-
1
-
-
0003722446
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1997)
Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925
-
-
Scranton, P.P.1
-
2
-
-
84972168217
-
Diversity in diversity: Flexible production and American industrialization, 1880-1930
-
Spring
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1991)
Business History Review
, vol.65
, pp. 27-90
-
-
Scranton, P.P.1
-
3
-
-
0010814863
-
-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1995)
The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915
-
-
Brown, J.K.1
-
4
-
-
0010065065
-
Getting it together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia
-
Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., New York: Columbia University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1991)
Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers
-
-
Harris, H.J.1
-
5
-
-
0003687287
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1996)
Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power
-
-
Herrigel, G.1
-
6
-
-
0003632312
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1996)
World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization
-
-
Säbel, C.F.1
Zeitlin, J.2
-
7
-
-
0003624744
-
-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1994)
Alternative Tracks: the Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917
-
-
Berk, G.1
-
8
-
-
1542744784
-
Communities of competitors: Open price associations and the American state, 1911-1929
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1996)
Social Science History
, vol.3
, pp. 375-400
-
-
Berk, G.1
-
9
-
-
0033480257
-
Political and institutional conditions for governance by association: Private order and price controls in American fire insurance
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(1999)
Politics and Society
, vol.27
, pp. 67-103
-
-
Schneiberg, M.1
-
10
-
-
0041616079
-
Organizational heterogeneity and the production of new forms: Politics, social movements and mutual companies in American fire insurance, 1900-1930
-
Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Greenwich, Conn.: JAI
-
In developing these findings, we add to a growing body of work that documents organizational diversity within national economies during the Fordist era. However, we go beyond work that often focuses on a single industry or case to add a form and a whole series of industries to the accumulating anomalies for uniform institutional images of national economies. See Phillip P. Scranton, Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 1865-1925 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); Phillip P. Scranton, "Diversity in Diversity: Flexible Production and American Industrialization, 1880-1930," Business History Review 65 (Spring 1991): 27-90; John K. Brown, The Baldwin Locomotive Works, 1831-1915 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1995); Howell J. Harris, "Getting It Together: The Metal Manufacturers' Association of Philadelphia," in Sanford M. Jacoby, ed., Masters to Managers: Historical and Comparative Perspectives on American Employers (New York: Columbia University Press, 1991); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions: The Sources of German Industrial Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Charles F. Säbel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities: Flexibility and Mass Production in Western Industrialization (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks: The Constitution of American Industrial Order, 1865-1917 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1994); Gerald Berk, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State, 1911-1929," Social Science History 3 (1996): 375-400; Marc Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions for Governance by Association: Private Order and Price Controls in American Fire Insurance," Politics and Society 27 (1999): 67-103; and Marc Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms: Politics, Social Movements and Mutual Companies in American Fire Insurance, 1900-1930," in Michael Lounsbury and Marc Vantresca, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2002).
-
(2002)
Research in the Sociology of Organizations
-
-
Schneiberg, M.1
-
11
-
-
0001934885
-
Beyond the iconography of order: Notes for a 'new' institutionalism
-
Larry Dodd and Calvin Jilson, eds., Boulder, Colo.: Westview
-
Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek, "Beyond the Iconography of Order: Notes for a 'New' Institutionalism," in Larry Dodd and Calvin Jilson, eds., The Dynamics of Politics (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1994); Kathleen Thelen, "Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics," Annual Review of American Political Science 2 (1999): 369-404; Colin Crouch and Henry Farrell, "Breaking the Path of Institutional Development? Alternatives to the New Determinism," MPIfG Discussion Paper 02/5, http://www.mpi-fg-koeln. mpg.de (2002); and Wolfgang Streeck and Kozo Yamamura, "Introduction: Convergence or Diversity? Stability and Change in German and Japanese Capitalism," in Kozo Yamamura and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese Capitalism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(1994)
The Dynamics of Politics
-
-
Orren, K.1
Skowronek, S.2
-
12
-
-
0033473433
-
Historical institutionalism in comparative politics
-
Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek, "Beyond the Iconography of Order: Notes for a 'New' Institutionalism," in Larry Dodd and Calvin Jilson, eds., The Dynamics of Politics (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1994); Kathleen Thelen, "Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics," Annual Review of American Political Science 2 (1999): 369-404; Colin Crouch and Henry Farrell, "Breaking the Path of Institutional Development? Alternatives to the New Determinism," MPIfG Discussion Paper 02/5, http://www.mpi-fg-koeln. mpg.de (2002); and Wolfgang Streeck and Kozo Yamamura, "Introduction: Convergence or Diversity? Stability and Change in German and Japanese Capitalism," in Kozo Yamamura and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese Capitalism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(1999)
Annual Review of American Political Science
, vol.2
, pp. 369-404
-
-
Thelen, K.1
-
13
-
-
4544305543
-
Breaking the path of institutional development? Alternatives to the new determinism
-
Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek, "Beyond the Iconography of Order: Notes for a 'New' Institutionalism," in Larry Dodd and Calvin Jilson, eds., The Dynamics of Politics (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1994); Kathleen Thelen, "Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics," Annual Review of American Political Science 2 (1999): 369-404; Colin Crouch and Henry Farrell, "Breaking the Path of Institutional Development? Alternatives to the New Determinism," MPIfG Discussion Paper 02/5, http://www.mpi-fg-koeln. mpg.de (2002); and Wolfgang Streeck and Kozo Yamamura, "Introduction: Convergence or Diversity? Stability and Change in German and Japanese Capitalism," in Kozo Yamamura and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese Capitalism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(2002)
MPIfG Discussion Paper
, vol.2
, Issue.5
-
-
Crouch, C.1
Farrell, H.2
-
14
-
-
3542992522
-
Introduction: Convergence or diversity? Stability and change in German and Japanese capitalism
-
Kozo Yamamura and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Karen Orren and Stephen Skowronek, "Beyond the Iconography of Order: Notes for a 'New' Institutionalism," in Larry Dodd and Calvin Jilson, eds., The Dynamics of Politics (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1994); Kathleen Thelen, "Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics," Annual Review of American Political Science 2 (1999): 369-404; Colin Crouch and Henry Farrell, "Breaking the Path of Institutional Development? Alternatives to the New Determinism," MPIfG Discussion Paper 02/5, http://www.mpi-fg-koeln. mpg.de (2002); and Wolfgang Streeck and Kozo Yamamura, "Introduction: Convergence or Diversity? Stability and Change in German and Japanese Capitalism," in Kozo Yamamura and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese Capitalism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(2003)
The End of Diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese Capitalism
-
-
Streeck, W.1
Yamamura, K.2
-
15
-
-
0002594332
-
Learning by monitoring: The institutions of economic development
-
Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1994)
Handbook of Economic Sociology
-
-
Sabel, C.F.1
-
16
-
-
0002718177
-
Stories, strategies, structures: Rethinking historical alternatives to mass production
-
Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1997)
World of Possibilities
-
-
Sabel, C.F.1
Zeitlin, J.2
-
17
-
-
0030463090
-
Recombinant property in eastern European capitalism
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1996)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.4
, pp. 993-1027
-
-
Stark, D.1
-
18
-
-
0003892325
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1998)
Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe
-
-
Stark, D.1
Bruszt, L.2
-
19
-
-
0039323933
-
Discursive cartels: Uniform cost accounting among American manufacturers before the new deal
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1997)
Business and Economic History
, vol.1
, pp. 229-251
-
-
Berk, G.1
-
20
-
-
46249114323
-
-
trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1996)
The Creativity of Action
-
-
Joas, H.1
-
21
-
-
0002902691
-
A theory of structure: Duality, agency, and transformation
-
July
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(1992)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.98
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-29
-
-
Sewell Jr., W.H.1
-
22
-
-
0242523411
-
-
New York: Verso
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(2003)
Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance
-
-
Fung, A.1
Wright, E.O.2
-
23
-
-
14544280054
-
-
chap. 1 unpublished ms.
-
Charles F. Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development," in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., Handbook of Economic Sociology (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); Charles F. Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures: Rethinking Historical Alternatives to Mass Production," in Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997); David Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1996): 993-1027; David Stark and Laszlo Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 1 (1997): 229-51; Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, trans. Jeremy Gaines and Paul Keast (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1996); William H. Sewell Jr., "A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation," American Journal of Sociology 98, no. 1 (July 1992): 1-29; and Archon Fung and Erik Olin Wright, Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance (New York: Verso, 2003). For a more extended discussion, see Gerald Berk, American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2004).
-
(2004)
American Possibilities: Brandeis, Antitrust and Trade Associations, 1890-1935
-
-
Berk, G.1
-
24
-
-
0004130112
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1977)
The Visible Hand
-
-
Chandler Jr., A.D.1
-
25
-
-
0004203461
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1990)
Scale and Scope
-
-
Chandler Jr., A.D.1
-
26
-
-
0002187515
-
The rise of the modern industrial enterprise: A new perspective
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1980)
Managerial Hierarchies
-
-
Daems, H.1
-
27
-
-
0039157918
-
The pluralist state: American economic regulation in comparative perspective, 1900-1930
-
Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Boston: Harvard Business School Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1981)
Regulation in Perspective
-
-
Keller, M.1
-
28
-
-
0003736594
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1984)
Prophets of Regulation
-
-
McCraw, T.K.1
-
29
-
-
0003839975
-
-
New York: Basic Books
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1984)
The Second Industrial Divide
-
-
Piore, M.1
Sabel, C.F.2
-
30
-
-
84972090867
-
Industrial concentration, Sectional competition and anti-trust politics in America
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1986)
Studies in American Political Development
, vol.1
, pp. 142-214
-
-
Sanders, E.1
-
31
-
-
0004216144
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1990)
The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring
-
-
Best, M.1
-
32
-
-
0004235878
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1900)
The Transformation of Corporate Control
-
-
Fligstein, N.1
-
33
-
-
0003948709
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1994)
Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia
-
-
Dunlavy, C.A.1
-
34
-
-
0003531051
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(1997)
Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation
-
-
Roy, W.G.1
-
35
-
-
14544301264
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Alfred D. Chandler Jr., The Visible Hand (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1977); Alfred D. Chandler Jr., Scale and Scope (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990); Herman Daems, "The Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise: A New Perspective," in Alfred D. Chandler Jr. and Herman Daems, eds., Managerial Hierarchies (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980); Morton Keller, "The Pluralist State: American Economic Regulation in Comparative Perspective, 1900-1930," in Thomas K. McCraw, ed., Regulation in Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1981); Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1984); Michael Piore and Charles F. Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1984); Elizabeth Sanders, "Industrial Concentration, Sectional Competition and Anti-Trust Politics in America," Studies in American Political Development 1 (1986), 142-214; Michael Best, The New Competition: Institutions of Industrial Restructuring (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Neil Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1900); Colleen A. Dunlavy, Politics and Industrialization: Early Railroads in the United States and Prussia (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1994); William G. Roy, Socializing Capital: The Rise of the Large Industrial Corporation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997); and Charles Perrow, Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002).
