-
1
-
-
84927456151
-
The Lender of Last Resort A Historical Perspective
-
See How unfitting that the heirs of the man who named the function–Sir Francis Barings–lived to see the Bank of England fairing to rescue Barings in 1995!
-
See T. Humphrey and R. Keleher, “The Lender of Last Resort A Historical Perspective” (1984) 4(1) Cato Journal 275,282. How unfitting that the heirs of the man who named the function–Sir Francis Barings–lived to see the Bank of England fairing to rescue Barings in 1995!
-
(1984)
Cato Journal
, vol.4
, Issue.1
-
-
Humphrey, T.1
Keleher, R.2
-
2
-
-
0003403462
-
-
Regulation A, which governs the extension of credit by Federal Reserve banks, states: “While open market operations are the primary means of affecting the overall supply of reserves, the lending function of the Federal Reserve Banks is an effective method of supplying reserves to meet the particular credit needs of individual depository institutions. The lending functions of the Federal Reserve System are conducted with regard to the basic objectives of monetary policy and the maintenance of a sound and orderly financial system.” (2) The lender of last resort is an instrument of banking supervision in a “crisis situation” stage. As part of its micro-prudential functions, the central bank acting as lender of last resort provides assistance to a bank (or banks) suffering from a liquidity crisis. (3) The lender of last resort is a service provided by the central bank in its capacity as bankers' bank From a central bank's point of view, the nature of its lender of last resort role involves three different aspects: (1) The discount rate at which the central bank lends, acting in its capacity as lender of last resort, is an instrument of monetary policy. In Germany the tightening and easing of the “lombard rate” (i.e. the rate at which the Bundesbank lends emergency funds to banks against collateral) has been used as an instrument of monetary policy. In the US the Federal Reserve System has made use of the discount window lending in monetary policy. However, it is argued that “for the sake of economic stability, it is important that the Fed distinguish at all times between its monetary policy and its LOLR function. The lender of last resort should replace liquidity lost as a result of customer demands; it should not force additional liquidity into the system” see
-
From a central bank's point of view, the nature of its lender of last resort role involves three different aspects: (1) The discount rate at which the central bank lends, acting in its capacity as lender of last resort, is an instrument of monetary policy. In Germany the tightening and easing of the “lombard rate” (i.e. the rate at which the Bundesbank lends emergency funds to banks against collateral) has been used as an instrument of monetary policy. In the US the Federal Reserve System has made use of the discount window lending in monetary policy. However, it is argued that “for the sake of economic stability, it is important that the Fed distinguish at all times between its monetary policy and its LOLR function. The lender of last resort should replace liquidity lost as a result of customer demands; it should not force additional liquidity into the system” (see G. Benston et al., Safe and Sound Banking: Past Present and Future (1986), p.113). Regulation A, which governs the extension of credit by Federal Reserve banks, states: “While open market operations are the primary means of affecting the overall supply of reserves, the lending function of the Federal Reserve Banks is an effective method of supplying reserves to meet the particular credit needs of individual depository institutions. The lending functions of the Federal Reserve System are conducted with regard to the basic objectives of monetary policy and the maintenance of a sound and orderly financial system.” (2) The lender of last resort is an instrument of banking supervision in a “crisis situation” stage. As part of its micro-prudential functions, the central bank acting as lender of last resort provides assistance to a bank (or banks) suffering from a liquidity crisis. (3) The lender of last resort is a service provided by the central bank in its capacity as bankers' bank.
-
(1986)
Safe and Sound Banking: Past Present and Future
, pp. 113
-
-
Benston, G.1
-
3
-
-
85022871417
-
The Lender of Last Resort Function under a Currency Board. The Case of Argentina
-
Under a currency board arrangement, however, the LOLR role of the central bank becomes limited (in the case of a mixed central bank/currency board system) or disappears altogether. For an interesting discussion on this issue, see Sept.
-
Under a currency board arrangement, however, the LOLR role of the central bank becomes limited (in the case of a mixed central bank/currency board system) or disappears altogether. For an interesting discussion on this issue, see G. Caprio, M. Dooley, D. Leipziger and C. Walsh, “The Lender of Last Resort Function under a Currency Board. The Case of Argentina”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1648. Sept. 1996.
-
(1996)
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
, Issue.1648
-
-
Caprio, G.1
Dooley, M.2
Leipziger, D.3
Walsh, C.4
-
6
-
-
0013171289
-
The Classical Concept of the Lender of Last Resort
-
Recent studies of the work of Thornton and Bagehot on the LOLR are found in
-
Recent studies of the work of Thornton and Bagehot on the LOLR are found in T. Humphrey, “The Classical Concept of the Lender of Last Resort” (1975) 61(1) Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 8
-
(1975)
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review
, vol.61
, Issue.1
, pp. 8
-
-
Humphrey, T.1
-
8
-
-
0043245524
-
The Lender of Last Resort Some Historical Insights
-
and
-
and M. Bordo, “The Lender of Last Resort Some Historical Insights” (1990) 76(1) Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review 18.
