메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 51, Issue 11, 2000, Pages 1-18

Monopoly Capital at the Turn of the Millennium

(1)  Foster, John Bellamy a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0347899483     PISSN: 00270520     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.14452/MR-051-11-2000-04_1     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (11)

References (38)
  • 1
    • 0004280585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Monthly Review Press
    • Paul A. Baran and Paul M. Sweezy, Monopoly Capital (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966), p. 125. It should be emphasized that in referring to "the tendency of surplus to rise" Baran and Sweezy had no intention of presenting this as an iron law, i.e., one not subject to countervailing factors that modify or mitigate its effect. Rather they invariably emphasized that this was a mere tendency (or tendential law), which could not be examined apart from such countervailing factors.
    • (1966) Monopoly Capital , pp. 125
    • Baran, P.A.1    Sweezy, P.M.2
  • 2
    • 0004255493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • August 16
    • Business Week, August 16, 1999, pp. 88-90, August 2, 1999, pp. 28-31 and December 27, 1999, pp. 52-55.
    • (1999) Business Week , pp. 88-90
  • 3
    • 33645769649 scopus 로고
    • October
    • Kevin J. Clancy and Robert S. Shulman, Across the Board (October 1993), p. 38, and Marketing Myths that are Killing Business (New York: McGraw Hill, 1994), pp. 140, 171.
    • (1993) Across the Board , pp. 38
    • Clancy, K.J.1    Shulman, R.S.2
  • 4
    • 0007285717 scopus 로고
    • New York: McGraw Hill
    • Kevin J. Clancy and Robert S. Shulman, Across the Board (October 1993), p. 38, and Marketing Myths that are Killing Business (New York: McGraw Hill, 1994), pp. 140, 171.
    • (1994) Marketing Myths That Are Killing Business , pp. 140
  • 5
    • 33645755527 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tables 1.1 and 1.16
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1,Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no. 8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surplus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323.
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States , vol.1
  • 6
    • 33645776137 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • August
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1,Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no. 8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surplus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323.
    • (1999) Survey of Current Business , vol.79 , Issue.8
  • 7
    • 0345829254 scopus 로고
    • The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988
    • John B. Davis, ed., Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1,Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no. 8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surplus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323.
    • (1992) The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies , pp. 42-70
    • Dawson, M.1    Foster, J.B.2
  • 8
    • 33645760104 scopus 로고
    • September
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1,Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no. 8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surplus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323.
    • (1991) Monthly Review , vol.43 , Issue.4 , pp. 37-50
  • 9
    • 84937301386 scopus 로고
    • Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor
    • Fall
    • National Income and Product Accounts of the United States, vol. 1,Tables 1.1 and 1.16; and U.S. Commerce Department, Survey of Current Business, vol. 79, no. 8 (August 1999), pp. D2 and D5. I would like to thank my friend and colleague Michael Dawson for the initial analysis of this data. It should be noted that depreciation is sometimes seen as a cost to be deducted before arriving at net profits, but in practice depreciation (the amount of which is enormously increased by accelerated depreciation allowances) is part of the social accumulation fund (or total economic surplus) available to capital and hence needs to be included in the surplus. In other words, the appropriate categories for analysis of accumulation are gross profits, gross savings/surplus and gross domestic product (all of which include depreciation) rather than net profits, net savings, or net national product. For more detailed discussion of these issues as well as a far more comprehensive empirical treatment of the tendency of the surplus to rise see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "The Tendency of Surplus to Rise, 1963-1988," in John B. Davis, ed., The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies (Brookfield, Vermont: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 42-70. A heavily abridged version of this research was published under the same title in Monthly Review, vol. 43, no. 4 (September 1991), pp. 37-50. For a graph of this data showing the tendency of the surplus to rise, see Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Is There an Allocation Problem?: Accounting for Unproductive Labor," Science & Society, vol. 58, no. 3 (Fall 1994), p. 323.