-
(2002)
Organizing America and Concentrating Power in the Nineteenth Century
-
-
Perrow, C.1
-
36
-
-
0039324002
-
-
For reviews, see Berk, "Communities of Competitors"; Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions"; and M. Schneiberg, "It Can - And Did - Happen Here: Association and Inter-Firm competition in the American Fire Insurance Industry," paper presented at
-
Communities of Competitors
-
-
Berk1
-
37
-
-
14544293801
-
-
For reviews, see Berk, "Communities of Competitors"; Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions"; and M. Schneiberg, "It Can - And Did - Happen Here: Association and Inter-Firm competition in the American Fire Insurance Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Madison, Wisconsin, July 1999.
-
Political and Institutional Conditions
-
-
Schneiberg1
-
38
-
-
14544279612
-
-
paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Madison, Wisconsin, July
-
For reviews, see Berk, "Communities of Competitors"; Schneiberg, "Political and Institutional Conditions"; and M. Schneiberg, "It Can - And Did - Happen Here: Association and Inter-Firm competition in the American Fire Insurance Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Madison, Wisconsin, July 1999.
-
(1999)
It Can - and Did - Happen Here: Association and Inter-Firm Competition in the American Fire Insurance Industry
-
-
Schneiberg, M.1
-
39
-
-
0004130112
-
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
The Visible Hand
-
-
Chandler1
-
40
-
-
0003416615
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
(1989)
Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry
-
-
Bowman, J.R.1
-
41
-
-
0003531998
-
-
New York: Free Press
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
(1985)
The Economic Institutions of Capitalism
-
-
Williamson, O.E.1
-
42
-
-
0002969712
-
The logic of coordinating American manufacturing sectors
-
John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
(1991)
Governance of the American Economy
-
-
Hollingsworth, J.R.1
-
43
-
-
0004063615
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
(1988)
The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism
-
-
Sklar, M.J.1
-
44
-
-
0003497226
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Chandler, The Visible Hand; John R. Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Oliver E. Williamson, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: Free Press, 1985); J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Logic of Coordinating American Manufacturing Sectors," in John L. Campbell, J. Rogers Hollingsworth, and Leon L. Lindberg, eds., Governance of the American Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Martin J. Sklar, The Corporate Reconstruction of American Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988); and Colin Gordon, New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994).
-
(1994)
New Deals: Business, Labor, and Politics in America, 1920-1935
-
-
Gordon, C.1
-
45
-
-
0004015966
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
(1985)
The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904
-
-
Lamoreaux, N.1
-
46
-
-
0000205713
-
Can transaction cost economics explain trade associations?
-
Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., London: Sage
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
(1990)
The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties
-
-
Schneiberg, M.1
Hollingsworth, J.R.2
-
47
-
-
0003699515
-
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
New Competition
-
-
Best1
-
48
-
-
0004235878
-
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
The Transformation of Corporate Control
-
-
Fligstein1
-
49
-
-
0004350483
-
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
Socializing Capital
-
-
Roy1
-
50
-
-
0033724621
-
The market that anti-trust built
-
Naomi Lamoreaux, The Great Merger Wave in American Business, 1895-1904 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985); Marc Schneiberg and J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?" in Masahiko Aoki, Bo Gustufson, and Oliver E. Williamson, eds., The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties (London: Sage, 1990); Best, New Competition; Fligstein, The Transformation of Corporate Control; Roy, Socializing Capital; and Frank Dobbin and Timothy J. Dowd, "The Market That Anti-Trust Built," American Sociological Review 65 (2000): 631-57.
-
(2000)
American Sociological Review
, vol.65
, pp. 631-657
-
-
Dobbin, F.1
Dowd, T.J.2
-
51
-
-
0004028395
-
-
New York: Free Press
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1963)
The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916
-
-
Kolko, G.1
-
52
-
-
0004212581
-
-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1970)
Airline Regulation in America
-
-
Jordan, W.A.1
-
53
-
-
0000456233
-
The Theory of Economic Regulation
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1971)
Bell Journal of Economics
, vol.2
, Issue.1
, pp. 3-21
-
-
Stigler, G.J.1
-
54
-
-
14544267443
-
-
Washington, D.C.: American Institute
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1977)
Federal-state Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance
-
-
McAvoy, P.W.1
-
55
-
-
70350140221
-
Cartels, collusion and horizontal merger
-
Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Amsterdam: Elsevier Science
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1989)
Handbook of Industrial Organization
, vol.1
-
-
Jaquemin, A.1
Slade, M.2
-
56
-
-
0000068117
-
The effects of economic regulation
-
Schmalansee and Willig, eds.
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
Handbook of Industrial Organization
, vol.1
-
-
Joskow, P.1
Rose, N.2
-
57
-
-
0003904260
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservativism, 1900-1916 (New York: Free Press, 1963); William A. Jordan, Airline Regulation in America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1970); George J. Stigler, "The Theory of Economic Regulation," Bell Journal of Economics 2, no. 1 (1971): 3-21; Paul W. McAvoy, Federal-State Regulation of the Pricing and Marketing of Insurance (Washington, D.C.: American Institute, 1977); A. Jaquemin and M. Slade, "Cartels, Collusion and Horizontal Merger," in Richard Schmalansee and Robert D. Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1 (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, 1989); Paul Joskow and N. Rose, "The Effects of Economic Regulation," in Schmalansee and Willig, eds., Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 1; Richard H. K. Victor, Contrived Competition (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1994).
-
(1994)
Contrived Competition
-
-
Victor, R.H.K.1
-
58
-
-
84928218561
-
The politics of the market: Economic competition and the organization of capitalists
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(1985)
Political Power and Social Theory
, vol.5
, pp. 35-88
-
-
Bowman, J.R.1
-
59
-
-
0003416615
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(1989)
Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry
-
-
Bowman, J.1
-
60
-
-
84871267619
-
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
New Deals
-
-
Gordon1
-
61
-
-
0010524222
-
-
Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(2002)
Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden
-
-
Swenson, P.A.1
-
62
-
-
0009649283
-
Employers, public policy, and the politics of decentralized cooperation in Germany and France
-
Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(2001)
Varieties of Capitalism: the Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage
, pp. 275-307
-
-
Culpepper, P.D.1
-
63
-
-
0011825683
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
John R. Bowman, "The Politics of the Market: Economic Competition and the Organization of Capitalists," Political Power and Social Theory 5 (1985): 35-88; John Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action: Competition, Cooperation and Conflict in the Coal Industry (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989); Gordon, New Deals; Peter A. Swenson, Capitalists against Markets: The Making of Labor Markets and Welfare States in the United States and Sweden (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002); Pepper D. Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France," in Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), 275-307; and Pepper D. Culpepper, Creating Cooperation: How States Develop Human Capital in Europe (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2003).
-
(2003)
Creating Cooperation: how States Develop Human Capital in Europe
-
-
Culpepper, P.D.1
-
64
-
-
14544278233
-
-
Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; and Stark and Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways, 8-11, 111-12, 129-36. For a more general discussion of the role of associations in contemporary capitalist democracy, see Joshua Cohen and Joel Rogers, Associations and Democracy (New York: Verso, 1995).
-
Learning by Monitoring
-
-
Sabel1
-
65
-
-
0003573012
-
-
Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; and Stark and Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways, 8-11, 111-12, 129-36. For a more general discussion of the role of associations in contemporary capitalist democracy, see Joshua Cohen and Joel Rogers, Associations and Democracy (New York: Verso, 1995).
-
Postsocialist Pathways
, pp. 8-11
-
-
Stark1
Bruszt2
-
66
-
-
0004222577
-
-
New York: Verso
-
Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; and Stark and Bruszt, Postsocialist Pathways, 8-11, 111-12, 129-36. For a more general discussion of the role of associations in contemporary capitalist democracy, see Joshua Cohen and Joel Rogers, Associations and Democracy (New York: Verso, 1995).
-
(1995)
Associations and Democracy
-
-
Cohen, J.1
Rogers, J.2
-
67
-
-
0000953669
-
The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1983)
American Sociological Review
, vol.48
, pp. 147-160
-
-
Dimaggio, P.J.1
Powell, W.W.2
-
68
-
-
0002351758
-
Introduction
-
Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1991)
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis
, pp. 1-40
-
-
Dimaggio, P.1
Powell, W.W.2
-
69
-
-
0003435635
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1994)
Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age
-
-
Dobbin, F.1
-
70
-
-
0031419318
-
World society and the nation state
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1997)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.103
, pp. 1441-1481
-
-
Meyer, J.1
Boli, J.2
-
71
-
-
84937286804
-
The individualist polity and the prevalence of professionalized psychology: A cross national study
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1995)
American Sociological Review
, vol.60
, pp. 360-377
-
-
Frank, D.J.1
Meyer, J.2
Miyahara, D.3
-
72
-
-
0031423329
-
World culture and world polity: A century of international non-governmental organizations
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1997)
American Sociological Review
, vol.62
, pp. 171-190
-
-
Boli, J.1
Thomas, G.M.2
-
73
-
-
0002769727
-
Divergent production regimes: Coordinated and uncoordinated market economies in the 1980s and 1990s
-
Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1999)
Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism
-
-
Soskice, D.1
-
74
-
-
0001902793
-
An introduction to varieties of capitalism
-
Hall and Soskice, eds.
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
Varieties of Capitalism
, pp. 1-68
-
-
Hall, P.A.1
Soskice, D.2
-
75
-
-
0000355441
-
Continuities and changes in social systems of production: The cases of Japan, Germany and the United States
-
J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1997)
Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions
, pp. 265-310
-
-
Hollingsworth, J.R.1
-
76
-
-
0042124262
-
The institutional embeddedness of American capitalism
-
Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., London: Sage
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1997)
Political Economy of Modern Capitalism
, pp. 132-147
-
-
Hollingsworth, J.R.1
-
77
-
-
0001893551
-
Coordination of economic actors and social systems of production
-
Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds.