-
(1990)
Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review
, vol.76
, Issue.1
, pp. 18
-
-
Bordo, M.1
-
9
-
-
85022795922
-
-
See “And at the rate of interest so raised, the holders–one or more–of the final Bank reserve must lend freely. Very large loans at very high rates are the best remedy for the worst malady of the Money Market when a foreign drain is added to a domestic drain.” Bagehot distinguished between actions to follow in the face of an external drain (a decline in the bank's gold reserve induced by a balance of payments deficit): raise bank rate, and actions to follow when threatened by an internal drain: lend freely
-
See Bagehot, idem, p.56: “And at the rate of interest so raised, the holders–one or more–of the final Bank reserve must lend freely. Very large loans at very high rates are the best remedy for the worst malady of the Money Market when a foreign drain is added to a domestic drain.” Bagehot distinguished between actions to follow in the face of an external drain (a decline in the bank's gold reserve induced by a balance of payments deficit): raise bank rate, and actions to follow when threatened by an internal drain: lend freely.
-
idem
, pp. 56
-
-
Bagehot1
-
11
-
-
21344481010
-
Bank Contagion: A Review of the Theory and Evidence
-
See
-
See G. Kaufman, “Bank Contagion: A Review of the Theory and Evidence” (1994) 8 J. Financial Services Research 123–150.
-
(1994)
J. Financial Services Research
, vol.8
, pp. 123-150
-
-
Kaufman, G.1
-
12
-
-
0002518681
-
Bank Failures, Systemic Risk and Bank Regulation
-
Kaufman further elaborates his views in In this latter study he concludes that “bank instability is more a regulatory phenomenon than a market phenomenon”. However, he concedes that “systemic risk may exist without government regulation” and that there may be a role for the central bank as LOLR in such a case. Furthermore, he also suggests that since the success of “macroeconomic policies to achieve stability and avoid price bubbles” is highly questionable, “backup prudential policy is desirable”
-
Kaufman further elaborates his views in “Bank Failures, Systemic Risk and Bank Regulation” (1996) 16(1) Cato Journal 39. In this latter study he concludes that “bank instability is more a regulatory phenomenon than a market phenomenon”. However, he concedes that “systemic risk may exist without government regulation” and that there may be a role for the central bank as LOLR in such a case. Furthermore, he also suggests that since the success of “macroeconomic policies to achieve stability and avoid price bubbles” is highly questionable, “backup prudential policy is desirable”.
-
(1996)
Cato Journal
, vol.16
, Issue.1
, pp. 39
-
-
-
15
-
-
85022742642
-
Banking Crises and the Macroeconomic Context”, presented at the EBRD Seminar
-
in Oct Kaufmann also notes: “Indeed the evidence for countries that do not have explicit government insurance indicates that they generally have implicit 100 percent insurance.∗’ P. Molyneux in a paper says that “everybody knows” the central bank will provide emergency liquidity assistance to what he calls “core banks”
-
Kaufmann also notes: “Indeed the evidence for countries that do not have explicit government insurance indicates that they generally have implicit 100 percent insurance.∗’ P. Molyneux in a paper, ”Banking Crises and the Macroeconomic Context”, presented at the EBRD Seminar, “Bank Failures and Bank Insolvency Law in Economies in Transition”, in Oct 1997, says that “everybody knows” the central bank will provide emergency liquidity assistance to what he calls “core banks”.
-
(1997)
Bank Failures and Bank Insolvency Law in Economies in Transition
-
-
-
16
-
-
85022839184
-
-
at have found that in all currency board regimes with no explicit LOLR, in instances of crises “some LOLR appears to have emerged”
-
Caprio et al, Discussion Paper No.239, at p.6, have found that in all currency board regimes with no explicit LOLR, in instances of crises “some LOLR appears to have emerged”.
-
Discussion Paper No.239
, pp. 6
-
-
Caprio1
-
18
-
-
85022819362
-
-
at While the test of illiquidity is rather straightforward (Le. lack of liquid funds), the test of insolvency is often more complicated. As H. Schiffman explains in the paper he presented to the Oct. 1997 EBRD Seminar (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System): “In commercial bankruptcy there are two traditional definitions of insolvency: failure to pay obligations as they fall due (equitable insolvency); and the condition when liabilities exceed assets (balance sheet insolvency).” Economists usually refer to insolvency following the balance-sheet insolvency test, i.e. when net worth is negative. (An institution may be liquid but insolvent, so long as its cash flow is positive.) However, an economically insolvent bank need not be declared legally insolvent by the responsible agency and may be offered instead financial assistance. A bank is considered to have failed when the competent authorities order the cessation in its operations and activities. If the bank is declared legally insolvent at the exact moment the market value of its net worth reaches zero, direct losses are suffered only by shareholders. If that declaration occurs when the market value of its net worth is already negative, losses will accrue not only to shareholders but also to uninsured creditors and/or to the insurance fund. See
-
While the test of illiquidity is rather straightforward (Le. lack of liquid funds), the test of insolvency is often more complicated. As H. Schiffman explains in the paper he presented to the Oct. 1997 EBRD Seminar (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System): “In commercial bankruptcy there are two traditional definitions of insolvency: failure to pay obligations as they fall due (equitable insolvency); and the condition when liabilities exceed assets (balance sheet insolvency).” Economists usually refer to insolvency following the balance-sheet insolvency test, i.e. when net worth is negative. (An institution may be liquid but insolvent, so long as its cash flow is positive.) However, an economically insolvent bank need not be declared legally insolvent by the responsible agency and may be offered instead financial assistance. A bank is considered to have failed when the competent authorities order the cessation in its operations and activities. If the bank is declared legally insolvent at the exact moment the market value of its net worth reaches zero, direct losses are suffered only by shareholders. If that declaration occurs when the market value of its net worth is already negative, losses will accrue not only to shareholders but also to uninsured creditors and/or to the insurance fund. See Lastra, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at p.135.