    • (1994) Science & Society , vol.58 , Issue.3 , pp. 323
    • Dawson, M.1    Foster, J.B.2
  • 10
    • 0010747479 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office
    • Both monopolistic and competitive sectors of the economy continue to exist side by side, but the giant corporation, able to control to a considerable extent its level of price, output, and investment, is the typical firm in a dynamic sense in the monopoly capitalist economy. Noting the difference in price structure in monopolistic and competitive industries, the Natural Resources Committee report, The Structure of the American Economy (1939), directed by Gardiner Means, observed that the term "monopoly" could be "used on the whole to refer to situations in which sufficient control would be exercised over price by an individual producer or by a colluding group of producers to make possible monopoly profits, i.e., profits above the rate necessary to induce new investment in other industries not subject to monopoly control." Conversely, "a situation was in general classified as competitive if there was insufficient control over price to make monopoly profits possible." Gardiner Means, ed., The Structure of the American Economy, Part I (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1939), p. 139.
    • (1939) The Structure of the American Economy, Part I , pp. 139
    • Means, G.1
  • 11
    • 33645792258 scopus 로고
    • A Note on Inflation
    • John Bellamy Foster and Henryk Szlajfer, ed., New York: Monthly Review Press
    • See Harry Magdoff, "A Note on Inflation," in John Bellamy Foster and Henryk Szlajfer, ed., The Faltering Economy: The Problem of Accumulation Under Monopoly Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1984), pp. 118-23. The Great Depression was of course an exception to the inflationary tendencies under monopoly capitalism.
    • (1984) The Faltering Economy: The Problem of Accumulation under Monopoly Capitalism , pp. 118-123
    • Magdoff, H.1
  • 12
    • 0004053366 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: The Free Press
    • Competition, which has as its main goal the development of monopoly power (entailing surplus profits or monopoly rents) through the monopolization of particular technologies and markets, is sometimes known as "Schumpeterian competition" and closely corresponds with how the term "competition" is used within business today. See James Galbraith, Created Unequal: The Crisis in American Pay (New York: The Free Press, 1998), pp. 40-42.
    • (1998) Created Unequal: The Crisis in American Pay , pp. 40-42
    • Galbraith, J.1
  • 13
    • 0032366495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monopoly Power in the United States Manufacturing Sector, 1899 to 1994
    • Spring
    • Myron Gordon, "Monopoly Power in the United States Manufacturing Sector, 1899 to 1994," Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, vol. 20, no. 3 (Spring 1998), pp. 323-25. Gordon's analysis is inspired by Michal Kalecki's concept of the "degree of monopoly," defined as the price mark-up over average prime production costs. On the relation of Kalecki's analysis to that of Baran and Sweezy see John Bellamy Foster, The Theory of Monopoly Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1986).
    • (1998) Journal of Post Keynesian Economics , vol.20 , Issue.3 , pp. 323-325
    • Gordon, M.1
  • 14
    • 0032366495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Monthly Review Press
    • Myron Gordon, "Monopoly Power in the United States Manufacturing Sector, 1899 to 1994," Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, vol. 20, no. 3 (Spring 1998), pp. 323-25. Gordon's analysis is inspired by Michal Kalecki's concept of the "degree of monopoly," defined as the price mark-up over average prime production costs. On the relation of Kalecki's analysis to that of Baran and Sweezy see John Bellamy Foster, The Theory of Monopoly Capitalism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1986).
    • (1986) The Theory of Monopoly Capitalism
    • Foster, J.B.1
  • 15
    • 33645789939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gordon, "Monopoly Power," pp. 323-25. The production workers category, upon which much of Gordon's analysis depends, is described in the Census of Manufactures as follows: "This item includes workers (up through the line-supervisor level) engaged in fabricating, processing, assembling, inspecting, receiving, storing, handling, packing, warehousing, shipping (but not delivering), maintenance, repair, janitorial and guard services, product development, auxiliary production for plant's own use (e.g., power plant), recordkeeping, and other services closely associated with production operations at the establishment covered by the report. Employees about the working-supervisor level are excluded from this item." General Summary, Census of Manufactures, 1992, p. A-1. Like most economic statistics there are some conceptual issues raised by the production workers category, which have to be taken into account in its application, such as the fact that it excludes all of those managers supervising production above the line-supervisor level (including these among nonproduction workers). Nevertheless, it draws an important distinction between those production workers directly engaged in the process of producing use values and those nonproduction workers primarily geared to management, marketing and finance, etc.
