메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 55, Issue 4, 2001, Pages 761-799

The rational design of international institutions

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0040162255     PISSN: 00208183     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1162/002081801317193592     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (1413)

References (105)
  • 1
    • 85009872187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Abbott et al. 2000; and Koremenos 2000
    • See Abbott et al. 2000; and Koremenos 2000.
  • 2
    • 85009879870 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For related definitions of international institutions, see Keohane 1984; and Young 1994
    • For related definitions of international institutions, see Keohane 1984; and Young 1994.
  • 3
    • 85009872184 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Martin and Simmons assess past work on international institutions and propose an agenda focused on explaining causal mechanisms and institutional effects. Martin and Simmons 1998. Their framework complements ours and shows how rational choice can address other important empirical questions.
  • 4
    • 85009859550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The early issues of International Organization, for example, focused on describing newly formed organizations and publicizing their rules and votes.
  • 5
    • 85009934429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Krasner 1983
    • Krasner 1983.
  • 6
    • 85009927104 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oye 1986; and Axelrod 1984
    • See Oye 1986; and Axelrod 1984.
  • 7
    • 0004318696 scopus 로고
    • Key works are Stephen Krasner's edited volume International Regimes (1983) and Robert Keohane's After Hegemony (1984). An excellent early overview is Haggard and Simmons 1987. Several commentators have noted that the field has had less and less to say about formal international organizations. See Rochester 1986; and Abbott and Snidal 1998.
    • (1983) International Regimes
    • Krasner', S.1
  • 8
    • 0004027370 scopus 로고
    • An excellent early overview is Haggard and Simmons 1987. Several commentators have noted that the field has had less and less to say about formal international organizations. See Rochester 1986; and Abbott and Snidal 1998
    • Key works are Stephen Krasner's edited volume International Regimes (1983) and Robert Keohane's After Hegemony (1984). An excellent early overview is Haggard and Simmons 1987. Several commentators have noted that the field has had less and less to say about formal international organizations. See Rochester 1986; and Abbott and Snidal 1998.
    • (1984) After Hegemony
    • Keohane's, R.1
  • 9
    • 85009846593 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Friedman 1971; and Fudenberg and Maskin 1986
    • See Friedman 1971; and Fudenberg and Maskin 1986.
  • 10
    • 85009927102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Notable exceptions are crises where immediate incentives overwhelm longer-term considerations. We set such situations aside.
  • 11
    • 85009879883 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Snidal 1985; and Stein 1983
    • See Snidal 1985; and Stein 1983.
  • 12
    • 85009909640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Krasner 1991; Morrow 1994c; and Fearon 1998
    • See Krasner 1991; Morrow 1994c; and Fearon 1998.
  • 13
    • 85009835396 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Oye 1986; and Lipson 1986 for an application
    • See Oye 1986; and Lipson 1986 for an application.
  • 14
    • 85009879880 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This point was foreshadowed by Downs, Rocke, and Siverson in their analysis of arms races, and by Downs and Rocke in their game-theoretic analysis of the limits to cooperation. See Downs, Rocke, and Siverson 1986; and Downs and Rocke 1990.
  • 15
    • 85009835397 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keohane 1984; and Morrow 1994c
    • See Keohane 1984; and Morrow 1994c.
  • 16
    • 85009883847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On noise, see Downs and Rocke 1990. On large numbers, see Pahre 1994
    • On noise, see Downs and Rocke 1990. On large numbers, see Pahre 1994.
  • 17
    • 85009859351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keohane 1984; and Axelrod and Keohane 1986
    • See Keohane 1984; and Axelrod and Keohane 1986.
  • 18
    • 85009927114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Chayes and Chayes 1995; and Mitchell 1994
    • See Chayes and Chayes 1995; and Mitchell 1994.
  • 19
    • 85009908008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our proposed conjectures are consistent with an evolutionary perspective that treats rational designs as superior in the sense of providing greater benefits to participants, even if participants are unwitting beneficiaries. Miles Kahler provides an excellent overview and discussion of the relationship between evolutionary and rational theories of international institutions. Kahler 1999. The two approaches begin to align through such concepts as "learning" and "imitation" as key factors underlying institutional development.
  • 20
    • 85009867431 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, many efforts at institutional design fail. States may misunderstand the circumstances they face or wrongly anticipate how actors will respond to institutional innovations, or simply make mistakes.
  • 21
    • 85009880301 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schrader 1996
    • See Schrader 1996.
