-
1
-
-
0004026130
-
-
Cambridge, ch. 2
-
Robert Young, Darwin's metaphor: Nature's place in Victorian culture (Cambridge, 1985), ch. 2; Martin J. S. Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy", The British journal for the history of science, vii (1974), 205-42; M. Norton Wise, "Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxvii (1989), 263-301 and 391-449, xxviii (1990), 221-61. See also the sources cited in ibid., 296 n7.
-
(1985)
Darwin's Metaphor: Nature's Place in Victorian Culture
-
-
Young, R.1
-
2
-
-
84972072932
-
Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy
-
Robert Young, Darwin's metaphor: Nature's place in Victorian culture (Cambridge, 1985), ch. 2; Martin J. S. Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy", The British journal for the history of science, vii (1974), 205-42; M. Norton Wise, "Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxvii (1989), 263-301 and 391-449, xxviii (1990), 221-61. See also the sources cited in ibid., 296 n7.
-
(1974)
The British Journal for the History of Science
, vol.7
, pp. 205-242
-
-
Rudwick, M.J.S.1
-
3
-
-
84965569285
-
Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain
-
Robert Young, Darwin's metaphor: Nature's place in Victorian culture (Cambridge, 1985), ch. 2; Martin J. S. Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy", The British journal for the history of science, vii (1974), 205-42; M. Norton Wise, "Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxvii (1989), 263-301 and 391-449, xxviii (1990), 221-61. See also the sources cited in ibid., 296 n7.
-
(1989)
History of Science
, vol.27
, pp. 263-301
-
-
Norton Wise, M.1
-
4
-
-
84965629342
-
-
Robert Young, Darwin's metaphor: Nature's place in Victorian culture (Cambridge, 1985), ch. 2; Martin J. S. Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy", The British journal for the history of science, vii (1974), 205-42; M. Norton Wise, "Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxvii (1989), 263-301 and 391-449, xxviii (1990), 221-61. See also the sources cited in ibid., 296 n7.
-
(1990)
History of Science
, vol.28
, pp. 221-261
-
-
-
5
-
-
0003059033
-
-
n7
-
Robert Young, Darwin's metaphor: Nature's place in Victorian culture (Cambridge, 1985), ch. 2; Martin J. S. Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne: Lyellian time and political economy", The British journal for the history of science, vii (1974), 205-42; M. Norton Wise, "Work and waste: Political economy and natural philosophy in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxvii (1989), 263-301 and 391-449, xxviii (1990), 221-61. See also the sources cited in ibid., 296 n7.
-
History of Science
, pp. 296
-
-
-
7
-
-
0001377903
-
Natural knowledge in cultural context: The Manchester model
-
A. W. Thackray, "Natural knowledge in cultural context: The Manchester model", American historical review, lxxix (1974), 672-709. See also his similar arguments in "The Industrial Revolution and the image of science", in A. W. Thackray and E. Mendelsohn (eds), Science and values (New York, 1974), 2-18.
-
(1974)
American Historical Review
, vol.79
, pp. 672-709
-
-
Thackray, A.W.1
-
8
-
-
1542732522
-
The Industrial Revolution and the image of science
-
New York
-
A. W. Thackray, "Natural knowledge in cultural context: The Manchester model", American historical review, lxxix (1974), 672-709. See also his similar arguments in "The Industrial Revolution and the image of science", in A. W. Thackray and E. Mendelsohn (eds), Science and values (New York, 1974), 2-18.
-
(1974)
Science and Values
, pp. 2-18
-
-
Thackray, A.W.1
Mendelsohn, E.2
-
9
-
-
1542417775
-
-
ref. 3
-
Thackray, "Natural knowledge" (ref. 3), 678; see Morris Berman, Social change and scientific organization: The Royal Institution, 1799-1844 (Ithaca, 1978) and Robert Kargon, Science in Victorian Manchester: Enterprise and expertise (Manchester, 1977).
-
Natural Knowledge
, pp. 678
-
-
Thackray1
-
11
-
-
0003961546
-
-
Manchester
-
Thackray, "Natural knowledge" (ref. 3), 678; see Morris Berman, Social change and scientific organization: The Royal Institution, 1799-1844 (Ithaca, 1978) and Robert Kargon, Science in Victorian Manchester: Enterprise and expertise (Manchester, 1977).
-
(1977)
Science in Victorian Manchester: Enterprise and Expertise
-
-
Kargon, R.1
-
14
-
-
84972654381
-
Objectivity and the escape from perspective
-
Lorraine Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective", Social studies of science, xxii (1992), 597-618; Simon Schaffer, "Scientific discoveries and the end of natural philosophy", Social studies of science, xvi (1986), 387-420, pp. 407-8; Richard Yeo, Defining science: William Whewell, natural knowledge, and public debate in early Victorian Britain (Cambridge, 1993).
-
(1992)
Social Studies of Science
, vol.22
, pp. 597-618
-
-
Daston, L.1
-
15
-
-
84972633344
-
Scientific discoveries and the end of natural philosophy
-
Lorraine Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective", Social studies of science, xxii (1992), 597-618; Simon Schaffer, "Scientific discoveries and the end of natural philosophy", Social studies of science, xvi (1986), 387-420, pp. 407-8; Richard Yeo, Defining science: William Whewell, natural knowledge, and public debate in early Victorian Britain (Cambridge, 1993).
-
(1986)
Social Studies of Science
, vol.16
, pp. 387-420
-
-
Schaffer, S.1
-
16
-
-
84972654381
-
-
Cambridge
-
Lorraine Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective", Social studies of science, xxii (1992), 597-618; Simon Schaffer, "Scientific discoveries and the end of natural philosophy", Social studies of science, xvi (1986), 387-420, pp. 407-8; Richard Yeo, Defining science: William Whewell, natural knowledge, and public debate in early Victorian Britain (Cambridge, 1993).
-
(1993)
Defining Science: William Whewell, Natural Knowledge, and Public Debate in Early Victorian Britain
-
-
Yeo, R.1
-
17
-
-
84972376946
-
Astronomers mark time: Discipline and the personal equation
-
An exception is Simon Schaffer, "Astronomers mark time: Discipline and the personal equation", Science in context, ii (1988), 115-45.
-
(1988)
Science in Context
, vol.2
, pp. 115-145
-
-
Schaffer, S.1
-
18
-
-
1542522452
-
-
Cambridge
-
One historian who has observed this use of scientific language is Maxine Berg, in The machinery question and the making of political economy 1815-1848 (Cambridge, 1980), Part 3, although she mainly focuses on the impact of scientific language on the factory and not the reverse. See also Wise's commentary on Berg in "Work and waste" (ref. 1), 393-4.
-
(1980)
The Machinery Question and the Making of Political Economy 1815-1848
, Issue.3 PART
-
-
Berg, M.1
-
19
-
-
1542732523
-
-
ref. 1
-
One historian who has observed this use of scientific language is Maxine Berg, in The machinery question and the making of political economy 1815-1848 (Cambridge, 1980), Part 3, although she mainly focuses on the impact of scientific language on the factory and not the reverse. See also Wise's commentary on Berg in "Work and waste" (ref. 1), 393-4.
-
Work and Waste
, pp. 393-394
-
-
Berg1
-
21
-
-
1542522471
-
-
ref. 1
-
Rudwick, "Poulett Scrope on the volcanoes of Auvergne" (ref. 1), 236-42; Wise, "Work and waste" (ref. 1), Parts 1 and 2.
-
Work and Waste
, Issue.1-2 PARTS
-
-
Wise1
-
22
-
-
1542417779
-
-
London
-
Gillian Beer, Darwin's plots: Evolutionary narrative in Darwin, George Eliot and nineteenth-century fiction (London, 1983), Part 1; Wise, "Work and waste" (ref. 1), 415. On Darwin see also Sylvan S. Schweber, "Darwin and the political economists: Divergence of character", Journal of the history of biology, xiii (1980), 195-289.
