 0, or MT-T > 0, or MD+MT-T > MD, or ML-T > MD, or 1/M > D/(ML-T), or p* > p**.
  • 173
    • 25844489147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra Figure 1 for a depiction of this result
    • See supra Figure 1 for a depiction of this result.
  • 174
    • 25844520844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 < 0.
  • 175
    • 25844502561 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 = > 0 as M > 1.
  • 176
    • 25844492560 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 < 0 as M > 1.
  • 177
    • 25844482641 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • M** > 1 is equivalent to (D+pT) > pL = pD+pT, or D > pD, or 1 > p.
  • 178
    • 25844442878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • p < 1 means that (D+pT) < D+T, or (D+pT) < L, or (D+pT)/L < 1, or(D+pT)/pL < 1/ p, or M** < M*.
  • 179
    • 25844459674 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 19-36 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 19-36 and accompanying text.
  • 180
    • 25844517221 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2) < 0.
  • 181
    • 25844528508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 > 0 as p < 1.
  • 182
    • 25844491763 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2 < 0 as p < 1.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.