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
Contemporary Capitalism
, pp. 1-47
-
-
Hollingsworth, J.R.1
Boyer, R.2
-
78
-
-
0037482658
-
The distinctiveness of Japan
-
Crouch and Streeck, eds.
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
Political Economy of Modern Capitalism
, pp. 21-32
-
-
Dore, R.1
-
79
-
-
84949854280
-
Varieties of capitalism
-
Richard Whitley, ed., Oxford: Oxford University Press
-
On arguments about isomorphism, diffusion and the national industrial cultures, see Paul J. DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields," American Sociological Review 48 ( 1983): 147-60; Paul DiMaggio and Walter W. Powell, "Introduction," in Walter Powell and Paul DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), 1-40; Frank Dobbin, Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railway Age (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994); John Meyer, John Boli, et al., "World Society and the Nation State," American Journal of Sociology 103 (1997): 1441-81; David John Frank, John Meyer, and David Miyahara, "The Individualist Polity and the Prevalence of Professionalized Psychology: A Cross National Study," American Sociological Review 60 (1995): 360-77; and John Boli and George M. Thomas, "World Culture and World Polity: A Century of International Non-Governmental Organizations," American Sociological Review 62 (1997): 171-90. On the arguments about complementarities and interlock, see, David Soskice, "Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s," in Herbert Kitschelt, ed., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Peter A. Hall and David Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," in Hall and Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism, 1-68; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "Continuities and Changes in Social Systems of Production: The Cases of Japan, Germany and the United States," in J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism: The Embeddedness of Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997), 265-310; J. Rogers Hollingsworth, "The Institutional Embeddedness of American Capitalism," in Colin Crouch and Wolfgang Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism (London: Sage, 1997), 132-47; J. Rogers Hollingsworth and Robert Boyer, "Coordination of Economic Actors and Social Systems of Production," in Hollingsworth and Boyer, eds., Contemporary Capitalism, 1-47; Ronald Dore, "The Distinctiveness of Japan," in Crouch and Streeck, eds., Political Economy of Modern Capitalism, 21-32; and Richard Whitley, "Varieties of Capitalism," in Richard Whitley, ed., Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999).
-
(1999)
Divergent Capitalisms: The Social Structuring and Change of Business Systems
-
-
Whitley, R.1
-
81
-
-
0039024177
-
-
New York: Appleton
-
Arthur Jerome Eddy, The New Competition (New York: Appleton, 1912), 100-1.
-
(1912)
The New Competition
, pp. 100-101
-
-
Eddy, A.J.1
-
82
-
-
14544293825
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
The Politics of the Market
, pp. 51
-
-
Bowman1
-
83
-
-
0003416615
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Capitalist Collective Action
-
-
Bowman1
-
84
-
-
84871267619
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade
-
New Deals
-
-
Gordon1
-
85
-
-
0010524222
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Capitalists against Markets.
-
-
Swenson1
-
86
-
-
0001709216
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism
, pp. 9-12
-
-
Hall1
Soskice2
-
87
-
-
0009649283
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France
-
-
Culpepper1
-
88
-
-
0011825683
-
-
See Bowman, "The Politics of the Market," 51, where he writes, When direct communication is impossible [because of antitrust], trade associations or similar institutions can perform a clearing house function and collect and disseminate "average" past prices or current prices, which, with very little imagination, can be transformed into current minimum prices. The same end can be achieved through the circulation of studies, which calculate "average" or "typical" costs. A more subtle method of communicating cost (and price) data among competing firms is through "cost education"-making sure that capitalists know all of their costs and circulating rules of thumb that tend to equalize costs (at a relatively high level) throughout an industry. See also Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; and Swenson, Capitalists against Markets. For a more general appeal to conceptualize business associations within an institutionally situated game theory approach as mechanisms to thicken expectations and otherwise solve coordination problems via information, see Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism," 9-12; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Creating Cooperation.
-
-
Culpepper1
-
90
-
-
0039024177
-
-
(italics in original).
-
Eddy, The New Competition, 148 (italics in original).
-
The New Competition
, pp. 148
-
-
Eddy1
-
91
-
-
14544277364
-
-
U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, (hereafter cited as CofC, March)
-
See J. H. Foy, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, 84-87 (hereafter cited as CofC, March 1924); Robert Belt, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. # 1960, 4-5 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1923); Austin Cheney, CofC, March 1924, 92; "7th International Cost Conference," National Association of Cost Accountants, NACA Yearbook, 1926 (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1921), 34 (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year); and George N. Voorhees, "The Story of Production Records," Typotehtae Bulletin 21, no. 17 (July 27, 1925): 281.
-
(1924)
Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924
, pp. 84-87
-
-
Foy, J.H.1
-
92
-
-
14544293375
-
-
U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. # 1960, (hereafter cited as CofC, October)
-
See J. H. Foy, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, 84-87 (hereafter cited as CofC, March 1924); Robert Belt, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. # 1960, 4-5 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1923); Austin Cheney, CofC, March 1924, 92; "7th International Cost Conference," National Association of Cost Accountants, NACA Yearbook, 1926 (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1921), 34 (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year); and George N. Voorhees, "The Story of Production Records," Typotehtae Bulletin 21, no. 17 (July 27, 1925): 281.
-
(1923)
Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923
, pp. 4-5
-
-
Belt, R.1
-
93
-
-
14544288488
-
-
March
-
See J. H. Foy, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, 84-87 (hereafter cited as CofC, March 1924); Robert Belt, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. # 1960, 4-5 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1923); Austin Cheney, CofC, March 1924, 92; "7th International Cost Conference," National Association of Cost Accountants, NACA Yearbook, 1926 (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1921), 34 (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year); and George N. Voorhees, "The Story of Production Records," Typotehtae Bulletin 21, no. 17 (July 27, 1925): 281.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 92
-
-
Cheney, A.1
-
94
-
-
14544301265
-
7th International cost conference
-
National Association of Cost Accountants, (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants), (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year)
-
See J. H. Foy, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, 84-87 (hereafter cited as CofC, March 1924); Robert Belt, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. # 1960, 4-5 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1923); Austin Cheney, CofC, March 1924, 92; "7th International Cost Conference," National Association of Cost Accountants, NACA Yearbook, 1926 (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1921), 34 (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year); and George N. Voorhees, "The Story of Production Records," Typotehtae Bulletin 21, no. 17 (July 27, 1925): 281.
-
(1921)
NACA Yearbook, 1926
, pp. 34
-
-
-
95
-
-
14544295979
-
The story of production records
-
July 27
-
See J. H. Foy, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York City, March 25-26, 1924, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, 84-87 (hereafter cited as CofC, March 1924); Robert Belt, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 23, 1923, U.S. Chamber of Commerce Papers, Ace. 3 1960, 4-5 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1923); Austin Cheney, CofC, March 1924, 92; "7th International Cost Conference," National Association of Cost Accountants, NACA Yearbook, 1926 (New York: National Association of Cost Accountants, 1921), 34 (hereafter cited as NACA Yearbook with year); and George N. Voorhees, "The Story of Production Records," Typotehtae Bulletin 21, no. 17 (July 27, 1925): 281.
-
(1925)
Typotehtae Bulletin
, vol.21
, Issue.17
, pp. 281
-
-
Voorhees, G.N.1
-
97
-
-
14544289831
-
-
Hagley Museum and Library, Papers of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Ace. # 1960 (hereafter cited as CofC, October)
-
Uniform Cost Accounting Conference held at Congress Hotel, Chicago, Illinois, October 28-29, 1924, 81, Hagley Museum and Library, Papers of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, Ace. # 1960 (hereafter cited as CofC, October 1924).
-
(1924)
Uniform Cost Accounting Conference Held at Congress Hotel, Chicago, Illinois, October 28-29, 1924
, vol.81
-
-
-
98
-
-
14544292319
-
-
note
-
Understanding the sources, character, and consequence of this policy reflexivity is the topic for another article. Here we simply want to document how antitrust authorities came to embrace collaborative learning and developmental associations.
-
-
-
-
101
-
-
14544272167
-
The reason for cost accounting
-
Nelson B. Gaskill, "The Reason for Cost Accounting," NACA Yearbook 1926, 21-24; Nelson B. Gaskill, chairman, Federal Trade Commission, "Some Aspects of Price Cut-ting," address to National Wholesale Grocers, June 8, 1922, 3, Federal Trade Commission Library.
-
NACA Yearbook 1926
, pp. 21-24
-
-
Gaskill, N.B.1
-
102
-
-
14544284374
-
-
address to National Wholesale Grocers, June 8, Federal Trade Commission Library
-
Nelson B. Gaskill, "The Reason for Cost Accounting," NACA Yearbook 1926, 21-24; Nelson B. Gaskill, chairman, Federal Trade Commission, "Some Aspects of Price Cut-ting," address to National Wholesale Grocers, June 8, 1922, 3, Federal Trade Commission Library.
-
(1922)
Some Aspects of Price Cut-ting
, pp. 3
-
-
Gaskill, N.B.1
-
103
-
-
14544279629
-
-
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office
-
See Federal Trade Commission, Fundamentals of a Cost System for Manufacturers (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1916); and Federal Trade Commission, "Helpful Activities to Strengthen American Business," January 1916, NARA, RG122, Box 3390, Act 5, Gov 5.
-
(1916)
Fundamentals of a Cost System for Manufacturers
-
-
-
104
-
-
0011462282
-
-
January NARA, RG122, Box 3390, Act 5, Gov 5
-
See Federal Trade Commission, Fundamentals of a Cost System for Manufacturers (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1916); and Federal Trade Commission, "Helpful Activities to Strengthen American Business," January 1916, NARA, RG122, Box 3390, Act 5, Gov 5.
-
(1916)
Helpful Activities to Strengthen American Business
-
-
-
105
-
-
0039323933
-
Discursive cartels: Uniform cost accounting among american manufacturers before the new deal
-
Fall
-
Gerald Berk, "Discursive Cartels: Uniform Cost Accounting among American Manufacturers before the New Deal," Business and Economic History 26, no. 1 (Fall 1997): 229-51.