-
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
, pp. 135
-
-
Lastra1
-
19
-
-
0001921971
-
The Misuse of the Fed's Discount Window
-
See
-
See A. Schwartz, “The Misuse of the Fed's Discount Window” (1992) 75(4) Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review 58–69.
-
(1992)
Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review
, vol.75
, Issue.4
, pp. 58-69
-
-
Schwartz, A.1
-
20
-
-
85022873915
-
-
at As recalls: “The bank was insolvent when its borrowing began and insolvent when its borrowing ended. The loans merely replaced funds that depositors withdrew, the inflow from the Reserve Bank matching withdrawals.”
-
As Schwartz, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review, at p.64, recalls: “The bank was insolvent when its borrowing began and insolvent when its borrowing ended. The loans merely replaced funds that depositors withdrew, the inflow from the Reserve Bank matching withdrawals.”
-
Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review
, pp. 64
-
-
Schwartz1
-
23
-
-
85022838496
-
-
et seq
-
12 U.S.C. 221 et seq.
-
U.S.C
, vol.12
, pp. 221
-
-
-
24
-
-
84960482855
-
-
FDICIA was enacted on 19 Dec. 105 Stat. 2236–2393
-
FDICIA was enacted on 19 Dec. 1991, Public Law 102–242 (105 Stat. 2236–2393).
-
(1991)
Public Law
, pp. 102-242
-
-
-
25
-
-
85022869253
-
-
See Case 172/80 The Court's decision made it clear that the banking sector is exempted from the competition rules only to the extent that any anti-competitive conduct by banks is imposed on them by the monetary authorities
-
See Case 172/80 Züchner v. Bayerische Vereinsbank [1981] E.GR. 2021. The Court's decision made it clear that the banking sector is exempted from the competition rules only to the extent that any anti-competitive conduct by banks is imposed on them by the monetary authorities.
-
(1981)
E.GR
, vol.2021
-
-
-
26
-
-
85022842737
-
Study of the State Aid Policy in the European Community: The ‘Illegal’ State Aid Problem
-
Art.92 of the EC Treaty. See generally
-
Art.92 of the EC Treaty. See generally Ileana Simplicean-Stroia, “Study of the State Aid Policy in the European Community: The ‘Illegal’ State Aid Problem” (1997) 3 J.Int. Legal Studies 87.
-
(1997)
J.Int. Legal Studies
, vol.3
, pp. 87
-
-
Simplicean-Stroia, I.1
-
27
-
-
85022758105
-
-
See C166/33 (Case T-62/97)
-
See (1997) OJ. C166/33 (Case T-62/97).
-
(1997)
OJ
-
-
-
28
-
-
0003913554
-
-
21 May The applicant challenged the decision of the Commission of 26 July 1995 which gave conditional approval to the aid granted by France to Credit Lyonnais (Case T-32/96). For a recent analysis of the approval by the Commission of the latest rescue plan for Crédit Lyonnais, see p38 and 22 May 1998
-
The applicant challenged the decision of the Commission of 26 July 1995 which gave conditional approval to the aid granted by France to Credit Lyonnais (Case T-32/96). For a recent analysis of the approval by the Commission of the latest rescue plan for Crédit Lyonnais, see Financial Times, 21 May 1998, p38 and 22 May 1998, p.2.
-
(1998)
Financial Times
, pp. 2
-
-
-
29
-
-
85022788910
-
-
See European Parliament written question No.P-1216/96 by Giorgio Ruffolo on several related aspects of the application of Art.92 to banks, published on 15 Oct 1996 (19%) C305/92
-
See European Parliament written question No.P-1216/96 by Giorgio Ruffolo on several related aspects of the application of Art.92 to banks, published on 15 Oct 1996 (19%) OJ. C305/92.
-
OJ
-
-
-
30
-
-
0003913558
-
-
See 7 Oct.
-
See Financial Times,7 Oct. 1997.
-
(1997)
Financial Times
-
-
-
31
-
-
9444259761
-
The German Landesbanken”
-
For a comprehensive study of the legal status of the Landesbanken, see
-
For a comprehensive study of the legal status of the Landesbanken, see M. Gruson and U. Schneider, The German Landesbanken” (1995) Columbia Business L.Rev. 337–446.