-
(1983)
Darwin's Plots: Evolutionary Narrative in Darwin, George Eliot and Nineteenth-century Fiction
, Issue.1 PART
-
-
Beer, G.1
-
23
-
-
1542732523
-
-
ref. 1
-
Gillian Beer, Darwin's plots: Evolutionary narrative in Darwin, George Eliot and nineteenth-century fiction (London, 1983), Part 1; Wise, "Work and waste" (ref. 1), 415. On Darwin see also Sylvan S. Schweber, "Darwin and the political economists: Divergence of character", Journal of the history of biology, xiii (1980), 195-289.
-
Work and Waste
, pp. 415
-
-
Wise1
-
24
-
-
0019054603
-
Darwin and the political economists: Divergence of character
-
Gillian Beer, Darwin's plots: Evolutionary narrative in Darwin, George Eliot and nineteenth-century fiction (London, 1983), Part 1; Wise, "Work and waste" (ref. 1), 415. On Darwin see also Sylvan S. Schweber, "Darwin and the political economists: Divergence of character", Journal of the history of biology, xiii (1980), 195-289.
-
(1980)
Journal of the History of Biology
, vol.13
, pp. 195-289
-
-
Schweber, S.S.1
-
25
-
-
0000141893
-
Figures of arithmetic, figures of speech: The discourse of statistics in the 1830s
-
On this subject in early nineteenth-century England see Mary Poovey, "Figures of arithmetic, figures of speech: The discourse of statistics in the 1830", Critical inquiry, xix (1993), 256-77 and Simon Dentith, "Political economy, fiction and the language of practical ideology in nineteenth-century England", Social history, viii (1983), 183-200.
-
(1993)
Critical Inquiry
, vol.19
, pp. 256-277
-
-
Poovey, M.1
-
26
-
-
1542521800
-
Political economy, fiction and the language of practical ideology in nineteenth-century England
-
On this subject in early nineteenth-century England see Mary Poovey, "Figures of arithmetic, figures of speech: The discourse of statistics in the 1830", Critical inquiry, xix (1993), 256-77 and Simon Dentith, "Political economy, fiction and the language of practical ideology in nineteenth-century England", Social history, viii (1983), 183-200.
-
(1983)
Social History
, vol.8
, pp. 183-200
-
-
Dentith, S.1
-
27
-
-
1542417788
-
Description of "the several employments and offices" of the fellows of Salomon's House
-
London
-
See in particular Bacon's description of "the several employments and offices" of the fellows of Salomon's House, in The advancement of learning and New Atlantis (1627; London, 1951), 296-7.
-
(1627)
The Advancement of Learning and New Atlantis
, pp. 296-297
-
-
Bacon1
-
28
-
-
0022117653
-
An idol of the market-place: Bacon in nineteenth-century Britain
-
See Richard Yeo, "An idol of the market-place: Bacon in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxiii (1985), 251-98; Jonathan Smith, Fact and feeling: Baconian science and the nineteenth-century literary imagination (Madison, Wisc., 1994), 11-44; and J. B. Morrell and Arnold Thackray, Gentlemen of science: Early years of the British Association for the Advancement of Science (Oxford, 1981), 267-73.
-
(1985)
History of Science
, vol.23
, pp. 251-298
-
-
Yeo, R.1
-
29
-
-
0022117653
-
-
Madison, Wisc.
-
See Richard Yeo, "An idol of the market-place: Bacon in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxiii (1985), 251-98; Jonathan Smith, Fact and feeling: Baconian science and the nineteenth-century literary imagination (Madison, Wisc., 1994), 11-44; and J. B. Morrell and Arnold Thackray, Gentlemen of science: Early years of the British Association for the Advancement of Science (Oxford, 1981), 267-73.
-
(1994)
Fact and Feeling: Baconian Science and the Nineteenth-century Literary Imagination
, pp. 11-44
-
-
Smith, J.1
-
30
-
-
0022117653
-
-
Oxford
-
See Richard Yeo, "An idol of the market-place: Bacon in nineteenth-century Britain", History of science, xxiii (1985), 251-98; Jonathan Smith, Fact and feeling: Baconian science and the nineteenth-century literary imagination (Madison, Wisc., 1994), 11-44; and J. B. Morrell and Arnold Thackray, Gentlemen of science: Early years of the British Association for the Advancement of Science (Oxford, 1981), 267-73.
-
(1981)
Gentlemen of Science: Early Years of the British Association for the Advancement of Science
, pp. 267-273
-
-
Morrell, J.B.1
Thackray, A.2
-
33
-
-
0009088264
-
Modern science - Inductive philosophy
-
John Herschel, Preliminary discourse on the study of natural philosophy (London, 1830), 103; William Whewell, "Modern science - inductive philosophy", Quarterly review, xlv (1831), 399.
-
(1831)
Quarterly Review
, vol.45
, pp. 399
-
-
Whewell, W.1
-
34
-
-
0004197458
-
-
his Works London
-
Charles Babbage, On the economy of machinery and manufactures (1835), in his Works (London, 1989), viii, 262n. On the Herschel campaign see Roy M. MacLeod, "Whigs and savants: Reflections on the reform movement in the Royal Society, 1830-48", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 55-90, pp. 59-66; for one view of Whewell's vision of the British Association see Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14), 425-30.
-
(1835)
On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures
-
-
Babbage, C.1
-
35
-
-
85086496549
-
Whigs and savants: Reflections on the reform movement in the Royal Society, 1830-48
-
Inkster and Morrell (eds), (ref. 6)
-
Charles Babbage, On the economy of machinery and manufactures (1835), in his Works (London, 1989), viii, 262n. On the Herschel campaign see Roy M. MacLeod, "Whigs and savants: Reflections on the reform movement in the Royal Society, 1830-48", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 55-90, pp. 59-66; for one view of Whewell's vision of the British Association see Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14), 425-30.
-
Metropolis and Province
, pp. 55-90
-
-
MacLeod, R.M.1
-
36
-
-
0004351970
-
-
ref. 14
-
Charles Babbage, On the economy of machinery and manufactures (1835), in his Works (London, 1989), viii, 262n. On the Herschel campaign see Roy M. MacLeod, "Whigs and savants: Reflections on the reform movement in the Royal Society, 1830-48", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 55-90, pp. 59-66; for one view of Whewell's vision of the British Association see Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14), 425-30.
-
Gentlemen of Science
, pp. 425-430
-
-
Morrell1
Thackray2
-
37
-
-
0003478484
-
-
Basingstoke, esp. ch. 5
-
See Geoffrey Ingham, Capitalism divided?: The city and industry in British social development (Basingstoke, 1984), esp. ch. 5; Harold Perkin, The origins of modern English society 1780-1880 (1969; Toronto, 1972); and Scott Gordon, "The London Economist and the high tide of laissez faire", Journal of political economy, lxiii (1955), 461-88. London was also the chief breeding-ground for discourses (e.g. Marxian and Carlylian) that opposed the new capitalist system. For the construction of 'political economy' in Edinburgh see Biancamaria Fontana, Rethinking the politics of commercial society: The Edinburgh Review, 1802-1832 (Cambridge, 1985).
-
(1984)
Capitalism Divided?: The City and Industry in British Social Development
-
-
Ingham, G.1
-
38
-
-
0003551629
-
-
Toronto
-
See Geoffrey Ingham, Capitalism divided?: The city and industry in British social development (Basingstoke, 1984), esp. ch. 5; Harold Perkin, The origins of modern English society 1780-1880 (1969; Toronto, 1972); and Scott Gordon, "The London Economist and the high tide of laissez faire", Journal of political economy, lxiii (1955), 461-88. London was also the chief breeding-ground for discourses (e.g. Marxian and Carlylian) that opposed the new capitalist system. For the construction of 'political economy' in Edinburgh see Biancamaria Fontana, Rethinking the politics of commercial society: The Edinburgh Review, 1802-1832 (Cambridge, 1985).