-
(1997)
Business and Economic History
, vol.26
, Issue.1
, pp. 229-251
-
-
Berk, G.1
-
106
-
-
14544299065
-
-
March
-
See address of NACA's second president, CofC March 1924, 51-57.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 51-57
-
-
-
107
-
-
14544295179
-
-
For discussions among the accountants of the importance of associational systems, see NACA Yearbook, 1921, 13-14, 39; NACA Yearbook, 1922, 16; and NACA Yearbook, 1923, 14, 19-20.
-
NACA Yearbook, 1921
, pp. 13-14
-
-
-
108
-
-
14544277347
-
-
For discussions among the accountants of the importance of associational systems, see NACA Yearbook, 1921, 13-14, 39; NACA Yearbook, 1922, 16; and NACA Yearbook, 1923, 14, 19-20.
-
NACA Yearbook, 1922
, pp. 16
-
-
-
109
-
-
14544274396
-
-
For discussions among the accountants of the importance of associational systems, see NACA Yearbook, 1921, 13-14, 39; NACA Yearbook, 1922, 16; and NACA Yearbook, 1923, 14, 19-20.
-
NACA Yearbook, 1923
, pp. 14
-
-
-
110
-
-
14544294706
-
The new umpires of american business
-
and "The National Chamber Appoints a Cooperating Committee," April 15
-
On the Chamber of Commerce, see "The New Umpires of American Business," and "The National Chamber Appoints a Cooperating Committee," Nation's Business (April 15, 1915): 7-8; and "Report of the Federal Trade Committee," Chamber of Commerce, Minutes of the Fourth Annual Meeting, 1916, 138, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, Box 2.
-
(1915)
Nation's Business
, pp. 7-8
-
-
-
111
-
-
14544291805
-
Report of the federal trade committee
-
Chamber of Commerce, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. 1960, Box 2
-
On the Chamber of Commerce, see "The New Umpires of American Business," and "The National Chamber Appoints a Cooperating Committee," Nation's Business (April 15, 1915): 7-8; and "Report of the Federal Trade Committee," Chamber of Commerce, Minutes of the Fourth Annual Meeting, 1916, 138, Hagley Museum and Library, Ace. # 1960, Box 2.
-
(1916)
Minutes of the Fourth Annual Meeting
, pp. 138
-
-
-
112
-
-
14544282245
-
-
October
-
CofC, October 1923, 87-91; CofC, March 1924, 3-5; and CofC, October 1924,57-59.
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 87-91
-
-
-
113
-
-
14544276671
-
-
March
-
CofC, October 1923, 87-91; CofC, March 1924, 3-5; and CofC, October 1924,57-59.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 3-5
-
-
-
114
-
-
14544267939
-
-
October
-
CofC, October 1923, 87-91; CofC, March 1924, 3-5; and CofC, October 1924,57-59.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 57-59
-
-
-
115
-
-
14544293825
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Politics of the Market
-
-
Bowman1
-
116
-
-
0003416615
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Capitalist Collective Action
-
-
Bowman1
-
117
-
-
84871267619
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
New Deals
-
-
Gordon1
-
118
-
-
0010524222
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Capitalists against Markets
-
-
Swenson1
-
119
-
-
0001709216
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"
-
-
Hall1
Soskice2
-
120
-
-
14544302055
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation
-
-
Culpepper1
-
121
-
-
0011825683
-
-
Bowman, "Politics of the Market"; Bowman, Capitalist Collective Action; Gordon, New Deals; Swenson, Capitalists against Markets; Hall and Soskice, "An Introduction to Varieties of Capitalism"; Culpepper, "Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics of Decentralized Cooperation"; and Culpepper, Creating Cooperation.
-
Creating Cooperation.
-
-
Culpepper1
-
122
-
-
14544288041
-
-
October
-
S. V. Dunkel, CofC, October 1923, 14-17.
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 14-17
-
-
Dunkel, S.V.1
-
123
-
-
14544286217
-
The results of twelve month's intensive work in the milk industry
-
October
-
R. E. Little, "The Results of Twelve Month's Intensive Work in the Milk Industry," CofC, October 1923, 3-4.
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 3-4
-
-
Little, R.E.1
-
124
-
-
14544288041
-
-
October
-
S. V. Dunkel, CofC, October 1923, 14-17.
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 14-17
-
-
Dunkel, S.V.1
-
125
-
-
14544298142
-
-
New York: American Institute Publishing
-
Eric A. Camman, Basic Standard Costs (New York: American Institute Publishing, 1932), 34-35. For evidence of Camman's vice presidency, see NACA letter to Cost Accounting Unit of the Research and Planning Division of the NRA, RG 9, Entry 256, Box 1.
-
(1932)
Basic Standard Costs
, pp. 34-35
-
-
Camman, E.A.1
-
127
-
-
14544282730
-
-
October
-
For the experience in Portland Cement, see CofC, October 1923, 34; in paper boxes, see CofC, October 1924, 70;
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 34
-
-
-
128
-
-
14544288057
-
-
October
-
For the experience in Portland Cement, see CofC, October 1923, 34; in paper boxes, see CofC, October 1924, 70;
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 70
-
-
-
129
-
-
14544269261
-
-
chairman of the Cost Committee of the National Association of Cotton Finishers, March
-
in cotton finishing, see G. A. McClatchie, chairman of the Cost Committee of the National Association of Cotton Finishers, CofC, March 1924, 152-55;
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 152-155
-
-
McClatchie, G.A.1
-
130
-
-
14544302971
-
Section E-cost accounting committees
-
chairman of the Committee on Costs of the American Foundrymen's Association, October
-
in foundries, see W. B. Greenlee, chairman of the Committee on Costs of the American Foundrymen's Association, "Section E-Cost Accounting Committees," CofC, October 1923, 6;
-
(1923)
CofC
, pp. 6
-
-
Greenlee, W.B.1
-
131
-
-
14544294252
-
-
March
-
in tents and awnings, see CofC, March 1924, 175-77;
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 175-177
-
-
-
132
-
-
14544273972
-
-
October
-
and in photo engraving, see CofC, October 1924, 66-67.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 66-67
-
-
-
133
-
-
14544274415
-
The future of trade association cost work
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Future of Trade Association Cost Work," NACA Year-book, 1923, 297-98; Ronald Zinn, CofC, March 1924, 113-14; and T. J. Bolitho, International Milk Dealers' Association, CofC, October 1924, 20.
-
NACA Year-book, 1923
, pp. 297-298
-
-
Stevenson, C.R.1
-
134
-
-
14544300361
-
-
March
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Future of Trade Association Cost Work," NACA Year-book, 1923, 297-98; Ronald Zinn, CofC, March 1924, 113-14; and T. J. Bolitho, International Milk Dealers' Association, CofC, October 1924, 20.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 113-114
-
-
Zinn, R.1
-
135
-
-
14544292317
-
-
International Milk Dealers' Association, October
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Future of Trade Association Cost Work," NACA Year-book, 1923, 297-98; Ronald Zinn, CofC, March 1924, 113-14; and T. J. Bolitho, International Milk Dealers' Association, CofC, October 1924, 20.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 20
-
-
Bolitho, T.J.1
-
136
-
-
14544300374
-
-
October vice president of the Printing Ink Cost Bureau
-
On the use of loose-leaf binders, see George J. Warmbold Jr., vice president of the Printing Ink Cost Bureau, CofC, October 1924, 5-11.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 5-11
-
-
Warmbold Jr., G.J.1
-
137
-
-
14544293823
-
-
director, Cost Accounting & Statistical Department, American Photo-Engravers' Assn., March
-
W. B. Lawrence, director, Cost Accounting & Statistical Department, American Photo-Engravers' Assn., CofC, March 1924, 24.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 24
-
-
Lawrence, W.B.1
-
138
-
-
14544293823
-
-
director, Cost Accounting & Statistical Department, American Photo-Engravers' Assn., March
-
W. B. Lawrence, director, Cost Accounting & Statistical Department, American Photo-Engravers' Assn., CofC, March 1924, 24.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 24
-
-
Lawrence, W.B.1
-
139
-
-
14544307241
-
-
Newsprint Service Bureau, March
-
G. A. Ware, Newsprint Service Bureau, CofC, March 1924, 166-172.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 166-172
-
-
Ware, G.A.1
-
140
-
-
14544274415
-
The future of trade association cost work
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Future of Trade Association Cost Work," NACA Yearbook, 1923, 297-301; and Stevenson's 1926 address before ATAE on Standard Costs.
-
NACA Yearbook, 1923
, pp. 297-301
-
-
Stevenson, C.R.1
-
141
-
-
14544282261
-
-
Stevenson's 1926 address before ATAE on Standard Costs.
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Future of Trade Association Cost Work," NACA Yearbook, 1923, 297-301; and Stevenson's 1926 address before ATAE on Standard Costs.
-
-
-
-
142
-
-
14544290824
-
-
Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office
-
Cited in U.S. Federal Trade Commission, Report on Open Price Associations (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1929), 12.
-
(1929)
Report on Open Price Associations
, pp. 12
-
-
-
143
-
-
14544276916
-
The economic effect of taking business at or below cost
-
Charles R. Stevenson, "The Economic Effect of Taking Business at or Below Cost," NACA Yearbook, 1927, 25.
-
NACA Yearbook, 1927
, pp. 25
-
-
Stevenson, C.R.1
-
145
-
-
14544298606
-
-
May National Archives and Records Administration (NARA), RG122, Box 216, File 2/459-2
-
UTA Department of Industrial Information, "Economic and Industrial Relations Background," May 1922, National Archives and Records Administration (NARA), RG122, Box 216, File 2/459-2.
-
(1922)
Economic and Industrial Relations Background
-
-
-
147
-
-
14544291317
-
-
May
-
Leona M. Powell, The History of the United Typothetae of American (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1926). See also Typographical Journal 36, no. 5 (May 1910): 612.
-
(1910)
Typographical Journal
, vol.36
, Issue.5
, pp. 612
-
-
-
149
-
-
14544301277
-
The value of the standard cost finding system to management
-
November 17, quote on 233, emphasis added
-
W. R. Ashe, "The Value of the Standard Cost Finding System to Management," Typothetae Bulletin 32, no. 7 (November 17, 1930): 231 -34, quote on 233, emphasis added.
-
(1930)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.32
, Issue.7
, pp. 231-234
-
-
Ashe, W.R.1
-
150
-
-
14544274414
-
-
Chicago: United Typothetae of America
-
On Form 9-H, see Elmer J. Koch, The Standard Book on Cost Finding for Printers (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1928), 31-33; United Typothetae of America, United Typothetae Standard Cost Finding System (Chicago: UTA, 1927), 6-19, 24-25; "Resolutions Submitted by the Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1913), 107-8.