-
(1995)
Columbia Business L.Rev
, pp. 337-446
-
-
Gruson, M.1
Schneider, U.2
-
32
-
-
0003913558
-
-
14 Oct See “An Uncertain Case for State Aid. The UK's Financial Law Panel is examining the legal position of banks.”
-
See Financial Times, 14 Oct 1997, p.15: “An Uncertain Case for State Aid. The UK's Financial Law Panel is examining the legal position of banks.”
-
(1997)
Financial Times
, pp. 15
-
-
-
33
-
-
85022761342
-
-
at See (“Who should supervise the banking business”)
-
See Lastra, Financial Times, at pp.145–156 (“Who should supervise the banking business”).
-
Financial Times
, pp. 145-156
-
-
Lastra1
-
34
-
-
84982959615
-
-
See also The relationship between the central bank and the banking system involves two distinct yet intimately related functions, for the central bank can act as “bankers' bank” and as “banking supervisor and regulator”. The boundaries between these two functions are at times blurred
-
See also Goodhart and Schoenmaker, Financial Times. The relationship between the central bank and the banking system involves two distinct yet intimately related functions, for the central bank can act as “bankers' bank” and as “banking supervisor and regulator”. The boundaries between these two functions are at times blurred.
-
Financial Times
-
-
Goodhart1
Schoenmaker2
-
35
-
-
84926273101
-
Alternatives to the Central Bank in the Developing World
-
As remarks: “The functions of banker to domestic commercial banks and of regulator of these banks' behaviour are closely linked.” The lender of last resort role of the central bank is an example of this complexity. In the UK the Bank of England has a long non-statutory tradition in its role as “bankers' bank”, but its banking supervisory functions have had a short statutory history: from 1979, when the first Banking Supervision Act was passed, to 1997, when the newly elected Labour government announced that a single financial regulatory agency was to be set up, thus stripping the Bank of its formal supervisory responsibilities (though the Bank retains its LOLR role as well as general responsibility for financial stability). It should be noted that while as “bankers' bank” the central bank typically acts as a “bank”, as formal “banking supervisor” it acts as a “public authority” with a statutory role, backed by legislation
-
As C. Collyns, “Alternatives to the Central Bank in the Developing World”, International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper No.20 (1983), p.3, remarks: “The functions of banker to domestic commercial banks and of regulator of these banks' behaviour are closely linked.” The lender of last resort role of the central bank is an example of this complexity. In the UK the Bank of England has a long non-statutory tradition in its role as “bankers' bank”, but its banking supervisory functions have had a short statutory history: from 1979, when the first Banking Supervision Act was passed, to 1997, when the newly elected Labour government announced that a single financial regulatory agency was to be set up, thus stripping the Bank of its formal supervisory responsibilities (though the Bank retains its LOLR role as well as general responsibility for financial stability). It should be noted that while as “bankers' bank” the central bank typically acts as a “bank”, as formal “banking supervisor” it acts as a “public authority” with a statutory role, backed by legislation.
-
(1983)
International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper No.20
, pp. 3
-
-
Collyns, C.1
-
36
-
-
85022789084
-
What Direction from Wallis
-
This point is emphasised by W. Hogan in his critique of the Australian Wallis Report (familiarly known as the Wallis Report) was published by the Australian Government Publishing Service in Mar. 1997
-
This point is emphasised by W. Hogan in his critique of the Australian Wallis Report “What Direction from Wallis” (1997). The Final Report of the Financial System Inquiry (familiarly known as the Wallis Report) was published by the Australian Government Publishing Service in Mar. 1997.
-
(1997)
The Final Report of the Financial System Inquiry
-
-
-
38
-
-
85022750788
-
-
For a brief exposé of the structure, goal and functions of the FS A see the released on 28 Oct.
-
For a brief exposé of the structure, goal and functions of the FS A see the “Pathfinder Prospectus” on the FSA, released on 28 Oct. 1997.
-
(1997)
“Pathfinder Prospectus” on the FSA
-
-
-
39
-
-
85022865806
-
-
Jan. For a comment and analysis on the FSA, see interview with the FSA Chairman, Howard Davies
-
For a comment and analysis on the FSA, see Parliamentary Brief, Jan. 1998, pp.28–34, interview with the FSA Chairman, Howard Davies.
-
(1998)
Parliamentary Brief
, pp. 28-34
-
-
-
40
-
-
85022826552
-
-
(d). However, “the rate applicable to such credit will be above the highest rate in effect for advances to depository institutions. Where the collateral used to secure such credit consists of assets other than obligations of, or fully guaranteed as to principal or interest by, the United States or an agency thereof, an affirmative vote of five or more members of the Board of Governors is required before credit may be extended.”
-
12 CF.R. 2013(d). However, “the rate applicable to such credit will be above the highest rate in effect for advances to depository institutions. Where the collateral used to secure such credit consists of assets other than obligations of, or fully guaranteed as to principal or interest by, the United States or an agency thereof, an affirmative vote of five or more members of the Board of Governors is required before credit may be extended.”