-
(1969)
The Origins of Modern English Society 1780-1880
-
-
Perkin, H.1
-
39
-
-
1542732504
-
The London Economist and the high tide of laissez faire
-
See Geoffrey Ingham, Capitalism divided?: The city and industry in British social development (Basingstoke, 1984), esp. ch. 5; Harold Perkin, The origins of modern English society 1780-1880 (1969; Toronto, 1972); and Scott Gordon, "The London Economist and the high tide of laissez faire", Journal of political economy, lxiii (1955), 461-88. London was also the chief breeding-ground for discourses (e.g. Marxian and Carlylian) that opposed the new capitalist system. For the construction of 'political economy' in Edinburgh see Biancamaria Fontana, Rethinking the politics of commercial society: The Edinburgh Review, 1802-1832 (Cambridge, 1985).
-
(1955)
Journal of Political Economy
, vol.63
, pp. 461-488
-
-
Gordon, S.1
-
40
-
-
0010079598
-
-
Cambridge
-
See Geoffrey Ingham, Capitalism divided?: The city and industry in British social development (Basingstoke, 1984), esp. ch. 5; Harold Perkin, The origins of modern English society 1780-1880 (1969; Toronto, 1972); and Scott Gordon, "The London Economist and the high tide of laissez faire", Journal of political economy, lxiii (1955), 461-88. London was also the chief breeding-ground for discourses (e.g. Marxian and Carlylian) that opposed the new capitalist system. For the construction of 'political economy' in Edinburgh see Biancamaria Fontana, Rethinking the politics of commercial society: The Edinburgh Review, 1802-1832 (Cambridge, 1985).
-
(1985)
Rethinking the Politics of Commercial Society: The Edinburgh Review, 1802-1832
-
-
Fontana, B.1
-
41
-
-
0006168974
-
-
ref. 4
-
For London see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4); for Edinburgh see Steven Shapin, "'Nibbling at the teats of science': Edinburgh and the diffusion of science in the 1830s", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 151-78. A parallel between the imperialist agenda of City economists and the language of empire within British science can be developed by comparing Ingham, Capitalism divided?, with Simon Schaffer, "The history and geography of the intellectual world: Whewell's politics of language", in Menachem Fisch and Simon Schaffer (eds), William Whewell: A composite portrait (Oxford, 1991), 201-31, pp. 203-7.
-
Social Change and Scientific Organization
-
-
Berman1
-
42
-
-
85086496998
-
'Nibbling at the teats of science': Edinburgh and the diffusion of science in the 1830s
-
Inkster and Morrell (eds), (ref. 6)
-
For London see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4); for Edinburgh see Steven Shapin, "'Nibbling at the teats of science': Edinburgh and the diffusion of science in the 1830s", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 151-78. A parallel between the imperialist agenda of City economists and the language of empire within British science can be developed by comparing Ingham, Capitalism divided?, with Simon Schaffer, "The history and geography of the intellectual world: Whewell's politics of language", in Menachem Fisch and Simon Schaffer (eds), William Whewell: A composite portrait (Oxford, 1991), 201-31, pp. 203-7.
-
Metropolis and Province
, pp. 151-178
-
-
Shapin, S.1
-
43
-
-
0004042211
-
-
For London see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4); for Edinburgh see Steven Shapin, "'Nibbling at the teats of science': Edinburgh and the diffusion of science in the 1830s", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 151-78. A parallel between the imperialist agenda of City economists and the language of empire within British science can be developed by comparing Ingham, Capitalism divided?, with Simon Schaffer, "The history and geography of the intellectual world: Whewell's politics of language", in Menachem Fisch and Simon Schaffer (eds), William Whewell: A composite portrait (Oxford, 1991), 201-31, pp. 203-7.
-
Capitalism Divided?
-
-
Ingham1
-
44
-
-
0011689251
-
The history and geography of the intellectual world: Whewell's politics of language
-
Menachem Fisch and Simon Schaffer (eds), Oxford
-
For London see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4); for Edinburgh see Steven Shapin, "'Nibbling at the teats of science': Edinburgh and the diffusion of science in the 1830s", in Inkster and Morrell (eds), Metropolis and province (ref. 6), 151-78. A parallel between the imperialist agenda of City economists and the language of empire within British science can be developed by comparing Ingham, Capitalism divided?, with Simon Schaffer, "The history and geography of the intellectual world: Whewell's politics of language", in Menachem Fisch and Simon Schaffer (eds), William Whewell: A composite portrait (Oxford, 1991), 201-31, pp. 203-7.
-
(1991)
William Whewell: A Composite Portrait
, pp. 201-231
-
-
Schaffer, S.1
-
45
-
-
1542417793
-
-
London
-
For mesmerism see (e.g.) George Sandby, Mesmerism and its opponents (London, 1848); for provincial medicine see the essays by Ian Inkster and Ivan Waddington in J. Woodward and D. Richards (eds), Health care and popular medicine in nineteenth century England (New York, 1977). On the Birmingham school see S. G. Checkland, "The Birmingham economists, 1815-1850", Economic history review, 2nd ser., i (1948), 1-19, and David J. Moss, Thomas Attwood: The biography of a radical (Montreal, 1990).
-
(1848)
Mesmerism and Its Opponents
-
-
Sandby, G.1
-
46
-
-
1542732509
-
-
J. Woodward and D. Richards (eds), New York
-
For mesmerism see (e.g.) George Sandby, Mesmerism and its opponents (London, 1848); for provincial medicine see the essays by Ian Inkster and Ivan Waddington in J. Woodward and D. Richards (eds), Health care and popular medicine in nineteenth century England (New York, 1977). On the Birmingham school see S. G. Checkland, "The Birmingham economists, 1815-1850", Economic history review, 2nd ser., i (1948), 1-19, and David J. Moss, Thomas Attwood: The biography of a radical (Montreal, 1990).
-
(1977)
Health Care and Popular Medicine in Nineteenth Century England
-
-
Inkster, I.1
Waddington, I.2
-
47
-
-
84977253984
-
The Birmingham economists, 1815-1850
-
For mesmerism see (e.g.) George Sandby, Mesmerism and its opponents (London, 1848); for provincial medicine see the essays by Ian Inkster and Ivan Waddington in J. Woodward and D. Richards (eds), Health care and popular medicine in nineteenth century England (New York, 1977). On the Birmingham school see S. G. Checkland, "The Birmingham economists, 1815-1850", Economic history review, 2nd ser., i (1948), 1-19, and David J. Moss, Thomas Attwood: The biography of a radical (Montreal, 1990).
-
(1948)
Economic History Review, 2nd Ser.
, vol.1
, pp. 1-19
-
-
Checkland, S.G.1
-
48
-
-
0005529678
-
-
Montreal
-
For mesmerism see (e.g.) George Sandby, Mesmerism and its opponents (London, 1848); for provincial medicine see the essays by Ian Inkster and Ivan Waddington in J. Woodward and D. Richards (eds), Health care and popular medicine in nineteenth century England (New York, 1977). On the Birmingham school see S. G. Checkland, "The Birmingham economists, 1815-1850", Economic history review, 2nd ser., i (1948), 1-19, and David J. Moss, Thomas Attwood: The biography of a radical (Montreal, 1990).
-
(1990)
Thomas Attwood: The Biography of a Radical
-
-
Moss, D.J.1
-
49
-
-
0041378721
-
-
ref. 7
-
Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective" (ref. 7) and Theodore Porter, The rise of statistical thinking 1820-1900 (Princeton, 1986). See also William J. Ashworth, "The calculating eye: Baily, Herschel, Babbage and the business of astronomy", The British journal for the history of science, xxvii (1994), 409-41, pp. 437-40.
-
Objectivity and the Escape from Perspective
-
-
Daston1
-
50
-
-
0003708837
-
-
Princeton
-
Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective" (ref. 7) and Theodore Porter, The rise of statistical thinking 1820-1900 (Princeton, 1986). See also William J. Ashworth, "The calculating eye: Baily, Herschel, Babbage and the business of astronomy", The British journal for the history of science, xxvii (1994), 409-41, pp. 437-40.