-
(1928)
The Standard Book on Cost Finding for Printers
, pp. 31-33
-
-
Koch, E.J.1
-
151
-
-
84926209061
-
-
Chicago: UTA
-
On Form 9-H, see Elmer J. Koch, The Standard Book on Cost Finding for Printers (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1928), 31-33; United Typothetae of America, United Typothetae Standard Cost Finding System (Chicago: UTA, 1927), 6-19, 24-25; "Resolutions Submitted by the Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1913), 107-8.
-
(1927)
United Typothetae Standard Cost Finding System
, pp. 6-19
-
-
-
152
-
-
14544281359
-
Resolutions submitted by the cost commission
-
Chicago: United Typothetae of America
-
On Form 9-H, see Elmer J. Koch, The Standard Book on Cost Finding for Printers (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1928), 31-33; United Typothetae of America, United Typothetae Standard Cost Finding System (Chicago: UTA, 1927), 6-19, 24-25; "Resolutions Submitted by the Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1913), 107-8.
-
(1913)
Proceedings of the Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America
, pp. 107-108
-
-
-
153
-
-
14544280069
-
Exposition of the standard cost finding system
-
Chicago: American Printers' Cost Commission
-
On departmentalization, see F. I. Ellick, Omaha (member of cost commission), "Exposition of the Standard Cost Finding System," in Proceedings of the Second International Cost Congress of Employing Printers of America (Chicago: American Printers' Cost Commission, 1910), 76-84; and F. I. Ellick, "Cost Accounting," Typographical Journal 44, no. 1 (January 1914): 11.
-
(1910)
Proceedings of the Second International Cost Congress of Employing Printers of America
, pp. 76-84
-
-
Ellick, F.I.1
Omaha2
-
154
-
-
14544279179
-
Cost accounting
-
January
-
On departmentalization, see F. I. Ellick, Omaha (member of cost commission), "Exposition of the Standard Cost Finding System," in Proceedings of the Second International Cost Congress of Employing Printers of America (Chicago: American Printers' Cost Commission, 1910), 76-84; and F. I. Ellick, "Cost Accounting," Typographical Journal 44, no. 1 (January 1914): 11.
-
(1914)
Typographical Journal
, vol.44
, Issue.1
, pp. 11
-
-
Ellick, F.I.1
-
155
-
-
14544308162
-
-
On product costing, or the "productive hour method," see F. I. Ellick, "The Results a Cost System Should Bring," in Proceedings of the Twenty-fourth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae of America, 1910 (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1910).
-
Productive Hour Method
-
-
-
158
-
-
14544308163
-
-
National Archives, NARA, RG122, Box 217, File 3 459-2-1
-
On the use of "fillers," see Testimony of Frank W. Fillmore in Hearings re: FTC v. UTA, National Archives, NARA, RG122, Box 217, File # 459-2-1, 1055, 1062-63. On stationery and other sales taken at a loss, see Ellick, "The Results a Cost System Should Bring."
-
Hearings Re: FTC V. UTA
, pp. 1055
-
-
Fillmore, F.W.1
-
159
-
-
14544272628
-
-
On the use of "fillers," see Testimony of Frank W. Fillmore in Hearings re: FTC v. UTA, National Archives, NARA, RG122, Box 217, File # 459-2-1, 1055, 1062-63. On stationery and other sales taken at a loss, see Ellick, "The Results a Cost System Should Bring."
-
The Results a Cost System Should Bring
-
-
Ellick1
-
160
-
-
14544273086
-
Departmental cost analysis
-
Chicago: United Typothetae of America
-
Mabel H. Dwyer, "Departmental Cost Analysis," in Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1930); also in Typothetae Bulletin 32, no. 3 (October 27, 1930): 100-3.
-
(1930)
Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA
-
-
Dwyer, M.H.1
-
161
-
-
14544275332
-
-
October 27
-
Mabel H. Dwyer, "Departmental Cost Analysis," in Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1930); also in Typothetae Bulletin 32, no. 3 (October 27, 1930): 100-3.
-
(1930)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.32
, Issue.3
, pp. 100-103
-
-
-
162
-
-
14544306350
-
-
Powell, History of the UTA, 168-73; and Proceedings of the Thirtieth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1916), 45-46.
-
History of the UTA
, pp. 168-173
-
-
Powell1
-
164
-
-
14544306350
-
-
Powell, History of the UTA, 168-73; and Proceedings of the Thirtieth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1916), 45-46.
-
History of the UTA
, pp. 168-173
-
-
Powell1
-
166
-
-
14544296879
-
The use of production records: How interest in records work has spread-necessity of accurate estimating-typothetae production records provide accurate efficiency gauge
-
Chicago: United Typothetae of America
-
George N. Voorhees, "The Use of Production Records: How Interest in Records Work has Spread-Necessity of Accurate Estimating-Typothetae Production Records Provide Accurate Efficiency Gauge," in Proceedings of the Thirty-ninth Annual Convention (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1925); also in Typothetae Bulletin (October 26, 1925): 136.
-
(1925)
Proceedings of the Thirty-ninth Annual Convention
-
-
Voorhees, G.N.1
-
167
-
-
14544297699
-
-
October 26
-
George N. Voorhees, "The Use of Production Records: How Interest in Records Work has Spread-Necessity of Accurate Estimating-Typothetae Production Records Provide Accurate Efficiency Gauge," in Proceedings of the Thirty-ninth Annual Convention (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1925); also in Typothetae Bulletin (October 26, 1925): 136.
-
(1925)
Typothetae Bulletin
, pp. 136
-
-
-
168
-
-
14544289393
-
-
address before the Convention of the Seventh District Typothetae Federation of Springfield, Ohio November 9
-
George N. Voorhees, "Better Pricing of the Product of the Printing Plant," address before the Convention of the Seventh District Typothetae Federation of Springfield, Ohio (November 9, 1920). NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2, 8-9.
-
(1920)
Better Pricing of the Product of the Printing Plant
-
-
Voorhees, G.N.1
-
169
-
-
14544306350
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
History of the UTA
, pp. 192-193
-
-
Powell1
-
170
-
-
14544292746
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912
, pp. 33-37
-
-
-
171
-
-
14544284373
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914
, pp. 97-98
-
-
-
172
-
-
14544305373
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916
, pp. 39
-
-
-
173
-
-
14544308644
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913
, pp. 21-22
-
-
-
174
-
-
14544288939
-
-
April 20
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
(1911)
Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States
-
-
-
175
-
-
14544302531
-
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913
, pp. 27-29
-
-
-
176
-
-
14544303457
-
Report of the american cost commission
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917
, pp. 89-91
-
-
Meyer, H.W.J.1
-
177
-
-
14544274871
-
-
November
-
For UTA annual membership from 1888 to 1926, see Powell, History of the UTA, 192-93. For figures on the growth of local and regional associations, and cost system distribution, see Proceedings of the Twenty Sixth Annual Convention of the UTA, September 3-6, 1912, 33-37; Proceedings of the Twenty-eighth Annual Convention of United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1914, 97-98; Proceedings of the 30th Annual Convention United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1916, 39; Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 21-22; and Proceedings of the First Printers'Cost Congress of the Southeastern States, April 20, 1911. For a list of new locals, see Proceedings of Twenty-seventh Annual Convention of the United Typothetae and Franklin Clubs of America, 1913, 27-29. On the growth of the composite statement, see H. W. J. Meyer, "Report of the American Cost Commission," in Proceedings of the Thirty-first Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917,89-91. A year later, the figures on the composite statement were very much the same; see Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 24.
-
(1918)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.12
, Issue.5
, pp. 24
-
-
-
178
-
-
14544268416
-
-
NARA, RG 122, Box 216, File 2/459-2
-
"Meeting of the Executive Council of the UTA and the Advisory Committee of the Allied Interests, August 23 and 24, 1918," 3. NARA, RG 122, Box 216, File 2/459-2.
-
Meeting of the Executive Council of the UTA and the Advisory Committee of the Allied Interests, August 23 and 24, 1918
, vol.3
-
-
-
179
-
-
14544276691
-
-
Resume of Progress made by the UTA as Reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a Meeting with the Executive Council of the UTA on January 23
-
"Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as Reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a Meeting with the Executive Council of the UTA on January 23, 1920; and Edward T. Miller, "Uniform Cost Systems," American Trade Association Executives, Proceedings and Addresses, Second Annual Convention, 1921, 67.
-
(1920)
Development of the Three Year Plan
-
-
-
180
-
-
14544288487
-
Uniform cost systems
-
American Trade Association Executives
-
"Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as Reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a Meeting with the Executive Council of the UTA on January 23, 1920; and Edward T. Miller, "Uniform Cost Systems," American Trade Association Executives, Proceedings and Addresses, Second Annual Convention, 1921, 67.
-
(1921)
Proceedings and Addresses, Second Annual Convention
, pp. 67
-
-
Miller, E.T.1
-
181
-
-
14544302982
-
-
October
-
E. T. Miller, CofC October 1924, 92; and Testimony of Miller, in the Official Report of the Proceedings before the Federal Trade Commission, Docket 459, FTC v UTA, July 5, 1922, 982, 990-991, in NARA, RG 122, Box 217, File # 459-2-1.
-
(1924)
CofC
, pp. 92
-
-
Miller, E.T.1
-
182
-
-
14544271280
-
-
in the Official Report of the Proceedings before the Federal Trade Commission, Docket 459, July 5, in NARA, RG 122, Box 217, File # 459-2-1
-
E. T. Miller, CofC October 1924, 92; and Testimony of Miller, in the Official Report of the Proceedings before the Federal Trade Commission, Docket 459, FTC v UTA, July 5, 1922, 982, 990-991, in NARA, RG 122, Box 217, File # 459-2-1.
-
(1922)
FTC V UTA
, pp. 982
-
-
Miller1
-
185
-
-
14544276214
-
-
January
-
Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 7 (January 1918): 3.
-
(1918)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.12
, Issue.7
, pp. 3
-
-
-
186
-
-
14544273086
-
Departmental cost analysis
-
Chicago: United Typothetae of America
-
Mabel H. Dwyer, "Departmental Cost Analysis," in Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1930); also in Typothetae Bulletin 32, no. 3 (October 27, 1930): 100-3.
