-
1
-
-
0014413249
-
The tragedy of the commons: The population problem has no solution; it requires a fundamental extension in morality
-
This phrase comes from the title of Garrett Hardin's now well-known essay "The Tragedy of the Commons: The Population Problem Has No Solution; It Requires a Fundamental Extension in Morality," Science 162 (1968), 1243-48.
-
(1968)
Science
, vol.162
, pp. 1243-1248
-
-
-
2
-
-
0002707919
-
The economics of environmental degradation: Problems, causes and responses
-
Anil Markandya and Julie Richardson, eds., London: Earthscan
-
It should be noted that market failure does not always lead to inefficiency or environmental degradation. Nor does it always lead to inefficiency. For an examination of nine causes of market failure that lead to both inefficiency and environmental degradation see T. Panayotou, "The Economics of Environmental Degradation: Problems, Causes and Responses," in Anil Markandya and Julie Richardson, eds., The Earthscan Reader in Environmental Economics (London: Earthscan, 1992).
-
(1992)
The Earthscan Reader in Environmental Economics
-
-
Panayotou, T.1
-
4
-
-
0028591144
-
'sustainable development': Is it a useful concept?
-
In fact, privatarian arguments imply that efficiency is the same thing as sustainability. There is also evidence in the environmental economics literature that maximization of value is not only a necessary but a sufficient condition for the achievement of sustainability. It is my view that this is mistaken. Accordingly, I have distinguished efficiency from sustainability. This is similar to the distinction made between efficiency and optimality. Efficiency is concerned only with the conservation of inputs and the maximization of outputs. Optimality is an ethical concept and is concerned with the ethically acceptable distribution of resources. There are many different types of optimality. Pareto optimality is the most famous, but there have been many modifications to this, including the Kaldor-Hicks criteria which slackens the Pareto criteria by allowing projects to proceed that increase aggregate value without necessarily compensating those made worse off. It is not yet the best way to resolve moral problems of optimality. Sustainability's ethical content is thought primarily to be located in the concern for resource allocation (especially to future generations). Sustainability is also beset with the same kinds of problems that have beset optimality. Some argue that sustainability is a superfluous concept that merely duplicates the ideas of welfare economics (Wilfred Beckerman, "'Sustainable Development': Is It a Useful Concept?" Environmental Values 3 [1994], 191-209). Others argue that sustainability is another excuse for more (environmentally damaging) government intervention (Thomas J. DiLorenzo, "The Mirage of Sustainable Development," The Futurist, September/October 1993, 14-19). Still others are working to develop its capacity to provide ethical guidance concerning resource use and future generations. In any case, it is clear that efficiency is not the same thing as sustainability, given its ethical requirements.
-
(1994)
Environmental Values
, vol.3
, pp. 191-209
-
-
Beckerman, W.1
-
5
-
-
85050708915
-
The mirage of sustainable development
-
September/October
-
In fact, privatarian arguments imply that efficiency is the same thing as sustainability. There is also evidence in the environmental economics literature that maximization of value is not only a necessary but a sufficient condition for the achievement of sustainability. It is my view that this is mistaken. Accordingly, I have distinguished efficiency from sustainability. This is similar to the distinction made between efficiency and optimality. Efficiency is concerned only with the conservation of inputs and the maximization of outputs. Optimality is an ethical concept and is concerned with the ethically acceptable distribution of resources. There are many different types of optimality. Pareto optimality is the most famous, but there have been many modifications to this, including the Kaldor-Hicks criteria which slackens the Pareto criteria by allowing projects to proceed that increase aggregate value without necessarily compensating those made worse off. It is not yet the best way to resolve moral problems of optimality. Sustainability's ethical content is thought primarily to be located in the concern for resource allocation (especially to future generations). Sustainability is also beset with the same kinds of problems that have beset optimality. Some argue that sustainability is a superfluous concept that merely duplicates the ideas of welfare economics (Wilfred Beckerman, "'Sustainable Development': Is It a Useful Concept?" Environmental Values 3 [1994], 191-209). Others argue that sustainability is another excuse for more (environmentally damaging) government intervention (Thomas J. DiLorenzo, "The Mirage of Sustainable Development," The Futurist, September/October 1993, 14-19). Still others are working to develop its capacity to provide ethical guidance concerning resource use and future generations. In any case, it is clear that efficiency is not the same thing as sustainability, given its ethical requirements.