-
(1986)
The Rise of Statistical Thinking 1820-1900
-
-
Porter, T.1
-
51
-
-
84971736607
-
The calculating eye: Baily, Herschel, Babbage and the business of astronomy
-
Daston, "Objectivity and the escape from perspective" (ref. 7) and Theodore Porter, The rise of statistical thinking 1820-1900 (Princeton, 1986). See also William J. Ashworth, "The calculating eye: Baily, Herschel, Babbage and the business of astronomy", The British journal for the history of science, xxvii (1994), 409-41, pp. 437-40.
-
(1994)
The British Journal for the History of Science
, vol.27
, pp. 409-441
-
-
Ashworth, W.J.1
-
53
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
John Herschel, Essays from the Edinburgh and Quarterly Reviews, with addresses and other pieces (London, 1857), 19. See also his defence of political economy in Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 73.
-
Preliminary discourse
, pp. 73
-
-
-
54
-
-
1542732517
-
The oral tradition in British economics: Influential economists in the Political Economy Club of London
-
See James P. Henderson, "The oral tradition in British economics: Influential economists in the Political Economy Club of London", History of political economy, xv (1983), 149-79 and Dentith, "Political economy" (ref. 12).
-
(1983)
History of Political Economy
, vol.15
, pp. 149-179
-
-
Henderson, J.P.1
-
55
-
-
33644921661
-
-
ref. 12
-
See James P. Henderson, "The oral tradition in British economics: Influential economists in the Political Economy Club of London", History of political economy, xv (1983), 149-79 and Dentith, "Political economy" (ref. 12).
-
Political Economy
-
-
Dentith1
-
56
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 10; see Yeo, "An idol of the market-place" (ref. 14), 258 and my discussion of Whewell below.
-
Preliminary Discourse
, pp. 10
-
-
Herschel1
-
57
-
-
1542417780
-
-
(ref. 14) and my discussion of Whewell below
-
Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 10; see Yeo, "An idol of the market-place" (ref. 14), 258 and my discussion of Whewell below.
-
An Idol of the Market-place
, pp. 258
-
-
Yeo1
-
60
-
-
34347374847
-
Science and the legislator: Adam Smith and after
-
On the social composition of the "natural aristocracy" in Smith see Donald Winch, "Science and the legislator: Adam Smith and after", Economic journal, xciii (1983), 501-20, pp. 502-11.
-
(1983)
Economic Journal
, vol.93
, pp. 501-520
-
-
Winch, D.1
-
61
-
-
0003587413
-
-
ref. 15
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 25, 265-7, 471, 785; Adam Smith, The theory of moral sentiments (1759; Oxford, 1976), 216. On the tensions between Smith's defence of competition and his resort to state enforcement, in the context of his views on mercantilism and physiocracy, see Keith Tribe, Land, labour and capital (London, 1978) and Vivienne Brown, Adam Smith's discourse: Canonicity, commerce and conscience (London, 1994), 142-61. For Smith on education see E. G. West, "Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964), in A. W. Coats (ed.), The classical economists and economic policy (London, 1971), 123-43.
-
Wealth of Nations
, pp. 25
-
-
Smith1
-
62
-
-
0004110659
-
-
Oxford
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 25, 265-7, 471, 785; Adam Smith, The theory of moral sentiments (1759; Oxford, 1976), 216. On the tensions between Smith's defence of competition and his resort to state enforcement, in the context of his views on mercantilism and physiocracy, see Keith Tribe, Land, labour and capital (London, 1978) and Vivienne Brown, Adam Smith's discourse: Canonicity, commerce and conscience (London, 1994), 142-61. For Smith on education see E. G. West, "Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964), in A. W. Coats (ed.), The classical economists and economic policy (London, 1971), 123-43.
-
(1759)
The Theory of Moral Sentiments
, pp. 216
-
-
Smith, A.1
-
63
-
-
1542417781
-
-
London
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 25, 265-7, 471, 785; Adam Smith, The theory of moral sentiments (1759; Oxford, 1976), 216. On the tensions between Smith's defence of competition and his resort to state enforcement, in the context of his views on mercantilism and physiocracy, see Keith Tribe, Land, labour and capital (London, 1978) and Vivienne Brown, Adam Smith's discourse: Canonicity, commerce and conscience (London, 1994), 142-61. For Smith on education see E. G. West, "Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964), in A. W. Coats (ed.), The classical economists and economic policy (London, 1971), 123-43.
-
(1978)
Land, Labour and Capital
-
-
Tribe, K.1
-
64
-
-
0003521733
-
-
London
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 25, 265-7, 471, 785; Adam Smith, The theory of moral sentiments (1759; Oxford, 1976), 216. On the tensions between Smith's defence of competition and his resort to state enforcement, in the context of his views on mercantilism and physiocracy, see Keith Tribe, Land, labour and capital (London, 1978) and Vivienne Brown, Adam Smith's discourse: Canonicity, commerce and conscience (London, 1994), 142-61. For Smith on education see E. G. West, "Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964), in A. W. Coats (ed.), The classical economists and economic policy (London, 1971), 123-43.
-
(1994)
Adam Smith's Discourse: Canonicity, Commerce and Conscience
, pp. 142-161
-
-
Brown, V.1
-
65
-
-
1542627304
-
"Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964)
-
A. W. Coats (ed.), London
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 25, 265-7, 471, 785; Adam Smith, The theory of moral sentiments (1759; Oxford, 1976), 216. On the tensions between Smith's defence of competition and his resort to state enforcement, in the context of his views on mercantilism and physiocracy, see Keith Tribe, Land, labour and capital (London, 1978) and Vivienne Brown, Adam Smith's discourse: Canonicity, commerce and conscience (London, 1994), 142-61. For Smith on education see E. G. West, "Private versus public education, a classical economic dispute" (1964), in A. W. Coats (ed.), The classical economists and economic policy (London, 1971), 123-43.
-
(1971)
The Classical Economists and Economic Policy
, pp. 123-143
-
-
West, E.G.1
-
67
-
-
1542732520
-
-
ref. 7
-
Daston observes in "Objectivity and the escape from perspective" (ref. 7), 605, that Smith looked up to natural philosophers as "paragons of the virtue of disinterestedness, both in the immediate sense of forsaking the motives of selfish gain, and in the more remote sense of remaining serene in the face of ... public contempt". On the value of disinterestedness in Smith see also Mary Poovey, "The social constitution of 'class': Towards a history of classificatory thinking", in W. C. Dimock and M. T. Gilmore (eds), Rethinking class: Literary studies and social formations (New York, 1994), 15-56, pp. 32-47.
-
Objectivity and the Escape from Perspective
, pp. 605
-
-
-
68
-
-
1542417782
-
The social constitution of 'class': Towards a history of classificatory thinking
-
W. C. Dimock and M. T. Gilmore (eds), New York
-
Daston observes in "Objectivity and the escape from perspective" (ref. 7), 605, that Smith looked up to natural philosophers as "paragons of the virtue of disinterestedness, both in the immediate sense of forsaking the motives of selfish gain, and in the more remote sense of remaining serene in the face of ... public contempt". On the value of disinterestedness in Smith see also Mary Poovey, "The social constitution of 'class': Towards a history of classificatory thinking", in W. C. Dimock and M. T. Gilmore (eds), Rethinking class: Literary studies and social formations (New York, 1994), 15-56, pp. 32-47.
-
(1994)
Rethinking Class: Literary Studies and Social Formations
, pp. 15-56
-
-
Poovey, M.1
-
69
-
-
0003587413
-
-
ref. 15
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 21; Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 12-13. Malthus's Principles had appeared in 1820. As I suggested above, claims of this nature in Herschel can be found side-by-side with expressions of his contrary urge to recede from the 'real world'. Hence his concern about science catering to "pampered appetites", cited above, was followed immediately by a call for the natural philosopher "to descend from this high but fair ground" of theory "and justify himself, his pursuits, and his pleasures in the eyes of those around him". And even in his chapter on "the higher degrees of inductive generalization" he reverted to examples such as "the boiler of the steam-engine" and the value of multiple observations that had as their ultimate source the factory floor or the insurance office (ibid., 10-11, 194, 212-16).