-
(1930)
Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA
-
-
Dwyer, M.H.1
-
187
-
-
14544275332
-
-
October 27
-
Mabel H. Dwyer, "Departmental Cost Analysis," in Proceedings of the Forty-fourth Convention of the UTA (Chicago: United Typothetae of America, 1930); also in Typothetae Bulletin 32, no. 3 (October 27, 1930): 100-3.
-
(1930)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.32
, Issue.3
, pp. 100-103
-
-
-
188
-
-
14544290825
-
Management and the accountant
-
October 26
-
Reported by George N. Voorhees, "Management and the Accountant," Typothetae Bulletin (October 26,1925): 143-45.
-
(1925)
Typothetae Bulletin
, pp. 143-145
-
-
Voorhees, G.N.1
-
189
-
-
14544290826
-
-
Proceedings of the Twenty-fourth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae of America, May 17-19,1910 (Assn, 1910), 29-97; and Miller, "Uniform Methods and Standardized Costs," 150.
-
Proceedings of the Twenty-fourth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae of America, May 17-19,1910 (Assn, 1910)
, pp. 29-97
-
-
-
190
-
-
14544268417
-
-
Proceedings of the Twenty-fourth Annual Convention of the United Typothetae of America, May 17-19,1910 (Assn, 1910), 29-97; and Miller, "Uniform Methods and Standardized Costs," 150.
-
Uniform Methods and Standardized Costs
, pp. 150
-
-
Miller1
-
191
-
-
14544293824
-
-
November
-
Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 25-26; "Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23,1920, p. 1. NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2; and Testimony of Edward T. Miller, in Official Report of Proceedings before the FTC, Docket No. 459, In the Matter of FTC vs. UTA, Chicago, July 5, 1922, p. 990. RG 122, Box 217, File 459-2-1.
-
(1918)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.12
, Issue.5
, pp. 25-26
-
-
-
192
-
-
14544276691
-
-
Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2
-
Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 25-26; "Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23,1920, p. 1. NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2; and Testimony of Edward T. Miller, in Official Report of Proceedings before the FTC, Docket No. 459, In the Matter of FTC vs. UTA, Chicago, July 5, 1922, p. 990. RG 122, Box 217, File 459-2-1.
-
(1920)
Development of the Three Year Plan
, pp. 1
-
-
-
193
-
-
14544294723
-
-
in Official Report of Proceedings before the FTC, Docket No. 459, Chicago, July 5, RG 122, Box 217, File 459-2-1
-
Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November 1918): 25-26; "Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23,1920, p. 1. NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2; and Testimony of Edward T. Miller, in Official Report of Proceedings before the FTC, Docket No. 459, In the Matter of FTC vs. UTA, Chicago, July 5, 1922, p. 990. RG 122, Box 217, File 459-2-1.
-
(1922)
In the Matter of FTC Vs. UTA
, pp. 990
-
-
Miller, E.T.1
-
194
-
-
14544276691
-
-
Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2
-
"Development of the Three Year Plan," Resume of Progress made by the UTA as reported to Representatives of the Allied Industries at a meeting with the Exec Council of the UTA on January 23,1920, 3. NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2.
-
(1920)
Development of the Three Year Plan
, pp. 3
-
-
-
195
-
-
14544273559
-
-
before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960
-
In 1924, Secretary Miller told participants at a National Chamber of Commerce meeting on uniform cost accounting that printers had long been "next to last in the credit ratings, in 80th place and the 81 st place was the saloonkeeper. They are up to about the 15th place now." Charles L. Estey, "Address on the Three-Year-Plan," before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, 1924, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960, p. 95. See also Edward T. Miller testimony in FTC v. UTA Hearings, Chicago, etc., 928; George H. Gardner, vice president of the UTA, "Price Control," Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November, 1918): 147-48. In 1917, the UTA conducted its own credit study, comparing a sample of "those members who used the Standard Cost system and an equal number of the same kinds and character of plants outside of the Organization." They found that "of the Cost System users, 84 percent were given first-grade credit.... Of those plants outside of the Organization, it was shown that 38 percent of them had no credit rating whatever." See Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917, 23-27. Four years later, the association reported that according to Dun and Bradstreet's, 90 percent of the failures in the printing business in 1921 were in cities without a UTA chapter. "The Proof of the Puddin'," Typothetae Bulletin 17, no. 25 (September 17, 1923): 389.
-
(1924)
Address on the Three-Year-Plan
, pp. 95
-
-
Estey, C.L.1
-
196
-
-
14544288056
-
-
Hearings, Chicago, etc.
-
In 1924, Secretary Miller told participants at a National Chamber of Commerce meeting on uniform cost accounting that printers had long been "next to last in the credit ratings, in 80th place and the 81 st place was the saloonkeeper. They are up to about the 15th place now." Charles L. Estey, "Address on the Three-Year-Plan," before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, 1924, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960, p. 95. See also Edward T. Miller testimony in FTC v. UTA Hearings, Chicago, etc., 928; George H. Gardner, vice president of the UTA, "Price Control," Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November, 1918): 147-48. In 1917, the UTA conducted its own credit study, comparing a sample of "those members who used the Standard Cost system and an equal number of the same kinds and character of plants outside of the Organization." They found that "of the Cost System users, 84 percent were given first-grade credit.... Of those plants outside of the Organization, it was shown that 38 percent of them had no credit rating whatever." See Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917, 23-27. Four years later, the association reported that according to Dun and Bradstreet's, 90 percent of the failures in the printing business in 1921 were in cities without a UTA chapter. "The Proof of the Puddin'," Typothetae Bulletin 17, no. 25 (September 17, 1923): 389.
-
FTC V. UTA
, pp. 928
-
-
Miller, E.T.1
-
197
-
-
14544288055
-
Price control
-
November
-
In 1924, Secretary Miller told participants at a National Chamber of Commerce meeting on uniform cost accounting that printers had long been "next to last in the credit ratings, in 80th place and the 81 st place was the saloonkeeper. They are up to about the 15th place now." Charles L. Estey, "Address on the Three-Year-Plan," before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, 1924, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960, p. 95. See also Edward T. Miller testimony in FTC v. UTA Hearings, Chicago, etc., 928; George H. Gardner, vice president of the UTA, "Price Control," Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November, 1918): 147-48. In 1917, the UTA conducted its own credit study, comparing a sample of "those members who used the Standard Cost system and an equal number of the same kinds and character of plants outside of the Organization." They found that "of the Cost System users, 84 percent were given first-grade credit.... Of those plants outside of the Organization, it was shown that 38 percent of them had no credit rating whatever." See Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917, 23-27. Four years later, the association reported that according to Dun and Bradstreet's, 90 percent of the failures in the printing business in 1921 were in cities without a UTA chapter. "The Proof of the Puddin'," Typothetae Bulletin 17, no. 25 (September 17, 1923): 389.
-
(1918)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.12
, Issue.5
, pp. 147-148
-
-
Gardner, G.H.1
-
198
-
-
14544304885
-
-
In 1924, Secretary Miller told participants at a National Chamber of Commerce meeting on uniform cost accounting that printers had long been "next to last in the credit ratings, in 80th place and the 81 st place was the saloonkeeper. They are up to about the 15th place now." Charles L. Estey, "Address on the Three-Year-Plan," before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, 1924, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960, p. 95. See also Edward T. Miller testimony in FTC v. UTA Hearings, Chicago, etc., 928; George H. Gardner, vice president of the UTA, "Price Control," Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November, 1918): 147-48. In 1917, the UTA conducted its own credit study, comparing a sample of "those members who used the Standard Cost system and an equal number of the same kinds and character of plants outside of the Organization." They found that "of the Cost System users, 84 percent were given first-grade credit.... Of those plants outside of the Organization, it was shown that 38 percent of them had no credit rating whatever." See Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917, 23-27. Four years later, the association reported that according to Dun and Bradstreet's, 90 percent of the failures in the printing business in 1921 were in cities without a UTA chapter. "The Proof of the Puddin'," Typothetae Bulletin 17, no. 25 (September 17, 1923): 389.
-
Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917
, pp. 23-27
-
-
-
199
-
-
14544297251
-
The proof of the puddin'
-
September 17
-
In 1924, Secretary Miller told participants at a National Chamber of Commerce meeting on uniform cost accounting that printers had long been "next to last in the credit ratings, in 80th place and the 81 st place was the saloonkeeper. They are up to about the 15th place now." Charles L. Estey, "Address on the Three-Year-Plan," before the National Paper Trade Association, the Writing Paper Mfrs. Association, and the Cover Paper Mfrs. Association, June 1919, NARA, RG 122, Box 218, File 2/459-2. E. T. Miller, Uniform Cost Accounting Conference, Chicago, October 28-29, 1924, U.S. Chamber Papers, Ace. # 1960, p. 95. See also Edward T. Miller testimony in FTC v. UTA Hearings, Chicago, etc., 928; George H. Gardner, vice president of the UTA, "Price Control," Typothetae Bulletin 12, no. 5 (November, 1918): 147-48. In 1917, the UTA conducted its own credit study, comparing a sample of "those members who used the Standard Cost system and an equal number of the same kinds and character of plants outside of the Organization." They found that "of the Cost System users, 84 percent were given first-grade credit.... Of those plants outside of the Organization, it was shown that 38 percent of them had no credit rating whatever." See Proceedings of the 31st Annual Convention, United Typothetae of America, 1917, 23-27. Four years later, the association reported that according to Dun and Bradstreet's, 90 percent of the failures in the printing business in 1921 were in cities without a UTA chapter. "The Proof of the Puddin'," Typothetae Bulletin 17, no. 25 (September 17, 1923): 389.
-
(1923)
Typothetae Bulletin
, vol.17
, Issue.25
, pp. 389
-
-
-
200
-
-
0345617763
-
-
New York: Columbia University Press
-
Elizabeth F. Baker, Displacement of Men by Machines: Effects of Technological Change in Commercial Printing (New York: Columbia University Press, 1933), 18-24, 201. Baker divides her figures on press sales at 1913. In order to adjust for the effects of uniform cost accounting, we reconfigured her calculations to break at 1916.
-
(1933)
Displacement of Men by Machines: Effects of Technological Change in Commercial Printing
, pp. 18-24
-
-
Baker, E.F.1
-
201
-
-
14544269262
-
-
note
-
Between 1900 and 1919, value added per worker in book and job printing increased from $26, 372 to $31,118. These levels exceeded the average value added per worker for all American manufacturing industries by $3,825 to $7,864. Following the three-year plan, value added for printers increased from $31,118 in 1919 to $50,411 in 1929, levels that exceeded the American manufacturing average by $9,058 to $14,469.