-
(2013)
CF.R
, vol.12
-
-
-
41
-
-
85022844263
-
-
C.F.R. revised as of 1 Jan. 1996
-
12 C.F.R. 2017 (C.F.R. revised as of 1 Jan. 1996).
-
(2017)
C.F.R
, vol.12
-
-
-
42
-
-
0003831651
-
Do We Need an International Lender of Last Resort?
-
on 5 Oct. See Sachs argues that international bankruptcy procedures modelled upon Chapters 9 and 11 of the US Bankruptcy Code would be the best response to cope with Mexican-type crises. Sachs's proposals, which include the reorganisation of the IMF to act as a kind of international bankruptcy court rather than as a lender of last resort to member governments, overlook important legal and constitutional aspects, including inter alia the difficulties of enforcing international law and the differences in national legislation regarding insolvency law and liquidation procedures. For instance, at the EC level–where a coherent degree of harmonisation has been achieved in other banking aspects–a proposed directive on the reorganisation and winding up of credit institutions is still the subject of much controversy
-
See J. Sachs, “Do We Need an International Lender of Last Resort?”, paper presented to the Study Group on Private Capital Flows to Developing and Transitional Economies at the Council of Foreign Relations on 5 Oct. 1995. Sachs argues that international bankruptcy procedures modelled upon Chapters 9 and 11 of the US Bankruptcy Code would be the best response to cope with Mexican-type crises. Sachs's proposals, which include the reorganisation of the IMF to act as a kind of international bankruptcy court rather than as a lender of last resort to member governments, overlook important legal and constitutional aspects, including inter alia the difficulties of enforcing international law and the differences in national legislation regarding insolvency law and liquidation procedures. For instance, at the EC level–where a coherent degree of harmonisation has been achieved in other banking aspects–a proposed directive on the reorganisation and winding up of credit institutions is still the subject of much controversy.
-
(1995)
paper presented to the Study Group on Private Capital Flows to Developing and Transitional Economies at the Council of Foreign Relations
-
-
Sachs, J.1
-
43
-
-
0003649962
-
Crisis? What Crisis? Orderly Workouts for Sovereign Debtors
-
A bankruptcy procedure for developing countries analagous to Chapter 11 of the US Code is also recommended in a report published by B. Eichengreen and R. Portes in 1995, under the title
-
A bankruptcy procedure for developing countries analagous to Chapter 11 of the US Code is also recommended in a report published by B. Eichengreen and R. Portes in 1995, under the title “Crisis? What Crisis? Orderly Workouts for Sovereign Debtors”, CEPR.
-
CEPR
-
-
-
44
-
-
85022744764
-
Ten Working Party's Report
-
See also the Group of May
-
See also the Group of Ten Working Party's Report, “The Resolution of Sovereign Liquidity Crises”, May 1996
-
(1996)
The Resolution of Sovereign Liquidity Crises
-
-
-
45
-
-
0009021798
-
From Halifax to Lyons: What Has Been Done about Crises Management?
-
and Oct.
-
and P. Kenen (Ed.), “From Halifax to Lyons: What Has Been Done about Crises Management?” Essays in International Finance, Oct. 1996.
-
(1996)
Essays in International Finance
-
-
Kenen, P.1
-
46
-
-
0003705116
-
-
mimeo puts the blame on bad policies and bad banking
-
P. Krugman, “Will Asia Bounce Back?”, mimeo (1998) puts the blame on bad policies and bad banking.
-
(1998)
Will Asia Bounce Back?
-
-
Krugman, P.1
-
47
-
-
0003399878
-
-
mimeo puts the blame on financial panic, therefore justifying the possible role for an international lender of last resort
-
J. Sachs and S. Radelet, “The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crises”, mimeo (1998) puts the blame on financial panic, therefore justifying the possible role for an international lender of last resort.
-
(1998)
The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crises
-
-
Sachs, J.1
Radelet, S.2
-
48
-
-
85022837599
-
-
at The 1998 World Bank Global Development Finance Report also blames the lenders. Indeed, as noted after the Mexican crisis in 1995: “If Mexico is thought to have borrowed so much, it is also fair to ask why markets were so lax in providing the financing.”
-
The 1998 World Bank Global Development Finance Report also blames the lenders. Indeed, as A. Fraga, “The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crises”, at p.53, noted after the Mexican crisis in 1995: “If Mexico is thought to have borrowed so much, it is also fair to ask why markets were so lax in providing the financing.”
-
The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crises
, pp. 53
-
-
Fraga, A.1
-
49
-
-
0003221645
-
Boats, Planes and Capital Flows
-
25 Mar. In addition, other measures to prevent future crises, such as the desirability of controls over short-term capital inflows, have also been proposed following the turmoil in East Asia. See e.g. The flows that might be subject to controls are those which exhibit four characteristics: foreign currency denominated, short-term, fixed interest, financing flows
-
In addition, other measures to prevent future crises, such as the desirability of controls over short-term capital inflows, have also been proposed following the turmoil in East Asia. See e.g. J. Stiglitz, “Boats, Planes and Capital Flows”, Financial Times, 25 Mar. 1998. The flows that might be subject to controls are those which exhibit four characteristics: foreign currency denominated, short-term, fixed interest, financing flows.