-
Wealth of Nations
, pp. 21
-
-
Smith1
-
70
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 21; Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 12-13. Malthus's Principles had appeared in 1820. As I suggested above, claims of this nature in Herschel can be found side-by-side with expressions of his contrary urge to recede from the 'real world'. Hence his concern about science catering to "pampered appetites", cited above, was followed immediately by a call for the natural philosopher "to descend from this high but fair ground" of theory "and justify himself, his pursuits, and his pleasures in the eyes of those around him". And even in his chapter on "the higher degrees of inductive generalization" he reverted to examples such as "the boiler of the steam-engine" and the value of multiple observations that had as their ultimate source the factory floor or the insurance office (ibid., 10-11, 194, 212-16).
-
Preliminary Discourse
, pp. 12-13
-
-
Herschel1
-
71
-
-
1542627309
-
-
had appeared in
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 21; Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 12-13. Malthus's Principles had appeared in 1820. As I suggested above, claims of this nature in Herschel can be found side-by-side with expressions of his contrary urge to recede from the 'real world'. Hence his concern about science catering to "pampered appetites", cited above, was followed immediately by a call for the natural philosopher "to descend from this high but fair ground" of theory "and justify himself, his pursuits, and his pleasures in the eyes of those around him". And even in his chapter on "the higher degrees of inductive generalization" he reverted to examples such as "the boiler of the steam-engine" and the value of multiple observations that had as their ultimate source the factory floor or the insurance office (ibid., 10-11, 194, 212-16).
-
(1820)
Principles
-
-
Malthus1
-
72
-
-
84879965266
-
-
Smith, Wealth of nations (ref. 15), 21; Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 12-13. Malthus's Principles had appeared in 1820. As I suggested above, claims of this nature in Herschel can be found side-by-side with expressions of his contrary urge to recede from the 'real world'. Hence his concern about science catering to "pampered appetites", cited above, was followed immediately by a call for the natural philosopher "to descend from this high but fair ground" of theory "and justify himself, his pursuits, and his pleasures in the eyes of those around him". And even in his chapter on "the higher degrees of inductive generalization" he reverted to examples such as "the boiler of the steam-engine" and the value of multiple observations that had as their ultimate source the factory floor or the insurance office (ibid., 10-11, 194, 212-16).
-
Principles
, pp. 10-11
-
-
-
73
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 74, 173-4, 164; Babbage, Economy of machinery and manufactures (ref. 17), 263.
-
Preliminary Discourse
, pp. 74
-
-
Herschel1
-
75
-
-
0346332601
-
Reflections on the decline of science in England and on some of its causes
-
(ref. 17), and ch. 4
-
Charles Babbage, Reflections on the decline of science in England and on some of its causes (1830), in Works (ref. 17), vii. 21-25 and ch. 4.
-
(1830)
Works
, vol.7
, pp. 21-25
-
-
Babbage, C.1
-
76
-
-
1542417776
-
-
Ibid., 86-93, 71-72. See also his contrast between W. H. Wollaston and Humphry Davy in the conclusion to Reflections, where he praised Wollaston's care "to avoid error", to teach Babbage better techniques of observations, and to shun claiming to have made observations that others could not see (pp. 206, 208-12). Wollaston, and not Davy, was on a Committee with Babbage in 1827 to reform the Royal Society. See Zeno Swijtink, "The objectification of observation: Measurement and statistical methods in the nineteenth century", in L. Krüger, L. J. Daston and M. Heidelberger (eds), The probabilistic revolution (Cambridge, Mass., 1987), i, 261-85, pp. 266-7.
-
Works
, pp. 86-93
-
-
-
77
-
-
0000315471
-
The objectification of observation: Measurement and statistical methods in the nineteenth century
-
L. Krüger, L. J. Daston and M. Heidelberger (eds), Cambridge, Mass.
-
Ibid., 86-93, 71-72. See also his contrast between W. H. Wollaston and Humphry Davy in the conclusion to Reflections, where he praised Wollaston's care "to avoid error", to teach Babbage better techniques of observations, and to shun claiming to have made observations that others could not see (pp. 206, 208-12). Wollaston, and not Davy, was on a Committee with Babbage in 1827 to reform the Royal Society. See Zeno Swijtink, "The objectification of observation: Measurement and statistical methods in the nineteenth century", in L. Krüger, L. J. Daston and M. Heidelberger (eds), The probabilistic revolution (Cambridge, Mass., 1987), i, 261-85, pp. 266-7.
-
(1987)
The Probabilistic Revolution
-
-
Swijtink, Z.1
-
78
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 44-49, 114. The fact that Herschel's reference to Jenner appeared in a paragraph that celebrated Bacon underscores the frequent overlap between Baconianism and what I am describing as Herschel's 'economic' reform model.
-
Preliminary Discourse
, pp. 44-49
-
-
Herschel1
-
79
-
-
84974149423
-
Voluntary societies and British urban élites 1780-1850: An analysis
-
The best summary of the politics of the voluntary association is R. J. Morris, "Voluntary societies and British urban élites 1780-1850: An analysis", Historical journal, xxvi (1983), 95-118. Morris notes the formal connections between voluntary associations, most of which were non-profit, and joint-stock companies in Class, sect and party: The making of the British middle class, Leeds 1820-1850 (Manchester, 1990), ch. 12.
-
(1983)
Historical Journal
, vol.26
, pp. 95-118
-
-
Morris, R.J.1
-
80
-
-
84974149423
-
-
Manchester, ch. 12
-
The best summary of the politics of the voluntary association is R. J. Morris, "Voluntary societies and British urban élites 1780-1850: An analysis", Historical journal, xxvi (1983), 95-118. Morris notes the formal connections between voluntary associations, most of which were non-profit, and joint-stock companies in Class, sect and party: The making of the British middle class, Leeds 1820-1850 (Manchester, 1990), ch. 12.
-
(1990)
Class, Sect and Party: The Making of the British middle Class, Leeds 1820-1850
-
-
-
81
-
-
0003900531
-
-
London
-
Andrew Ure, Philosophy of manufactures (London, 1835), 19-24; and see Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 197-200, and Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Head and hand: Rhetorical resources in British pedagogical writing, 1770-1850", Oxford review of education, ii (1976), 231-54.
-
(1835)
Philosophy of Manufactures
, pp. 19-24
-
-
Ure, A.1
-
82
-
-
1542417790
-
-
ref. 9
-
Andrew Ure, Philosophy of manufactures (London, 1835), 19-24; and see Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 197-200, and Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Head and hand: Rhetorical resources in British pedagogical writing, 1770-1850", Oxford review of education, ii (1976), 231-54.
-
The Machinery Question
, pp. 197-200
-
-
Berg1
-
83
-
-
84963176053
-
Head and hand: Rhetorical resources in British pedagogical writing, 1770-1850
-
Andrew Ure, Philosophy of manufactures (London, 1835), 19-24; and see Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 197-200, and Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Head and hand: Rhetorical resources in British pedagogical writing, 1770-1850", Oxford review of education, ii (1976), 231-54.
-
(1976)
Oxford Review of Education
, vol.2
, pp. 231-254
-
-
Shapin, S.1
Barnes, B.2
-
84
-
-
0003734191
-
-
Herschel to Whewell, 20 Sept. 1831, New York
-
Herschel to Whewell, 20 Sept. 1831, cited in S. F. Cannon, Science in culture: The early Victorian period (New York, 1978), 194. Herschel's fear of democratic tyranny, as well as his concern elsewhere in this letter about preserving room for individual genius, demonstrates his ambivalent feelings about the possible consequences of minimizing the role of individual discovery. But such feelings did not keep him from opposing Whewell's claim that the best discoverers could be selected out and encouraged ahead of time.