-
-
-
-
202
-
-
14544289392
-
-
Institute for Energy Analysis, Oak Ridge Associated Universities, January Research Memorandum ORAU/IEA-84-8 (M)
-
Warren D. Devine Jr., Technological Change and Electrification in the Printing Industry, 1880-1930, Institute for Energy Analysis, Oak Ridge Associated Universities, January 1985, Research Memorandum ORAU/IEA-84-8 (M), 58-59; and Baker, Displacement of Men by Machines, 48-80. Nor was the continued decentralization of the industry a foregone conclusion. In the late 1910s and the early 1920s, census data seemed to show the opposite and some knowledgeable commentators predicted continued concentration. See Lewis, "The UTA Marketing Program," 96.
-
(1985)
Technological Change and Electrification in the Printing Industry, 1880-1930
, pp. 58-59
-
-
Devine Jr., W.D.1
-
203
-
-
14544286229
-
-
Warren D. Devine Jr., Technological Change and Electrification in the Printing Industry, 1880-1930, Institute for Energy Analysis, Oak Ridge Associated Universities, January 1985, Research Memorandum ORAU/IEA-84-8 (M), 58-59; and Baker, Displacement of Men by Machines, 48-80. Nor was the continued decentralization of the industry a foregone conclusion. In the late 1910s and the early 1920s, census data seemed to show the opposite and some knowledgeable commentators predicted continued concentration. See Lewis, "The UTA Marketing Program," 96.
-
Displacement of Men by Machines
, pp. 48-80
-
-
Baker1
-
204
-
-
14544294724
-
-
Warren D. Devine Jr., Technological Change and Electrification in the Printing Industry, 1880-1930, Institute for Energy Analysis, Oak Ridge Associated Universities, January 1985, Research Memorandum ORAU/IEA-84-8 (M), 58-59; and Baker, Displacement of Men by Machines, 48-80. Nor was the continued decentralization of the industry a foregone conclusion. In the late 1910s and the early 1920s, census data seemed to show the opposite and some knowledgeable commentators predicted continued concentration. See Lewis, "The UTA Marketing Program," 96.
-
The UTA Marketing Program
, pp. 96
-
-
Lewis1
-
205
-
-
14544276692
-
-
note
-
As noted in part I, the Chamber of Commerce formed its own uniform cost accounting group, and convened a series of conferences in April 1920, October 1923, and March and October 1924, bringing together hundreds of firms and associations to discuss cost accounting systems and their implementation. These conferences provide us with lists of participants, as well as proceedings and papers describing what particular associations had done to develop and operate classification schemes, costs manuals, and benchmarking systems. In addition, the Federal Trade Commission conducted an extensive investigation of open price associations in the 1920s, generating an inventory of associations that had "Uniform Systems" and a table documenting the activities of those organizations in some detail in its 1927 Report. Taken together, these sources provide a wealth of detailed data on developmental associations and their activity across American industries in the 1920 to 1925 period.
-
-
-
-
206
-
-
14544276917
-
-
note
-
In compiling this list, we focused on associations-they dominated the conference proceedings numerically and were the only organizations listed in the FTC study. Yet we also kept track of businesses, typically large corporations like Kodak, Bethlehem Steel, and AT&T, who attended conferences, but as individual firms rather than as officers, representatives, or members of associations.
-
-
-
-
207
-
-
14544275759
-
-
note
-
Note that in constructing these data sets, we took a conservative approach in assigning higher levels of involvement to associations and industries. We coded them to the substantial involvement or benchmarking
-
-
-
-
208
-
-
14544274872
-
-
note
-
This group of firms included AT&T and Stromberg Carlson, Kodak, Johnson and Johnson, National Cash Register, Standard Chemical, and Harrisburg Shoe, as well as General Tire, Deere, Corona Typewriter, and a number of large steel producers including Bethlehem, Laclede, and Peerless Tube.
-
-
-
-
209
-
-
0002771445
-
Organizing business interests: Patterns of trade association founds, transformations and deaths
-
Glen Carroll ed., (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger)
-
The figures presented are calculated as percentages of ( 1 ) the total number of manufacturing industries listed in the U.S. Census in 1919, and (2) the estimated number of national and regional business associations in existence in the United States in the 1920s. Reliable estimates of associations during this time period vary between 600 and 1,000. For perhaps the most comprehensive study, which results in the lower estimate, see Howard Aldrich and Udo Staber, "Organizing Business Interests: Patterns of Trade Association Founds, Transformations and Deaths," in Glen Carroll ed., Ecological Models of Organization (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1988), 123; and Howard Aldrich, Udo Staber, Catherine Zimmer, and John J Beggs, "Minimalism and Organizational Mortality: Patterns of Disbanding among U.S. Trade Associations, 1900-1983," in Jitrendra Singh, ed., Organizational Evolution (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1990), 33. Studies from the 1920s to 1940s vary between 500 and 1,500 (though the latter includes about 500 fraternal associations). After careful review, the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) concluded there were between 800 and 1,000 national or interstate business associations in 1925. See National Industrial Conference Board, Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status (New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1925): 319-26. Jay Judkins, National Associations of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1949), viii, and National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States (New York: Columbia Books, 1990), 7, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000.
-
(1988)
Ecological Models of Organization
, pp. 123
-
-
Aldrich, H.1
Staber, U.2
-
210
-
-
0001827510
-
Minimalism and organizational mortality: Patterns of disbanding among U.S. trade associations, 1900-1983
-
Jitrendra Singh, ed., (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage)
-
The figures presented are calculated as percentages of ( 1 ) the total number of manufacturing industries listed in the U.S. Census in 1919, and (2) the estimated number of national and regional business associations in existence in the United States in the 1920s. Reliable estimates of associations during this time period vary between 600 and 1,000. For perhaps the most comprehensive study, which results in the lower estimate, see Howard Aldrich and Udo Staber, "Organizing Business Interests: Patterns of Trade Association Founds, Transformations and Deaths," in Glen Carroll ed., Ecological Models of Organization (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1988), 123; and Howard Aldrich, Udo Staber, Catherine Zimmer, and John J Beggs, "Minimalism and Organizational Mortality: Patterns of Disbanding among U.S. Trade Associations, 1900-1983," in Jitrendra Singh, ed., Organizational Evolution (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1990), 33. Studies from the 1920s to 1940s vary between 500 and 1,500 (though the latter includes about 500 fraternal associations). After careful review, the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) concluded there were between 800 and 1,000 national or interstate business associations in 1925. See National Industrial Conference Board, Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status (New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1925): 319-26. Jay Judkins, National Associations of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1949), viii, and National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States (New York: Columbia Books, 1990), 7, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000.
-
(1990)
Organizational Evolution
, pp. 33
-
-
Aldrich, H.1
Staber, U.2
Zimmer, C.3
Beggs, J.J.4
-
211
-
-
14544268829
-
-
New York: National Industrial Conference Board
-
The figures presented are calculated as percentages of ( 1 ) the total number of manufacturing industries listed in the U.S. Census in 1919, and (2) the estimated number of national and regional business associations in existence in the United States in the 1920s. Reliable estimates of associations during this time period vary between 600 and 1,000. For perhaps the most comprehensive study, which results in the lower estimate, see Howard Aldrich and Udo Staber, "Organizing Business Interests: Patterns of Trade Association Founds, Transformations and Deaths," in Glen Carroll ed., Ecological Models of Organization (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1988), 123; and Howard Aldrich, Udo Staber, Catherine Zimmer, and John J Beggs, "Minimalism and Organizational Mortality: Patterns of Disbanding among U.S. Trade Associations, 1900-1983," in Jitrendra Singh, ed., Organizational Evolution (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1990), 33. Studies from the 1920s to 1940s vary between 500 and 1,500 (though the latter includes about 500 fraternal associations). After careful review, the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) concluded there were between 800 and 1,000 national or interstate business associations in 1925. See National Industrial Conference Board, Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status (New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1925): 319-26. Jay Judkins, National Associations of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1949), viii, and National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States (New York: Columbia Books, 1990), 7, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000.
-
(1925)
Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status
, pp. 319-326
-
-
-
212
-
-
84965882175
-
-
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce
-
The figures presented are calculated as percentages of ( 1 ) the total number of manufacturing industries listed in the U.S. Census in 1919, and (2) the estimated number of national and regional business associations in existence in the United States in the 1920s. Reliable estimates of associations during this time period vary between 600 and 1,000. For perhaps the most comprehensive study, which results in the lower estimate, see Howard Aldrich and Udo Staber, "Organizing Business Interests: Patterns of Trade Association Founds, Transformations and Deaths," in Glen Carroll ed., Ecological Models of Organization (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1988), 123; and Howard Aldrich, Udo Staber, Catherine Zimmer, and John J Beggs, "Minimalism and Organizational Mortality: Patterns of Disbanding among U.S. Trade Associations, 1900-1983," in Jitrendra Singh, ed., Organizational Evolution (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1990), 33. Studies from the 1920s to 1940s vary between 500 and 1,500 (though the latter includes about 500 fraternal associations). After careful review, the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) concluded there were between 800 and 1,000 national or interstate business associations in 1925. See National Industrial Conference Board, Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status (New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1925): 319-26. Jay Judkins, National Associations of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1949), viii, and National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States (New York: Columbia Books, 1990), 7, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000.
-
(1949)
National Associations of the United States
-
-
Judkins, J.1
-
213
-
-
14544284838
-
-
New York: Columbia Books, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000
-
The figures presented are calculated as percentages of ( 1 ) the total number of manufacturing industries listed in the U.S. Census in 1919, and (2) the estimated number of national and regional business associations in existence in the United States in the 1920s. Reliable estimates of associations during this time period vary between 600 and 1,000. For perhaps the most comprehensive study, which results in the lower estimate, see Howard Aldrich and Udo Staber, "Organizing Business Interests: Patterns of Trade Association Founds, Transformations and Deaths," in Glen Carroll ed., Ecological Models of Organization (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1988), 123; and Howard Aldrich, Udo Staber, Catherine Zimmer, and John J Beggs, "Minimalism and Organizational Mortality: Patterns of Disbanding among U.S. Trade Associations, 1900-1983," in Jitrendra Singh, ed., Organizational Evolution (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1990), 33. Studies from the 1920s to 1940s vary between 500 and 1,500 (though the latter includes about 500 fraternal associations). After careful review, the National Industrial Conference Board (NICB) concluded there were between 800 and 1,000 national or interstate business associations in 1925. See National Industrial Conference Board, Trade Associations: Their Economic Significance and Legal Status (New York: National Industrial Conference Board, 1925): 319-26. Jay Judkins, National Associations of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1949), viii, and National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States (New York: Columbia Books, 1990), 7, both report approximately 1,000 trade associations in 1920. We report the interval between 600 and 1,000.