-
(1998)
Financial Times
-
-
Stiglitz, J.1
-
50
-
-
80052509906
-
The IMF and the Liberalization of Capital Markets
-
claims that the Mexican debt crisis of 1994–95 revealed some “major weaknesses in the current approach to liquidity crises”, including “the lack of adequate preventive mechanisms to detect potential liquidity crises at an early stage and avoid their occurrence or limit their magnitude”. He explains that the resolution of external debt problems due to a major capital outflow is not the responsibility of the Fund, but the responsibility of the country facing this outflow. He further argues that, though in an age of liberalisation of capital markets, these principles may seem antiquated, they are still in force and must be observed. However, it should be noted that discussions are currently under way to extend the IMF's jurisdiction to capital movements, through an amendment of the IMF Articles of Agreement
-
F. Gianviti, General Counsel of the IMF, in “The IMF and the Liberalization of Capital Markets” (1997) 19 Houston J.Int.L. 773, 774–775, claims that the Mexican debt crisis of 1994–95 revealed some “major weaknesses in the current approach to liquidity crises”, including “the lack of adequate preventive mechanisms to detect potential liquidity crises at an early stage and avoid their occurrence or limit their magnitude”. He explains that the resolution of external debt problems due to a major capital outflow is not the responsibility of the Fund, but the responsibility of the country facing this outflow. He further argues that, though in an age of liberalisation of capital markets, these principles may seem antiquated, they are still in force and must be observed. However, it should be noted that discussions are currently under way to extend the IMF's jurisdiction to capital movements, through an amendment of the IMF Articles of Agreement.
-
(1997)
Houston J.Int.L
, vol.19
-
-
-
51
-
-
85022848659
-
-
27 Apr. See e.g. S. Cross–in private correspondence–suggests that the IMF should shift more of its attention and effort to the capital side of every member's situation; as part of the surveillance process, every member would have to project the capital inflow-outflow consequence of its prospective current account position, and say how it expects to finance its forthcoming surplus/deficit, and the likely consequences for the capital markets. The IMF can then give or withhold its blessings on the member country's plans
-
See e.g. IMF Survey, 27 Apr. 1998, p.121. S. Cross–in private correspondence–suggests that the IMF should shift more of its attention and effort to the capital side of every member's situation; as part of the surveillance process, every member would have to project the capital inflow-outflow consequence of its prospective current account position, and say how it expects to finance its forthcoming surplus/deficit, and the likely consequences for the capital markets. The IMF can then give or withhold its blessings on the member country's plans.
-
(1998)
IMF Survey
, pp. 121
-
-
-
52
-
-
85022793436
-
-
30 Mar. Of course, the IMF will need to strike a fine balance between its role as a confidential adviser to members and its potential role as an international financial watchdog see This debate at an international level resembles the domestic debate in the UK in the 1970s when the Bank of England, till then an honest broker for commercial banks in its capacity as “bankers' bank”, also adopted a more formal role as bank supervisor, with the passage of the 1979 Banking Act
-
Of course, the IMF will need to strike a fine balance between its role as a confidential adviser to members and its potential role as an international financial watchdog (see Financial Tunes, 30 Mar. 1998, p.3). This debate at an international level resembles the domestic debate in the UK in the 1970s when the Bank of England, till then an honest broker for commercial banks in its capacity as “bankers' bank”, also adopted a more formal role as bank supervisor, with the passage of the 1979 Banking Act
-
(1998)
Financial Tunes
, pp. 3
-
-
-
53
-
-
0347048439
-
Crises Prevention and Management: Lessons from Mexico
-
at in Kenen (Ed.) has indicated that the IMF should act as “the permanent auditor of countries, who should voluntarily submit themselves to examination in order to lower their borrowing costs”. Fraga also proposes that Art.IV consultations be supplemented by quarterly reviews to enhance the credibility of the data released under the IMFs initiatives on better disclosure of country data (i.e. the special and general data dissemination initiatives)
-
A. Fraga, “Crises Prevention and Management: Lessons from Mexico”, in Kenen (Ed.), Financial Tunes, at p.54, has indicated that the IMF should act as “the permanent auditor of countries, who should voluntarily submit themselves to examination in order to lower their borrowing costs”. Fraga also proposes that Art.IV consultations be supplemented by quarterly reviews to enhance the credibility of the data released under the IMFs initiatives on better disclosure of country data (i.e. the special and general data dissemination initiatives).