-
(1993)
The Futurist
, pp. 14-19
-
-
DiLorenzo, T.J.1
-
6
-
-
84974307338
-
The property rights paradigm
-
Hereafter, "privatarian" approaches. Another way of characterizing privatarianism is as "the property rights theory of externalities" or the "property rights paradigm" (as in A. A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm," Journal of Economic History 33 [1973], 16-27). However, there is one important difference: the privatarians argue that not just proper assignment of property rights is necessary for conservation to be effective, but that individual property rights are necessary. This obviates the recognition of a group as a sufficient locus of ownership.
-
(1973)
Journal of Economic History
, vol.33
, pp. 16-27
-
-
Alchian, A.A.1
Demsetz, H.2
-
16
-
-
0001394870
-
Towards a theory of property rights
-
Harold Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights," American Economic Review 57 (1967), 347-59.
-
(1967)
American Economic Review
, vol.57
, pp. 347-359
-
-
Demsetz, H.1
-
17
-
-
0002214922
-
The structure of a contract theory of a nonexclusive resource
-
S. N. Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory of a Nonexclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics 13 (1970), 49-70.
-
(1970)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.13
, pp. 49-70
-
-
Cheung, S.N.1
-
18
-
-
0000540638
-
The development of individual rights to property in Tribal Africa
-
D. E. Ault and G. L. Rutman, "The Development of Individual Rights to Property in Tribal Africa," Journal of Law and Economics 22 (1979), 163-82.
-
(1979)
Journal of Law and Economics
, vol.22
, pp. 163-182
-
-
Ault, D.E.1
Rutman, G.L.2
-
19
-
-
1842769438
-
Testing for common versus private property: Comment
-
For example, D. W. Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property: Comment," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 21 (1991), 92-96; E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Fikret Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development (London: Belhaven Press, 1989); and G. G. Stevenson, Common Property Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).
-
(1991)
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
, vol.21
, pp. 92-96
-
-
Bromley, D.W.1
-
20
-
-
85040890266
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
For example, D. W. Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property: Comment," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 21 (1991), 92-96; E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Fikret Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development (London: Belhaven Press, 1989); and G. G. Stevenson, Common Property Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).
-
(1990)
Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action
-
-
Ostrom, E.1
-
21
-
-
85040883044
-
-
London: Belhaven Press
-
For example, D. W. Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property: Comment," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 21 (1991), 92-96; E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Fikret Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development (London: Belhaven Press, 1989); and G. G. Stevenson, Common Property Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).
-
(1989)
Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community-based Sustainable Development
-
-
Berkes, F.1
-
22
-
-
1842769438
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
For example, D. W. Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property: Comment," Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 21 (1991), 92-96; E. Ostrom, Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990); Fikret Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development (London: Belhaven Press, 1989); and G. G. Stevenson, Common Property Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).
-
(1991)
Common Property Economics
-
-
Stevenson, G.G.1
-
23
-
-
0039280209
-
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
Common Property Economics
-
-
-
24
-
-
85050784424
-
Of mice and meadows: Strategies of Alpine land use
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1972)
Anthropological Quarterly
, vol.45
, pp. 132-144
-
-
Netting, R.McC.1
-
25
-
-
0000865577
-
Common property as a concept in natural resource policy
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1975)
Natural Resources Journal
, vol.15
, pp. 713-727
-
-
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V.1
Bishop, R.C.2
-
26
-
-
0009247155
-
Property rights and access management in the small boat fishery: A case study from Southwest Nova Scotia
-
Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1984)
Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-making Case Studies
-
-
Davis, A.1
-
27
-
-
0003797054
-
-
Tucson: University of Arizona Press
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1987)
The Question of the Commons
-
-
McCay, B.J.1
Acheson, J.M.2
-
28
-
-
0024844165
-
Cultural theory and management of common property resources
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1989)
Human Ecology
, vol.17
, pp. 101-116
-
-
Buck, S.J.1
-
29
-
-
0025591015
-
Property rights, externalities, and resource degradation: Locating the tragedy
-
For example, ibid.; R. McC. Netting, "Of Mice and Meadows: Strategies of Alpine Land Use," Anthropological Quarterly 45 (1972): 132-44; S. V. Ciriacy-Wantrup and R. C. Bishop, "Common Property as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy," Natural Resources Journal 15 (1975), 713-27; A. Davis, "Property Rights and Access Management in the Small Boat Fishery: A Case Study from Southwest Nova Scotia," in Cynthia Lamson and A. J. Hanson, eds., Atlantic Fisheries and Coastal Communities: Fisheries Decision-Making Case Studies (Halifax: Dalhousie Ocean Studies Programme, 1984); B. J. McCay and James M. Acheson, eds., The Question of the Commons (Tucson: University of Arizona Press, 1987); S. J. Buck, "Cultural Theory and Management of Common Property Resources," Human Ecology 17 (1989), 101-16; and B. A. Larson and D. W. Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy," Journal of Development Economics 33 (1992), 235-62.