-
(1978)
Science in Culture: The Early Victorian Period
, pp. 194
-
-
Cannon, S.F.1
-
85
-
-
1542417784
-
-
ref. 7
-
Schaffer, "The end of natural philosophy" (ref. 7); John Rule, "The property of skill in the period of manufacture", in Patrick Joyce (ed.), The historical meanings of work (Cambridge, 1987), 99-118, p. 111.
-
The End of Natural Philosophy
-
-
Schaffer1
-
86
-
-
0039765470
-
The property of skill in the period of manufacture
-
Patrick Joyce (ed.), Cambridge
-
Schaffer, "The end of natural philosophy" (ref. 7); John Rule, "The property of skill in the period of manufacture", in Patrick Joyce (ed.), The historical meanings of work (Cambridge, 1987), 99-118, p. 111.
-
(1987)
The Historical Meanings of Work
, pp. 99-118
-
-
Rule, J.1
-
87
-
-
0021618373
-
Artisan or labour aristocrat?
-
See also E. J. Hobsbawm, "Artisan or labour aristocrat?", Economic history review, xxxvii (1984), 355-72, pp. 357-61 for the contemporary distinction between 'being in a trade' and 'having a trade'.
-
(1984)
Economic History Review
, vol.37
, pp. 355-372
-
-
Hobsbawm, E.J.1
-
88
-
-
1542522474
-
-
ref. 17
-
Babbage, Economy of machinery (ref. 17), 263; Reflections on the decline of science (ref. 33), 21.
-
Economy of Machinery
, pp. 263
-
-
Babbage1
-
90
-
-
0003742864
-
-
ref. 36
-
These categories correspond with R. J. Morris's division of voluntary associations into "the membership society" and "the patronage society": see Morris, Class, sect and party (ref. 36), 191.
-
Class, Sect and Party
, pp. 191
-
-
Morris1
-
91
-
-
33748389949
-
-
Parliamentary papers, 1829, xxi, 221. See Ashworth, "The calculating eye" (ref. 21), 430-34; J. L. E. Dreyer and H. H. Turner (eds), History of the Royal Astronomical Society 1820-1920 (London, 1923), 44, 55-63; and David Philip Miller, "Method and the 'Micropolitics' of science: The early years of the Geological and Astronomical Societies of London", in J. A. Schuster and R. R. Yeo (eds), The politics and rhetoric of scientific method (Dordrecht, 1986), 227-57.
-
(1829)
Parliamentary Papers
, vol.21
, pp. 221
-
-
-
92
-
-
0346527830
-
-
ref. 21
-
Parliamentary papers, 1829, xxi, 221. See Ashworth, "The calculating eye" (ref. 21), 430-34; J. L. E. Dreyer and H. H. Turner (eds), History of the Royal Astronomical Society 1820-1920 (London, 1923), 44, 55-63; and David Philip Miller, "Method and the 'Micropolitics' of science: The early years of the Geological and Astronomical Societies of London", in J. A. Schuster and R. R. Yeo (eds), The politics and rhetoric of scientific method (Dordrecht, 1986), 227-57.
-
The Calculating Eye
, pp. 430-434
-
-
Ashworth1
-
93
-
-
0040111552
-
-
London
-
Parliamentary papers, 1829, xxi, 221. See Ashworth, "The calculating eye" (ref. 21), 430-34; J. L. E. Dreyer and H. H. Turner (eds), History of the Royal Astronomical Society 1820-1920 (London, 1923), 44, 55-63; and David Philip Miller, "Method and the 'Micropolitics' of science: The early years of the Geological and Astronomical Societies of London", in J. A. Schuster and R. R. Yeo (eds), The politics and rhetoric of scientific method (Dordrecht, 1986), 227-57.
-
(1923)
History of the Royal Astronomical Society 1820-1920
, pp. 44
-
-
Dreyer, J.L.E.1
Turner, H.H.2
-
94
-
-
1542732508
-
Method and the 'Micropolitics' of science: The early years of the Geological and Astronomical Societies of London
-
J. A. Schuster and R. R. Yeo (eds), Dordrecht
-
Parliamentary papers, 1829, xxi, 221. See Ashworth, "The calculating eye" (ref. 21), 430-34; J. L. E. Dreyer and H. H. Turner (eds), History of the Royal Astronomical Society 1820-1920 (London, 1923), 44, 55-63; and David Philip Miller, "Method and the 'Micropolitics' of science: The early years of the Geological and Astronomical Societies of London", in J. A. Schuster and R. R. Yeo (eds), The politics and rhetoric of scientific method (Dordrecht, 1986), 227-57.
-
(1986)
The Politics and Rhetoric of Scientific Method
, pp. 227-257
-
-
Miller, D.P.1
-
95
-
-
85044898581
-
Lord Brougham, Charles Knight, and the rights of industry
-
William F. Kennedy, "Lord Brougham, Charles Knight, and The rights of industry", Economica, xxix ( 1962), 58-71; W. H. Chaloner, "The skilled artisans during the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850" (1969), in Industry and innovation: Selected essays (London, 1990), 220-31, pp. 224-5.
-
(1962)
Economica
, vol.29
, pp. 58-71
-
-
Kennedy, W.F.1
-
96
-
-
1542732507
-
The skilled artisans during the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850
-
(1969), London
-
William F. Kennedy, "Lord Brougham, Charles Knight, and The rights of industry", Economica, xxix ( 1962), 58-71; W. H. Chaloner, "The skilled artisans during the Industrial Revolution, 1750-1850" (1969), in Industry and innovation: Selected essays (London, 1990), 220-31, pp. 224-5.
-
(1990)
Industry and Innovation: Selected Essays
, pp. 220-231
-
-
Chaloner, W.H.1
-
97
-
-
1542732513
-
-
ref. 36
-
Morris, "Voluntary societies" (ref. 36), 101. On the SDUK's administration see Monica Grobel, "The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge 1826-1846" (D.Phil, thesis, University College London, 1932).
-
Voluntary Societies
, pp. 101
-
-
Morris1
-
99
-
-
1542522478
-
Early nineteenth-century science and society: Sir John Herschel, scientism, and political economy
-
Drinkwater to Thomas Coates, 19 Oct. 1829, SDUK papers, University College London. On Herschel and the SDUK see Marvin Bolt, "Early nineteenth-century science and society: Sir John Herschel, scientism, and political economy", paper given at the 1995 History of Science Society conference in Minneapolis.
-
1995 History of Science Society conference in Minneapolis
-
-
Bolt, M.1
-
100
-
-
1542732519
-
-
Memo by J. R. McCulloch, 26 June 1830; McCulloch to Coates, 9 July 1831; De Morgan to Coates, 5 Jan. 1833, Nov. 1834, SDUK papers
-
Memo by J. R. McCulloch, 26 June 1830; McCulloch to Coates, 9 July 1831; De Morgan to Coates, 5 Jan. 1833, Nov. 1834, SDUK papers.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
1542732511
-
-
ref. 45
-
Grobel, "The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge" (ref. 45), 681; see also J. N. Hays, "Science and Brougham's Society", Annals of science, xx (1964), 227-41, pp. 239-40. On mechanics' institutes see Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Science, nature and control: Interpreting Mechanics' Institutes", Social studies of science, vii (1977), 31-74, esp. pp. 48-59; and Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 145-78.
-
The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge
, pp. 681
-
-
Grobel1
-
102
-
-
0039434051
-
Science and Brougham's Society
-
Grobel, "The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge" (ref. 45), 681; see also J. N. Hays, "Science and Brougham's Society", Annals of science, xx (1964), 227-41, pp. 239-40. On mechanics' institutes see Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Science, nature and control: Interpreting Mechanics' Institutes", Social studies of science, vii (1977), 31-74, esp. pp. 48-59; and Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 145-78.
-
(1964)
Annals of Science
, vol.20
, pp. 227-241
-
-
Hays, J.N.1
-
103
-
-
84925906326
-
Science, nature and control: Interpreting Mechanics' Institutes
-
Grobel, "The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge" (ref. 45), 681; see also J. N. Hays, "Science and Brougham's Society", Annals of science, xx (1964), 227-41, pp. 239-40. On mechanics' institutes see Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Science, nature and control: Interpreting Mechanics' Institutes", Social studies of science, vii (1977), 31-74, esp. pp. 48-59; and Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 145-78.