-
Financial Tunes
, pp. 54
-
-
Fraga, A.1
-
54
-
-
85022750045
-
-
7 May in his remarks before the refers to cross-border inter-bank funding as “potentially the Achilles' heel of the international financial system” and a “significant source of systemic risk”. He points out that “creditor banks expect claims on banks, especially banks in emerging economies, to be protected by a safety net and, consequently, consider them to be essentially sovereign claims”. He suggests that some sort of discipline should be imposed on creditor and debtor banks: “For example, capital requirements could be raised on borrowing banks by making the required level of capital dependent not just on the nature of the bank's assets but also on the nature of their funding. An increase in required capital can be thought of as providing a larger cushion for the sovereign guarantor in the event of a bank's failure… Alternatively, the issue of moral hazard in interbank markets could be addressed by charging banks for the existence of the sovereign guarantee, particularly in more vulnerable countries where that guarantee is more likely to be called upon and whose cost might deter some aberrant borrowing. For example, sovereigns could charge an explicit premium, or could impose reserve requirements, earning low or even zero interests rates, on interbank liabilities. Increasing the capital charge on lending banks, instead of on borrowing banks, might also be effective. Under the Basle capital accord, short-term claims on banks from any country carry only a twenty percent risk weight. The higher cost to the lending banks associated with a higher risk weight would presumably be passed on to the borrowing banks.”
-
A. Greenspan, in his remarks before the 34th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 7 May 1998, refers to cross-border inter-bank funding as “potentially the Achilles' heel of the international financial system” and a “significant source of systemic risk”. He points out that “creditor banks expect claims on banks, especially banks in emerging economies, to be protected by a safety net and, consequently, consider them to be essentially sovereign claims”. He suggests that some sort of discipline should be imposed on creditor and debtor banks: “For example, capital requirements could be raised on borrowing banks by making the required level of capital dependent not just on the nature of the bank's assets but also on the nature of their funding. An increase in required capital can be thought of as providing a larger cushion for the sovereign guarantor in the event of a bank's failure… Alternatively, the issue of moral hazard in interbank markets could be addressed by charging banks for the existence of the sovereign guarantee, particularly in more vulnerable countries where that guarantee is more likely to be called upon and whose cost might deter some aberrant borrowing. For example, sovereigns could charge an explicit premium, or could impose reserve requirements, earning low or even zero interests rates, on interbank liabilities. Increasing the capital charge on lending banks, instead of on borrowing banks, might also be effective. Under the Basle capital accord, short-term claims on banks from any country carry only a twenty percent risk weight. The higher cost to the lending banks associated with a higher risk weight would presumably be passed on to the borrowing banks.”
-
(1998)
34th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
-
-
Greenspan, A.1
-
55
-
-
0003913554
-
-
5 Mar. M. Feldstein in an article published in the (“Trying to do too much”) claims that if the purpose of the IMF packages for Korea, Thailand and Indonesia was “to act as a lender of last resort in order to stop financial panics and the runs by creditors, the IMF's funds would have had to be available for immediate disbursal, not held back until these countries demonstrated their willingness to carry out major structural reforms”
-
M. Feldstein in an article published in the Financial Times, 5 Mar. 1998 (“Trying to do too much”) claims that if the purpose of the IMF packages for Korea, Thailand and Indonesia was “to act as a lender of last resort in order to stop financial panics and the runs by creditors, the IMF's funds would have had to be available for immediate disbursal, not held back until these countries demonstrated their willingness to carry out major structural reforms”.
-
(1998)
Financial Times
-
-
-
56
-
-
85022855539
-
Financial Times Survey
-
See 27 Apr.
-
See Financial Times Survey, “Asian Financial Markets”, 27 Apr. 1998, p.33.
-
(1998)
Asian Financial Markets
, pp. 33
-
-
-
57
-
-
85022759755
-
-
12 Jan. See This facility has at the international level some of the features that Thornton and Bagehot described for the LOLR at the domestic level. It should be noted that both Thornton and Bagehot wrote their important contributions to the understanding of the LOLR in the 19th century, when crises were mostly confined to the national arena
-
See IMF Survey, 12 Jan. 1998, p.7. This facility has at the international level some of the features that Thornton and Bagehot described for the LOLR at the domestic level. It should be noted that both Thornton and Bagehot wrote their important contributions to the understanding of the LOLR in the 19th century, when crises were mostly confined to the national arena.
-
(1998)
IMF Survey
, pp. 7
-
-
-
58
-
-
85022850481
-
-
See The IMF also intends to bring to completion at an early date ongoing studies of mechanisms that could effectively limit the need for official financing in cases of crisis of market confidence
-
See IMF Survey. The IMF also intends to bring to completion at an early date ongoing studies of mechanisms that could effectively limit the need for official financing in cases of crisis of market confidence.
-
IMF Survey
-
-
-
59
-
-
0001635726
-
Conditionality: Past, Present and Future
-
argues in International Monetary Fund, Dec. 1995, that the interpretation of conditionality is not independent of the international economic regime in place
-
M. Guitián argues in “Conditionality: Past, Present and Future”, Staff Papers, Vol.42, No.4, International Monetary Fund, Dec. 1995, that the interpretation of conditionality is not independent of the international economic regime in place.