    • Monopoly Power , pp. 323-325
    • Gordon1
  • 16
    • 33645779619 scopus 로고
    • Gordon, "Monopoly Power," pp. 323-25. The production workers category, upon which much of Gordon's analysis depends, is described in the Census of Manufactures as follows: "This item includes workers (up through the line-supervisor level) engaged in fabricating, processing, assembling, inspecting, receiving, storing, handling, packing, warehousing, shipping (but not delivering), maintenance, repair, janitorial and guard services, product development, auxiliary production for plant's own use (e.g., power plant), recordkeeping, and other services closely associated with production operations at the establishment covered by the report. Employees about the working-supervisor level are excluded from this item." General Summary, Census of Manufactures, 1992, p. A-1. Like most economic statistics there are some conceptual issues raised by the production workers category, which have to be taken into account in its application, such as the fact that it excludes all of those managers supervising production above the line-supervisor level (including these among nonproduction workers). Nevertheless, it draws an important distinction between those production workers directly engaged in the process of producing use values and those nonproduction workers primarily geared to management, marketing and finance, etc.
    • (1992) General Summary, Census of Manufactures
  • 18
    • 33645754616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are some theoretical difficulties in equating the "nonproduction workers" category with the concept of "monopoly workers." For one thing, monopoly power is normally rooted in production, so that production workers are also, in a sense, monopoly workers. But Gordon's intention is clearly one of emphasizing that production workers are caught up in the stringent capitalist logic of increasing productivity, and at the same time keeping down unit labor costs-in other words raising the rate of exploitation-in contrast to nonproduction (or "monopoly") workers who have as their main task the increase of the mark-up.
  • 19
    • 33645777716 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid, pp. 327-28
    • Ibid, pp. 327-28.
  • 20
    • 0004140817 scopus 로고
    • New York: Simon and Schuster
    • Richard J. Barnet and John Cavanagh, Global Dreams (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1994), pp. 325-28; Walter LaFeber, Michael Jordan and the New Global Capitalism (New York: W.W. Norton, 1999), pp. 106-07, 147-48; David Korten, The Post-Corporate World: Life After Capitalism, 1999), pp. 77-78.
    • (1994) Global Dreams , pp. 325-328
    • Barnet, R.J.1    Cavanagh, J.2
  • 21
    • 0003668227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: W.W. Norton
    • Richard J. Barnet and John Cavanagh, Global Dreams (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1994), pp. 325-28; Walter LaFeber, Michael Jordan and the New Global Capitalism (New York: W.W. Norton, 1999), pp. 106-07, 147-48; David Korten, The Post-Corporate World: Life After Capitalism, 1999), pp. 77-78.
    • (1999) Michael Jordan and the New Global Capitalism , pp. 106-107
    • LaFeber, W.1
  • 22
    • 0003636976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Richard J. Barnet and John Cavanagh, Global Dreams (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1994), pp. 325-28; Walter LaFeber, Michael Jordan and the New Global Capitalism (New York: W.W. Norton, 1999), pp. 106-07, 147-48; David Korten, The Post-Corporate World: Life After Capitalism, 1999), pp. 77-78.
    • (1999) The Post-Corporate World: Life after Capitalism , pp. 77-78
    • Korten, D.1
  • 23
    • 0343150409 scopus 로고
    • Boulder: Westview Press
    • On General Motors see Douglas Dowd, The Waste of Nations (Boulder: Westview Press, 1989), pp. 65-66. This example of course doesn't take account of the fact that the sales effort had actually penetrated into the production process of such large firms, as Veblen and later Baran and Sweezy were to argue, so that incorporated into production costs themselves were the costs associated with frequent model changes-accounting for perhaps a third of all production costs in automobile production by the middle of the last century.