-
(1977)
Social Studies of Science
, vol.7
, pp. 31-74
-
-
Shapin, S.1
Barnes, B.2
-
104
-
-
1542417790
-
-
ref. 9
-
Grobel, "The Society for the Diffusion of Useful Knowledge" (ref. 45), 681; see also J. N. Hays, "Science and Brougham's Society", Annals of science, xx (1964), 227-41, pp. 239-40. On mechanics' institutes see Steven Shapin and Barry Barnes, "Science, nature and control: Interpreting Mechanics' Institutes", Social studies of science, vii (1977), 31-74, esp. pp. 48-59; and Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 145-78.
-
The Machinery Question
, pp. 145-178
-
-
Berg1
-
105
-
-
1542627307
-
Study of natural philosophy
-
on Herschel's failure to support including science in the undergraduate curriculum
-
Herschel's disinclination to practice what he preached (or even preach it very consistently) frustrated his scientific friends: see De Morgan, "Study of natural philosophy", Quarterly journal of education, iii (1832), 70 (on Herschel's failure to support including science in the undergraduate curriculum) and Cannon, Science in culture (ref. 37), 183-4, on his ambivalent response to Babbage's Reflections.
-
(1832)
Quarterly Journal of Education
, vol.3
, pp. 70
-
-
De Morgan1
-
106
-
-
0004611311
-
-
ref. 37
-
Herschel's disinclination to practice what he preached (or even preach it very consistently) frustrated his scientific friends: see De Morgan, "Study of natural philosophy", Quarterly journal of education, iii (1832), 70 (on Herschel's failure to support including science in the undergraduate curriculum) and Cannon, Science in culture (ref. 37), 183-4, on his ambivalent response to Babbage's Reflections.
-
Science in Culture
, pp. 183-184
-
-
Cannon1
-
107
-
-
77949408036
-
-
Herschel's disinclination to practice what he preached (or even preach it very consistently) frustrated his scientific friends: see De Morgan, "Study of natural philosophy", Quarterly journal of education, iii (1832), 70 (on Herschel's failure to support including science in the undergraduate curriculum) and Cannon, Science in culture (ref. 37), 183-4, on his ambivalent response to Babbage's Reflections.
-
Reflections
-
-
Babbage1
-
109
-
-
1542417783
-
Passages from the life of a philosopher
-
Babbage to Herschel, 2 June 1825, HS 2.184, Royal Society papers; (ref. 17)
-
Babbage to Herschel, 2 June 1825, HS 2.184, Royal Society papers; Babbage, Passages from the life of a philosopher (1864), in Works (ref. 17), xi, 86.
-
(1864)
Works
, pp. 11
-
-
Babbage1
-
110
-
-
84937314397
-
Babbage's intelligence: Calculating engines and the factory system
-
The best discussion of Babbage's misbegotten partnership with Clement is in Simon Schaffer, "Babbage's intelligence: Calculating engines and the factory system", Critical inquiry, xxi (1994), 201-28.
-
(1994)
Critical Inquiry
, vol.21
, pp. 201-228
-
-
Schaffer, S.1
-
111
-
-
0028508581
-
A calculating profession: Victorian actuaries among the statisticians
-
On the important place of commercial life insurance in early nineteenth-century British scientific reform see T. L. Alborn, "A calculating profession: Victorian actuaries among the statisticians", Science in context, vii (1994), 433-68.
-
(1994)
Science in Context
, vol.7
, pp. 433-468
-
-
Alborn, T.L.1
-
112
-
-
1542417785
-
-
Thomas Colby to Babbage, 22 Apr. 1824, BL add ms 37183.120; Babbage to Herschel, 28 May 1824, HP 2.196, Royal Society papers
-
Thomas Colby to Babbage, 22 Apr. 1824, BL add ms 37183.120; Babbage to Herschel, 28 May 1824, HP 2.196, Royal Society papers.
-
-
-
-
113
-
-
1542417786
-
-
Babbage to Herschel, ibid.
-
Babbage to Herschel, ibid.
-
-
-
-
115
-
-
0347968849
-
-
ref. 50
-
Babbage, Comparative view of the various institutions for the assurance of lives (London, 1826); Hyman, Charles Babbage (ref. 50), 62-64.
-
Charles Babbage
, pp. 62-64
-
-
Hyman1
-
116
-
-
1542522474
-
-
ref. 17
-
Babbage, Economy of machinery (ref. 17), 264; and in general, see Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 182-9.
-
Economy of Machinery
, pp. 264
-
-
Babbage1
-
117
-
-
1542417790
-
-
ref. 9
-
Babbage, Economy of machinery (ref. 17), 264; and in general, see Berg, The machinery question (ref. 9), 182-9.
-
The Machinery Question
, pp. 182-189
-
-
Berg1
-
120
-
-
77949408036
-
-
(ref. 33), ch. 1
-
Babbage, Reflections (ref. 33), ch. 1; for Brewster see his review of Babbage in Quarterly review, lxiii (1831), 305-42; for Harcourt see British Association report, 1831, 22-42, and Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14).
-
Reflections
-
-
Babbage1
-
121
-
-
1542627310
-
-
Babbage, Reflections (ref. 33), ch. 1; for Brewster see his review of Babbage in Quarterly review, lxiii (1831), 305-42; for Harcourt see British Association report, 1831, 22-42, and Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14).
-
(1831)
Quarterly Review
, vol.63
, pp. 305-342
-
-
Babbage1
-
122
-
-
33748410051
-
-
Babbage, Reflections (ref. 33), ch. 1; for Brewster see his review of Babbage in Quarterly review, lxiii (1831), 305-42; for Harcourt see British Association report, 1831, 22-42, and Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14).
-
(1831)
British Association Report
, pp. 22-42
-
-
Harcourt1
-
123
-
-
0004351970
-
-
ref. 14
-
Babbage, Reflections (ref. 33), ch. 1; for Brewster see his review of Babbage in Quarterly review, lxiii (1831), 305-42; for Harcourt see British Association report, 1831, 22-42, and Morrell and Thackray, Gentlemen of science (ref. 14).
-
Gentlemen of Science
-
-
Morrell1
Thackray2
-
124
-
-
1542417784
-
-
ref. 7
-
See Schaffer, "The end of natural philosophy" (ref. 7) and "The history and geography of the intellectual world" (ref. 19); and Yeo, Defining science (ref. 7).
-
The End of Natural Philosophy
-
-
Schaffer1
-
126
-
-
0038931353
-
-
ref. 7
-
See Schaffer, "The end of natural philosophy" (ref. 7) and "The history and geography of the intellectual world" (ref. 19); and Yeo, Defining science (ref. 7).
-
Defining Science
-
-
Yeo1
-
127
-
-
1542522480
-
-
ref. 1
-
Wise makes a similar point about Whewell's response to Babbage's economics of steam power in "Work and waste" (ref. 1), Part 2.
-
Work and Waste
, Issue.2 PART
-
-
-
128
-
-
0347158286
-
Charles Dupin's study visits to the British Isles, 1816-1824
-
As did other French economists at the time: see Margaret Bradley, "Charles Dupin's study visits to the British Isles, 1816-1824", Technology and culture, xxxii (1991), 47-69.
-
(1991)
Technology and Culture
, vol.32
, pp. 47-69
-
-
Bradley, M.1
-
130
-
-
0038973272
-
Say's conception of the role of the entrepreneur
-
See G. Koolman, "Say's conception of the role of the entrepreneur", Economica, xxxviii (1971), 269-86, pp. 284-5.
-
(1971)
Economica
, vol.38
, pp. 269-286
-
-
Koolman, G.1
-
133
-
-
1542522475
-
Mathematical exposition of some doctrines of political economy
-
Whewell "Mathematical exposition of some doctrines of political economy", Transactions of the Cambridge Philosophical Society, iii (1830), 191-230 and "Mathematical exposition of some of the leading doctrines in Mr Ricardo's 'Principles of political economy and taxation'", ibid, iv (1831), 155-98. See Pietro Corsi, "The heritage of Dugald Stewart: Oxford philosophy and the method of political economy", Nuncius, iii (1987), 89-144.