-
Staff Papers
, vol.42
, Issue.4
-
-
Guitián, M.1
-
60
-
-
85037391341
-
-
15 Dec. See for the approval of the Korean arrangement, IMF Survey, 17 Nov. 1997 for the approval of the Indonesian stand-by arrangement, and IMF Survey, 17 Sept 1997, for the approval of the Thai stand-by arrangement
-
See IMF Survey, 15 Dec. 1997 for the approval of the Korean arrangement, IMF Survey, 17 Nov. 1997 for the approval of the Indonesian stand-by arrangement, and IMF Survey, 17 Sept 1997, for the approval of the Thai stand-by arrangement.
-
(1997)
IMF Survey
-
-
-
61
-
-
85022824044
-
-
at himself a managing director of Soros Fund Management, notes: “investors behave myopically, each one perhaps thinking that it will be possible to exit ahead of the rest Moral hazard on the part of investment bankers (who hope to earn underwriting fees) and of Wall Street traders and mutual fund managers (who are paid bonuses every year) also helps to explain the Mexican case.” Feldstein, IMF Survey, also claims that “using IMF funds to pay off loans to private creditors weakens the incentive of lenders to be cautious in future international lending”
-
Fraga, IMF Survey, at p.53, himself a managing director of Soros Fund Management, notes: “investors behave myopically, each one perhaps thinking that it will be possible to exit ahead of the rest Moral hazard on the part of investment bankers (who hope to earn underwriting fees) and of Wall Street traders and mutual fund managers (who are paid bonuses every year) also helps to explain the Mexican case.” Feldstein, IMF Survey, also claims that “using IMF funds to pay off loans to private creditors weakens the incentive of lenders to be cautious in future international lending”.
-
IMF Survey
, pp. 53
-
-
Fraga1
-
62
-
-
0008644779
-
Capital Punishment
-
17 Mar. As M Wolf explains in an article “If a commercial bank in Thailand borrows dollars, no central bank will provide it with the currency they may need. Similarly, if Thailand as a country borrows dollars, there is no lender of last resort to assist it if creditors suddenly want their money back. The IMF–which cannot print US$–lacks the resources to perform this role.”
-
As M Wolf explains in an article, “Capital Punishment”, Financial Times, 17 Mar. 1998: “If a commercial bank in Thailand borrows dollars, no central bank will provide it with the currency they may need. Similarly, if Thailand as a country borrows dollars, there is no lender of last resort to assist it if creditors suddenly want their money back. The IMF–which cannot print US$–lacks the resources to perform this role.”
-
(1998)
Financial Times
-
-
-
63
-
-
0043055214
-
-
27 Mar. See If investors remain free to make off with their winnings, they should also pick up the tab for their losses
-
See JP Morgan, “World Financial Markets”, 27 Mar. 1998, p.13. If investors remain free to make off with their winnings, they should also pick up the tab for their losses.
-
(1998)
World Financial Markets
, pp. 13
-
-
Morgan, J.P.1
-
64
-
-
85037493098
-
-
The liquid resources of the IMF consist of usable currencies and SDRs held in the General Resources Account. When supplementary resources are needed to prevent or cope with a crisis the IMF can borrow under the General Arrangement to Borrow (credit lines from 11 industrial countries), an associated agreement with Saudi Arabia, and under the recently created New Arrangement to Borrow (credit line with 25 participant countries). The IMF can also get more resources through an increase in quotas and through an SDR allocation (provision of international reserves to its members in proportion to their quotas). The last increase in quotas–by 45%–was approved by the IMF Board of Governors on 23 Dec. 1997. See 12 Jan.
-
The liquid resources of the IMF consist of usable currencies and SDRs held in the General Resources Account. When supplementary resources are needed to prevent or cope with a crisis the IMF can borrow under the General Arrangement to Borrow (credit lines from 11 industrial countries), an associated agreement with Saudi Arabia, and under the recently created New Arrangement to Borrow (credit line with 25 participant countries). The IMF can also get more resources through an increase in quotas and through an SDR allocation (provision of international reserves to its members in proportion to their quotas). The last increase in quotas–by 45%–was approved by the IMF Board of Governors on 23 Dec. 1997. See IMF Survey, 12 Jan. 1998, p.7.
-
(1998)
IMF Survey
, pp. 7
-
-
-
65
-
-
0004098466
-
-
As reminds us: “The record [in financial markets] shows displacement, euphoria, distress, panic and crises occurring decade after decade, century after century.”
-
As G Kindleberger, A Financial History of Western Europe (1984), p.273, reminds us: “The record [in financial markets] shows displacement, euphoria, distress, panic and crises occurring decade after decade, century after century.”
-
(1984)
A Financial History of Western Europe
, pp. 273
-
-
Kindleberger, G.1
-
66
-
-
0343832875
-
Global Payments Bodies to Merge
-
Sec e.g. 1 Oct.
-
Sec e.g. Financial Times, 1 Oct. 1997, “Global Payments Bodies to Merge”.
-
(1997)
Financial Times
-
-
|