-
(1990)
National Trade and Professional Associations of the United States
, pp. 7
-
-
-
214
-
-
14544306783
-
-
88fnl, Lamoreaux finds that 52 of the 232 industries in her study, or 22 percent, experienced significant consolidation activity during the great merger wave, a figure broadly consistent with Fligstein's reanalysis, which finds that 21 percent of 230 sectors, or 48 industries, underwent consolidation (in Transformation of Corporate Control, 318-19). Curiously, there are no established metrics or benchmarks in the literature on economic organization for establishing when or where a particular form, institutional logic, or industrial order becomes significant or dominant within an economy
-
In The Great Merger Movement, 88fnl, Lamoreaux finds that 52 of the 232 industries in her study, or 22 percent, experienced significant consolidation activity during the great merger wave, a figure broadly consistent with Fligstein's reanalysis, which finds that 21 percent of 230 sectors, or 48 industries, underwent consolidation (in Transformation of Corporate Control, 318-19). Curiously, there are no established metrics or benchmarks in the literature on economic organization for establishing when or where a particular form, institutional logic, or industrial order becomes significant or dominant within an economy.
-
The Great Merger Movement
-
-
-
215
-
-
14544285318
-
-
note
-
These are industry level data from the 1919 and 1929 Census of Manufactures. Productivity data consist of (1) the average of the value added per worker for all of the industries falling in each category for 1919, and (2) the average of the increase in the value added per worker from 1919 to 1929 for all industries in each category. Growth data consist of ( 1 ) the average of the number of workers employed per industry for all of the industries falling in each category for 1919, and (2) the average of the increase in employment from 1919 to 1929 for all industries in each category. The averages are not adjusted for the sizes or initial productivity. Note that the involvement categories listed here are mutually exclusive and exhaustive.
-
-
-
-
216
-
-
0002047941
-
Community, market, state-and associations? the prospective contribution of interest governance to social order
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Beverly Hills, CA: Sage
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, "Community, Market, State-and Associations? The Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order," in Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Private Interest Government (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985); Michael Atkinson and William Coleman, "Corporatism and Industrial Policy," in Alan Cawson, ed, Organized Interests and the State (London: Sage, 1985); Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed., The Political Economy of Corporatism (London: Macmillan, 1986); Schneiberg and Rollings worth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?"; and Lindberg, Campbell, and Hollingsworth, "Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy."
-
(1985)
Private Interest Government
-
-
Streeck, W.1
Schmitter, P.2
-
217
-
-
0002456101
-
Corporatism and industrial policy
-
Alan Cawson, ed, London: Sage
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, "Community, Market, State-and Associations? The Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order," in Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Private Interest Government (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985); Michael Atkinson and William Coleman, "Corporatism and Industrial Policy," in Alan Cawson, ed, Organized Interests and the State (London: Sage, 1985); Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed., The Political Economy of Corporatism (London: Macmillan, 1986); Schneiberg and Rollings worth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?"; and Lindberg, Campbell, and Hollingsworth, "Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy."
-
(1985)
Organized Interests and the State
-
-
Atkinson, M.1
Coleman, W.2
-
218
-
-
0002641084
-
Neo-corporatism and the State
-
Wyn Grant, ed., (London: Macmillan)
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, "Community, Market, State-and Associations? The Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order," in Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Private Interest Government (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985); Michael Atkinson and William Coleman, "Corporatism and Industrial Policy," in Alan Cawson, ed, Organized Interests and the State (London: Sage, 1985); Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed., The Political Economy of Corporatism (London: Macmillan, 1986); Schneiberg and Rollings worth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?"; and Lindberg, Campbell, and Hollingsworth, "Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy."
-
(1986)
The Political Economy of Corporatism
-
-
Schmitter, P.1
-
219
-
-
14544303930
-
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, "Community, Market, State-and Associations? The Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order," in Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Private Interest Government (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985); Michael Atkinson and William Coleman, "Corporatism and Industrial Policy," in Alan Cawson, ed, Organized Interests and the State (London: Sage, 1985); Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed., The Political Economy of Corporatism (London: Macmillan, 1986); Schneiberg and Rollings worth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?"; and Lindberg, Campbell, and Hollingsworth, "Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy."
-
Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?
-
-
Schneiberg1
Worth, R.2
-
220
-
-
14544288940
-
-
Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, "Community, Market, State-and Associations? The Prospective Contribution of Interest Governance to Social Order," in Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Private Interest Government (Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1985); Michael Atkinson and William Coleman, "Corporatism and Industrial Policy," in Alan Cawson, ed, Organized Interests and the State (London: Sage, 1985); Philippe Schmitter, "Neo-corporatism and the State," in Wyn Grant, ed., The Political Economy of Corporatism (London: Macmillan, 1986); Schneiberg and Rollings worth, "Can Transaction Cost Economics Explain Trade Associations?"; and Lindberg, Campbell, and Hollingsworth, "Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy."
-
Economic Governance and the Analysis of Structural Change in the American Economy
-
-
Lindberg1
Campbell2
Hollingsworth3
-
221
-
-
14544290350
-
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
American Possibilities
-
-
Berk1
-
222
-
-
14544277362
-
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms
-
-
Schneiberg1
-
223
-
-
14544297252
-
Private, public, or cooperative? Economic order, institutional embeddedness and organizational form in the US electrical utility industry
-
paper presented at the Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(2002)
Annual Meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies
-
-
Schneiberg, M.1
-
224
-
-
0002464333
-
Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices and institutional contradictions
-
Powell and DiMaggio, eds.
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis.
-
-
Friedland, R.1
Alford, R.R.2
-
225
-
-
0030548983
-
The color of money and the nature of value: Greenbacks and gold in postbellum America
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(1996)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.101
, pp. 1556-1591
-
-
Carruthers, B.1
Babb, S.2
-
226
-
-
49549121503
-
-
Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(1997)
The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925
-
-
-
227
-
-
0032331695
-
Caveat emptor: The construction of nonprofit watchdog organizations
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(1998)
American Journal of Sociology
, vol.4
, pp. 912-951
-
-
Rao, H.1
-
228
-
-
0003839971
-
-
Chicago: University of Chicago
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(2000)
Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations
-
-
Scott, W.R.1
Ruef, M.2
Mendel, P.3
Caronna, C.4
-
229
-
-
0007208944
-
Legitimacy processes as institutional politics: Implications for theory and research in the sociology of organizations
-
in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI)
-
See notes 2 and 3 above. We also draw here on our own recent work along these lines, and research by new institutionalists in organizational sociology that have begun to reconceptualize systems and fields as constituted by multiple institutional logics. See Berk, American Possibilities; Schneiberg, "Organizational Heterogeneity and the Production of New Forms"; and Marc Schneiberg, "Private, Public, or Cooperative? Economic Order, Institutional Embeddedness and Organizational Form in the US Electrical Utility Industry," paper presented at the annual meeting of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economies, Minneapolis, Minnesota, June 27-30,2002. The classic piece in sociology is Roger Friedland and Robert R. Alford, "Bringing Society Back In: Symbols, Practices and Institutional Contradictions," in Powell and DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. See also Bruce Carruthers and Sarah Babb, "The Color of Money and the Nature of Value: Greenbacks and Gold in Postbellum America," American Journal of Sociology 101 (1996), 1556-91; Elizabeth Clemens, The People's Lobby: Organizational Innovation and the Rise of Interest Group Politics in the United States, 1890-1925 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997); Hayagareeva Rao, "Caveat Emptor: The Construction of Nonprofit Watchdog Organizations," American Journal of Sociology 4 (1998): 912-51; W. Richard Scott, Martin Ruef, Peter Mendel, and Carol Caronna, Institutional Change and Healthcare Organizations (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2000); and Robin Stryker, "Legitimacy Processes as Institutional Politics: Implications for Theory and Research in the Sociology of Organizations," in Samuel Bacharach and Edward Lawler, eds., Research in the Sociology of Organizations (Greenwich, Conn.: JAI, 2000).
-
(2000)
Research in the Sociology of Organizations
-
-
Stryker, R.1
-
230
-
-
14544290350
-
-
chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
American Possibilities
-
-
Berk1
-
231
-
-
14544278233
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
Learning by Monitoring
-
-
Sabel1
-
232
-
-
0040903246
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
Stories, Strategies, Structures
-
-
Sabel1
Zeitlin2
-
233
-
-
0010170508
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism
-
-
Stark1
-
234
-
-
14544283181
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
Discursive Cartels
-
-
Berk1
-
235
-
-
46249114323
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
The Creativity of Action
-
-
Joas1
-
236
-
-
0004350113
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
A Theory of Structure
-
-
Sewell1
-
237
-
-
67049142863
-
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
People 'S Lobby
-
-
Clemens1
-
238
-
-
84900232856
-
Institutional change and interstitial emergence: The growth of alternative dispute resolution in American law, 1965-1995
-
in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., (Chicago: University of Chicago)
-
Berk, American Possibilities, chap. 1, provides a fuller discussion of reflexivity and agency in institutional development, and the related concepts of recombination, syncretism, and redeployment. See also, Sabel, "Learning by Monitoring"; Sabel and Zeitlin, "Stories, Strategies, Structures;" Stark, "Recombinant Property in Eastern European Capitalism"; Berk, "Discursive Cartels"; Joas, The Creativity of Action; Sewell, "A Theory of Structure"; Clemens, People 's Lobby; Calvin Morrill, "Institutional Change and Interstitial Emergence: The Growth of Alternative Dispute Resolution in American Law, 1965-1995," in Walter Powell and Dan Jones, eds., How Institutions Change (Chicago: University of Chicago, 2003); and Kathleen Thelen, How Institutions Evolve, chap. 1 (unpublished ms., 2003). gberk@uoregon.edu marc.schneiberg@directory.reed.edu
-
(2003)
How Institutions Change
-
-
Morrill, C.1
|