  • 22
    • 85009884705 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The converse is not true, and not all equilibria are institutions as we define them. In particular we exclude equilibria resulting from tacit bargains and implicit arrangements that arise without negotiation.
  • 23
    • 85009908002 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Calvert 1995; Morrow 1994c; and Snidal 1997
    • See Calvert 1995; Morrow 1994c; and Snidal 1997.
  • 24
    • 85009846575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A parallel and important implication within rational institutional design is that all relevant "margins" of choice must be considered. Barzel 1989. In John Richards' analysis of international airline regulation in this volume, for example, effective agreements on airline fares also require that airlines be prohibited from competing on other margins, such as food quality or seat comfort.
  • 25
    • 85009868108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Haas 1980
    • Haas 1980.
  • 26
    • 85009909621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Moravcsik 1991
    • Moravcsik 1991.
  • 27
    • 85009927106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Kenen 1995; and Moravcsik 1998
    • See Kenen 1995; and Moravcsik 1998.
  • 28
    • 85009845247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oye 1986
    • Oye 1986.
  • 29
    • 85009883853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Alternatively, states will not waste time designing institutions that will not be enforced by their own incentives.
  • 30
    • 85009859558 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In particular, once the games are complicated even slightly, the clean distinctions among them break down. When Prisoners' Dilemma repeats through time, for example, multiple equilibria emerge, and the supergame contains distributional problems. Similarly, recurring Battle of the Sexes problems create incentives for some states to shift the prevailing equilibrium.
  • 31
    • 85009868109 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Krasner 1991; and Grieco 1988
    • See Krasner 1991; and Grieco 1988.
  • 32
    • 85009934418 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • James Fearon makes a parallel argument that, at a sufficiently general level, all problems in international relations have a common strategic structure. Fearon 1998. States must choose among the range of available cooperative arrangements and ensure that participants will adhere to the chosen arrangement. We label these the "distribution problem" and the "enforcement problem," respectively.
  • 33
    • 85009879859 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We asked contributors to examine these independent variables but also invited them to consider others; thus the project as a whole is open to a wider set of independent variables, albeit in a more inductive way.
  • 34
    • 85009846572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Krasner 1991
    • Krasner 1991.
  • 35
    • 85009927094 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fearon 1998
    • Fearon 1998.
  • 36
    • 85009934428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Webb 1991
    • Webb 1991.
  • 37
    • 85009859540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Snidal 1994
    • Snidal 1994.
  • 38
    • 85009879860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Levy 1993
    • Levy 1993.
  • 39
    • 85009934422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We do adopt standard terminology in using the term uncertainty instead of risk. See, for example, Kreps 1990; Hirshleifer and Riley 1992; and Osborne and Rubinstein 1994.
  • 40
    • 85009868106 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Interaction effects may be positive, negative, or zero - that is, when two "problems" arise together in a given context, their joint effect may be less than either problem individually (a large negative effect) or more than either problem individually but less than the sum of the two (a small negative effect). Alternatively, the combined effect may equal the sum of the two individual effects (a zero interaction effect) or be greater than the sum of the individual effects (a positive interaction effect).
  • 41
    • 85009927082 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 1999a
    • Koremenos 1999a.
  • 42
    • 85009883843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We thank Jim Morrow for this example, which corresponds to a comparison of conjectures M1 and M2.
  • 43
    • 85009859544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We focus on states as key actors, though most of the analysis can be generalized to nonstate actors.
  • 44
    • 85009909627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, harsher punishment strategies can be used to support greater cooperation when the shadow of the future is short; however, such strategies are subject to problems of renegotiation proofness. See Downs and Rocke 1995; and Abreu, Pearce, and Stacchetti 1986.
  • 45
    • 85009868113 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a general discussion of transaction costs, see Williamson 1985. For an important application to international politics, see Lake 1996. Unlike Williamson, we do not assume that the presence of transaction costs implies bounded rationality. Transaction costs refers to the costs of making an agreement and operating it, not of doing what the agreement is designed to do (for example, if two states agree to jointly build a dam, the costs of negotiating and administering the agreement are transactions costs, but the costs of building the dam are not).
  • 46
    • 85009846582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Williamson 1985; and Yarbrough and Yarbrough 1992
    • See Williamson 1985; and Yarbrough and Yarbrough 1992.
  • 47
    • 85009927095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lake 1996
    • Lake 1996.
  • 48
    • 85009883844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Morrow 1991
    • Morrow 1991.
  • 49
    • 85009888782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Olson 1965
    • Olson 1965.