-
(1830)
Transactions of the Cambridge Philosophical Society
, vol.3
, pp. 191-230
-
-
Whewell1
-
134
-
-
0346020525
-
Mathematical exposition of some of the leading doctrines in Mr Ricardo's 'Principles of political economy and taxation'
-
Whewell "Mathematical exposition of some doctrines of political economy", Transactions of the Cambridge Philosophical Society, iii (1830), 191-230 and "Mathematical exposition of some of the leading doctrines in Mr Ricardo's 'Principles of political economy and taxation'", ibid, iv (1831), 155-98. See Pietro Corsi, "The heritage of Dugald Stewart: Oxford philosophy and the method of political economy", Nuncius, iii (1987), 89-144.
-
(1831)
Transactions of the Cambridge Philosophical Society
, vol.4
, pp. 155-198
-
-
-
135
-
-
1542732514
-
The heritage of Dugald Stewart: Oxford philosophy and the method of political economy
-
Whewell "Mathematical exposition of some doctrines of political economy", Transactions of the Cambridge Philosophical Society, iii (1830), 191-230 and "Mathematical exposition of some of the leading doctrines in Mr Ricardo's 'Principles of political economy and taxation'", ibid, iv (1831), 155-98. See Pietro Corsi, "The heritage of Dugald Stewart: Oxford philosophy and the method of political economy", Nuncius, iii (1987), 89-144.
-
(1987)
Nuncius
, vol.3
, pp. 89-144
-
-
Corsi, P.1
-
136
-
-
33644953368
-
-
Whewell to Jones, 19 Feb. 1832, London
-
Whewell to Jones, 19 Feb. 1832, in Isaac Todhunter, William Whewell (London, 1876), ii, 140-1.
-
(1876)
William Whewell
-
-
Todhunter, I.1
-
138
-
-
1542417789
-
-
ref. 16
-
Herschel, Preliminary discourse (ref. 16), 305-6; see also p. 300. I am here claiming only that Dalton occupied the same location with respect to Whewell that artisans occupied with respect to capitalists; not that Dalton himself was more like an artisan than a capitalist.
-
Preliminary Discourse
, pp. 305-306
-
-
Herschel1
-
139
-
-
1542522482
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.
-
Quoted in Arnold Thackray, John Dalton (Cambridge, Mass., 1972), 118.
-
(1972)
John Dalton
, pp. 118
-
-
Thackray, A.1
-
140
-
-
1542417792
-
-
ref. 8
-
On Airy, see Schaffer, "Astronomers mark time" (ref. 8); on Royal Institution members as "entrepreneurial" men of science see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4), ch. 5 (on Faraday) and p. xxi, where he credits the RI with "bending science to entrepreneurial and professional purposes".
-
Astronomers Mark Time
-
-
Schaffer1
-
141
-
-
33748403406
-
-
ref. 4, ch. 5 (on Faraday)
-
On Airy, see Schaffer, "Astronomers mark time" (ref. 8); on Royal Institution members as "entrepreneurial" men of science see Berman, Social change and scientific organization (ref. 4), ch. 5 (on Faraday) and p. xxi, where he credits the RI with "bending science to entrepreneurial and professional purposes".
-
Social Change and Scientific Organization
-
-
Berman1
-
142
-
-
0004135818
-
-
Chicago
-
Although, as Adrian Desmond has shown in The politics of evolution: Morphology, medicine, and reform in radical London (Chicago, 1989), scientists whose views were closer to Whewell's than to Babbage's did not hesitate to play the 'public combination' card when it suited them. See Desmond's discussion of P. M. Roget's self-defence against charges that he had plagiarized R. E. Grant's anatomy lectures in his Bridgewater treatise - a defence that rested on the claim that Grant's lectures had entered the public domain once Roget had paid to attend.
-
(1989)
The Politics of Evolution: Morphology, Medicine, and Reform in Radical London
-
-
Desmond, A.1
-
144
-
-
0004280390
-
-
3rd edn, London
-
Whewell, History of the inductive sciences (1837; 3rd edn, London, 1857), ii, 132; and see Yeo, Defining science (ref. 7), 150-60. On Craik and Smiles see Kenneth Fielden, "Samuel Smiles and self-help", Victorian studies, xii (1968), 155-76.
-
(1837)
History of the Inductive Sciences
-
-
Whewell1
-
145
-
-
0038931353
-
-
ref. 7
-
Whewell, History of the inductive sciences (1837; 3rd edn, London, 1857), ii, 132; and see Yeo, Defining science (ref. 7), 150-60. On Craik and Smiles see Kenneth Fielden, "Samuel Smiles and self-help", Victorian studies, xii (1968), 155-76.
-
Defining Science
, pp. 150-160
-
-
Yeo1
-
146
-
-
1542627308
-
Samuel Smiles and self-help
-
Whewell, History of the inductive sciences (1837; 3rd edn, London, 1857), ii, 132; and see Yeo, Defining science (ref. 7), 150-60. On Craik and Smiles see Kenneth Fielden, "Samuel Smiles and self-help", Victorian studies, xii (1968), 155-76.
-
(1968)
Victorian Studies
, vol.12
, pp. 155-176
-
-
Fielden, K.1
-
148
-
-
84929068833
-
Negotiating notation: Chemical symbols and British society, 1831-1835
-
T. L. Alborn, "Negotiating notation: Chemical symbols and British society, 1831-1835", Annals of science, xlvi (1989), 437-60; Lawrence Goldman, "The origins of British 'Social science': Political economy, natural science and statistics, 1830-1835", Historical journal, xxvi (1983), 589-616.
-
(1989)
Annals of Science
, vol.46
, pp. 437-460
-
-
Alborn, T.L.1
-
149
-
-
0020868168
-
The origins of British 'Social science': Political economy, natural science and statistics, 1830-1835
-
T. L. Alborn, "Negotiating notation: Chemical symbols and British society, 1831-1835", Annals of science, xlvi (1989), 437-60; Lawrence Goldman, "The origins of British 'Social science': Political economy, natural science and statistics, 1830-1835", Historical journal, xxvi (1983), 589-616.
-
(1983)
Historical Journal
, vol.26
, pp. 589-616
-
-
Goldman, L.1
-
152
-
-
84923937773
-
-
Princeton
-
In theory: see Charles Darwin, The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex (1871; Princeton, 1981), ii, 385. In practice: see James A. Secord, "Darwin and the breeders: A social history", in David Kohn (ed.), The Darwinian heritage (Princeton, 1985), 519-42 and John Beatty, "Speaking of species: Darwin's strategy", ibid., 265-81.
-
(1871)
The Descent of Man, and Selection in Relation to Sex
-
-
Darwin, C.1
-
153
-
-
0042812833
-
Darwin and the breeders: A social history
-
David Kohn (ed.), Princeton
-
In theory: see Charles Darwin, The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex (1871; Princeton, 1981), ii, 385. In practice: see James A. Secord, "Darwin and the breeders: A social history", in David Kohn (ed.), The Darwinian heritage (Princeton, 1985), 519-42 and John Beatty, "Speaking of species: Darwin's strategy", ibid., 265-81.
-
(1985)
The Darwinian Heritage
, pp. 519-542
-
-
Secord, J.A.1
-
154
-
-
0011680369
-
Speaking of species: Darwin's strategy
-
Princeton
-
In theory: see Charles Darwin, The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex (1871; Princeton, 1981), ii, 385. In practice: see James A. Secord, "Darwin and the breeders: A social history", in David Kohn (ed.), The Darwinian heritage (Princeton, 1985), 519-42 and John Beatty, "Speaking of species: Darwin's strategy", ibid., 265-81.
-
The Darwinian Heritage
, pp. 265-281
-
-
Beatty, J.1
|