    • (1989) The Waste of Nations , pp. 65-66
    • Dowd, D.1
  • 25
    • 0003421866 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Report of the President, 1999, p. 39; Korten, The Post-Corporate World, p. 42; New York Times, January 19, 1998, p. A1; Michael J. Mandel, "All These Mergers are Great But...," Business Week, October 18, 1999, p. 48.
    • Economic Report of the President, 1999 , pp. 39
  • 26
    • 0003636976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic Report of the President, 1999, p. 39; Korten, The Post-Corporate World, p. 42; New York Times, January 19, 1998, p. A1; Michael J. Mandel, "All These Mergers are Great But...," Business Week, October 18, 1999, p. 48.
    • The Post-Corporate World , pp. 42
    • Korten1
  • 27
    • 0004185307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • January 19
    • Economic Report of the President, 1999, p. 39; Korten, The Post-Corporate World, p. 42; New York Times, January 19, 1998, p. A1; Michael J. Mandel, "All These Mergers are Great But...," Business Week, October 18, 1999, p. 48.
    • (1998) New York Times
  • 28
    • 33645798220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • All These Mergers are Great But
    • October 18
    • Economic Report of the President, 1999, p. 39; Korten, The Post-Corporate World, p. 42; New York Times, January 19, 1998, p. A1; Michael J. Mandel, "All These Mergers are Great But...," Business Week, October 18, 1999, p. 48.
    • (1999) Business Week , pp. 48
    • Mandel, M.J.1
  • 29
    • 0347321374 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The First Global Car Colossus
    • May 18
    • "The First Global Car Colossus," Business Week, May 18, 1998, pp. 40-41.
    • (1998) Business Week , pp. 40-41
  • 31
    • 33645764061 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Virtual Capitalism
    • Robert W. McChesney, Ellen Meiksins Wood and John Bellamy Foster, ed., New York: Monthly Review Press
    • Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Virtual Capitalism," in Robert W. McChesney, Ellen Meiksins Wood and John Bellamy Foster, ed., Capitalism in the Information Age (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1998), pp. 53-54; United Nations, Human Development Report (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), p. 3.
    • (1998) Capitalism in the Information Age , pp. 53-54
    • Dawson, M.1    Foster, J.B.2
  • 32
    • 28244449869 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • Michael Dawson and John Bellamy Foster, "Virtual Capitalism," in Robert W. McChesney, Ellen Meiksins Wood and John Bellamy Foster, ed., Capitalism in the Information Age (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1998), pp. 53-54; United Nations, Human Development Report (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), p. 3.
    • (1999) Human Development Report , pp. 3
  • 33
    • 0004295395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Verso
    • Doug Henwood, Wall Street (New York: Verso, 1997), pp. 72-75; Business Week, January 24, 2000, p. 37.
    • (1997) Wall Street , pp. 72-75
    • Henwood, D.1
  • 34
    • 0004255493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • January 24
    • Doug Henwood, Wall Street (New York: Verso, 1997), pp. 72-75; Business Week, January 24, 2000, p. 37.
    • (2000) Business Week , pp. 37
  • 35
    • 33645780319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bulletin 2474 April
    • U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, A BLS Reader on Productivity, Bulletin 2474 (April 1996), p. 12.
    • (1996) A BLS Reader on Productivity , pp. 12
  • 36
    • 0033474537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trends in Compensation for Production Workers, 1948-1995
    • December
    • Eric A. Nilsson, "Trends in Compensation for Production Workers, 1948-1995," Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 31, no. 4 (December 1999), pp. 133-63.
    • (1999) Review of Radical Political Economics , vol.31 , Issue.4 , pp. 133-163
    • Nilsson, E.A.1
  • 37
    • 0003792784 scopus 로고
    • New York: Monthly Review Press
    • Harry Magdoff, The Age of Imperialism (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969), p. 200.
    • (1969) The Age of Imperialism , pp. 200
    • Magdoff, H.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.