  • 50
    • 85009859346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Oye 1986. Pahre points out that under strict public good conditions, such restrictions are suboptimal. Pahre 1994. He demonstrates the possibility of large-n multilateral cooperation under certain conditions. But unlike conjecture M1, his equilibrium is vulnerable to bad information, and it needs other institutional supports that we discuss under conjectures C1-C3.
  • 51
    • 85009868115 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Buchanan 1965
    • Buchanan 1965.
  • 52
    • 85009930232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Snidal 1979
    • Snidal 1979.
  • 53
    • 85009909696 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Downs and Rocke 1995, 126
    • Downs and Rocke 1995, 126.
  • 54
    • 85009901510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Spence 1974 illustrates how education provides a costly signal of the quality of prospective employees to employers. Spence 1974. Fearon applies signaling models to crisis bargaining. Fearon 1994. See also Kydd 2000a, b.
  • 55
    • 85009934488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Waltz 1979; and Grieco 1988
    • See Waltz 1979; and Grieco 1988.
  • 56
    • 85009859603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Snidal 1991
    • Snidal 1991.
  • 57
    • 85009934508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We do not claim that heterogeneity promotes cooperation; in some cases it promotes distributional differences and conflict. Our position is that linkage provides an institutional means to harness these differences in a mutually beneficial way. Also, having a larger number may promote heterogeneity in capabilities (which we do not address here). For an insightful discussion of these points that also relates heterogeneity to institutional design, see Martin 1994.
  • 58
    • 85009906324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sebenius 1983, 314
    • Sebenius 1983, 314.
  • 59
    • 85009846639 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In some cases, membership may act as a mediating variable through which number affects endogenous variables such as scope. Even in such cases, number may also have direct effects, perhaps due to asymmetries among the parties, for which member is not a mediating variable. This complexity is typical in a system with multiple dependent (or endogenous) and independent (or exogenous) variables. Our conjectures focus on the impact of individual independent variables' main effects and thus hold the other independent variables constant, but not the other dependent variables.
  • 60
    • 85009909697 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tollison and Willett 1979
    • Tollison and Willett 1979.
  • 61
    • 85009872229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Conjectures S1 and S2, though distinct, share a similar logic. In each case differences among the actors lead them to expand the issue set in order to find a better outcome. In this way, distributional differences (which cause conflict within issues) are the engine of efficiency gains (across issues). For an instructive analogy in the social-choice literature on logrolling, see Mueller 1989. Logrolling, however, occurs within an institutional framework and thus can lead to Pareto-inefficient moves. Riker and Brams 1973. We would not expect this in the design of new institutional arrangements.
  • 62
    • 85009867478 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001a
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001a.
  • 63
    • 85009906314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Raiffa 1982
    • Raiffa 1982.
  • 64
    • 85009845294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Hardin 1982; McGinnis 1986; and Bernheim and Whinston 1990. A more nuanced version of this conjecture would consider the interrelationships among the issues, for example, whether they are substitutes or complements. See Spagnolo 1997.
  • 65
    • 85009883906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001a
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001a.
  • 66
    • 85009930240 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Thus our independent variables may affect the costs as well as the benefits of scope.
  • 67
    • 85009901507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kreps 1990
    • Kreps 1990.
  • 68
    • 85009846633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Downs and Rocke 1990
    • Downs and Rocke 1990.
  • 69
    • 85009901504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axelrod and Keohane 1986
    • Axelrod and Keohane 1986.
  • 70
    • 85009883896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Milgrom, North, and Weingast 1990
    • Milgrom, North, and Weingast 1990.
  • 71
    • 85009934487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Morrow 1994c; and Farrell and Gibbons 1989. The parallel relationship that centralization increases to resolve uncertainty about other states' preferences or types is also likely to hold. The very willingness to allow centralized inspection by an organization like the IAEA contains useful information about a state's goals even before it generates any information about its behavior.
  • 72
    • 85009906313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Keohane 1984; and Martin 1992a
    • See Keohane 1984; and Martin 1992a.
  • 73
    • 85009890820 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abbott and Snidal 1998
    • Abbott and Snidal 1998.
  • 74
    • 85009845270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calvert 1995
    • Calvert 1995.
  • 75
    • 85009927150 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Bates 1997; and Koremenos 1999a
    • See Bates 1997; and Koremenos 1999a.
  • 76
    • 85009859591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Genschel 1997; and Abbott and Snidal 2001
    • See Genschel 1997; and Abbott and Snidal 2001.
  • 77
    • 85009930224 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fudenberg and Maskin 1986
    • Fudenberg and Maskin 1986.
  • 78
    • 85009835458 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Bendor and Mookherjee 1987 and 1997. Bendor and Mookherjee offer a differentiated view of centralization and show how a combination (federalism) of centralized and decentralized arrangements is most effective for the problem they are examining. Ostrom provides evidence of how small levels of centralization can promote otherwise decentralized cooperation. Ostrom 1990.
  • 79
    • 85009868142 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Using similar logic, Lake argues that "the probability that the partner will engage in opportunistic behavior decreases with relational hierarchy." Lake 1996, 14. In other words, as the expected costs of opportunism increase, hierarchy will be the preferred governance structure.
  • 80
    • 85009846646 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Schwartz and Tomz show that the value of centralization does not always increase monotonically with the capacity of the central agent. Schwartz and Tomz 1997. In their model, an intermediate level of monitoring means that some shirking will occur so that less talented actors are detected and excluded from the group.
  • 81
    • 85009890818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Posner 1999
    • Posner 1999.
  • 82
    • 85009835456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Martin 1992b
    • Martin 1992b.
  • 83
    • 85009915525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Number here refers to members of the institution who are eligible to have a say in its operations. This is a good example of our earlier observation that a prior institutional decision may be treated as exogenous in considering the adoption of other rules. Alternatively, membership and control rules may be determined together such that, for example, a decision to have a large membership is compatible with one set of control rules, and a decision to have a small membership is compatible with another set of control rules.
  • 84
    • 85009883877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hosli 1993
    • Hosli 1993.
  • 85
    • 85009934468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A more sophisticated analysis would also consider the policy preferences of governments. Garrett and Tsebelis show how this leads to a consideration of a broader set of control institutions (for example, the Commission and the Council of Ministers) and to rules regarding other forms of control, such as agenda setting. Garrett and Tsebelis 1996.
  • 86
    • 85009915524 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Barry 1979. See also the Rae-Taylor theorem in Rae 1969; and Taylor 1969. Mueller provides an excellent overview of the issues and a comparison of majority/unanimity rules. Mueller 1989. Buchanan and Tullock argue for the virtues of unanimity in promoting efficient outcomes when there are no transaction costs. Buchanan and Tullock 1962. As decision-making costs increase - including the costs of preference revelation (which corresponds to uncertainty about preferences) - the case for smaller majorities grows.
  • 87
    • 85009835446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shubik 1982
    • Shubik 1982.
  • 88
    • 85009908038 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Winter 1996
    • Winter 1996.
  • 89
    • 85009880327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Weingast 1979
    • Weingast 1979.
  • 90
    • 85009859589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collie 1988
    • Collie 1988.
  • 91
    • 85009883879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We proposed but later dropped the related conjecture that "individual control (to block undesirable outcomes) increases with the severity of the distributional problem" because it was logically equivalent to conjecture V3. The impact of distribution flowed fundamentally from uncertainty about the distribution rather than from known distributional consequences, which could be dealt with in other institutional ways. The deleted conjecture was strongly supported in the empirical studies, so dropping it does not bias the results in our favor.
  • 92
    • 85009901495 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Downs and Rocke 1995
    • Downs and Rocke 1995.
  • 93
    • 85009930226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 2001
    • Koremenos 2001.
  • 94
    • 85009883887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This kind of flexibility also solved important distributional issues, the subject of conjecture F2.
  • 95
    • 85009909686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abbott and Snidal 2000
    • Abbott and Snidal 2000.
  • 96
    • 85009872217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fearon 1998
    • Fearon 1998.
  • 97
    • 85009867463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 2001
    • Koremenos 2001.
  • 98
    • 85009848725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001b
    • Busch and Koremenos 2001b.
  • 99
    • 85009880332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hardin 1992
    • Hardin 1992.
  • 100
    • 85009909689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 1999a
    • Koremenos 1999a.
  • 101
    • 85009883891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a theoretical analysis with corresponding empirical support, see Koremenos 2000.
  • 102
    • 85009927369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The choice among alternatives may also depend on interactions with other independent variables. Thus, the WTO's move toward more centralized dispute resolution was related to the large number of states involved.
  • 103
    • 85009909662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This problem has been central to the analysis of macroeconomic policy in open economies, especially the relationship between the number of policy goals and the number of policy instruments. Mundell 1962.
  • 104
    • 85009835421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This problem would bias the empirical results against our bivariate conjectures.
  • 105
    • 85009868141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Aggarwal 1985
    • Aggarwal 1985.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.