-
(1992)
Journal of Development Economics
, vol.33
, pp. 235-262
-
-
Larson, B.A.1
Bromley, D.W.2
-
30
-
-
0039280204
-
Property
-
Paul Edwards, ed., New York: Macmillan
-
S. I. Benn, "Property," in Paul Edwards, ed., The Encyclopedia of Philosophy (New York: Macmillan, 1967), 1491.
-
(1967)
The Encyclopedia of Philosophy
, pp. 1491
-
-
Benn, S.I.1
-
33
-
-
0041059050
-
The economic theory of a common property resource: The fishery
-
Robert Dorfman and N. S. Dorfman, eds., New York: Norton
-
H. Scott Gordon, "The Economic Theory of a Common Property Resource: The Fishery," in Robert Dorfman and N. S. Dorfman, eds., Economics and the Environment: Selected Readings (2d ed.; New York: Norton, 1977), 131.
-
(1977)
Economics and the Environment: Selected Readings 2d Ed.
, pp. 131
-
-
Gordon, H.S.1
-
37
-
-
84936824565
-
Private and common property rights in the economics of the environment
-
J. Quiggin, "Private and Common Property Rights in the Economics of the Environment," Journal of Economic Issues 22 (1988), 1073; and J. A. Swaney, "Common Property, Reciprocity, and Community," Journal of Economic Issues 24 (1990), 451.
-
(1988)
Journal of Economic Issues
, vol.22
, pp. 1073
-
-
Quiggin, J.1
-
38
-
-
0001606064
-
Common property, reciprocity, and community
-
J. Quiggin, "Private and Common Property Rights in the Economics of the Environment," Journal of Economic Issues 22 (1988), 1073; and J. A. Swaney, "Common Property, Reciprocity, and Community," Journal of Economic Issues 24 (1990), 451.
-
(1990)
Journal of Economic Issues
, vol.24
, pp. 451
-
-
Swaney, J.A.1
-
44
-
-
0003570937
-
-
For example, Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources; Ostrom, Governing the Commons; Stevenson, Common Property Economics; and Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property," 94.
-
Common Property Resources
-
-
Berkes1
-
45
-
-
0004239198
-
-
For example, Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources; Ostrom, Governing the Commons; Stevenson, Common Property Economics; and Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property," 94.
-
Governing the Commons
-
-
Ostrom1
-
46
-
-
0003642987
-
-
For example, Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources; Ostrom, Governing the Commons; Stevenson, Common Property Economics; and Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property," 94.
-
Common Property Economics
-
-
Stevenson1
-
47
-
-
0041059046
-
-
For example, Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources; Ostrom, Governing the Commons; Stevenson, Common Property Economics; and Bromley, "Testing for Common versus Private Property," 94.
-
Testing for Common Versus Private Property
, pp. 94
-
-
Bromley1
-
50
-
-
0004148498
-
-
trans. by W. D. Ross Oxford: Oxford University Press, §1261 b3
-
Aristotle, The Works of Aristotle, trans. by W. D. Ross (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1952), §1261 b3.
-
(1952)
The Works of Aristotle
-
-
Aristotle1
-
54
-
-
0041059045
-
Private solutions to conservation problems
-
Tyler Cowen, ed., Fairfax, Va.: George Mason University Press
-
R. J. Smith, "Private Solutions to Conservation Problems," in Tyler Cowen, ed., The Theory of Market Failure: A Critical Examination (Fairfax, Va.: George Mason University Press, 1988), 342-43.
-
(1988)
The Theory of Market Failure: A Critical Examination
, pp. 342-343
-
-
Smith, R.J.1
-
60
-
-
0027037919
-
Property-rights regimes and natural resources: A conceptual analysis
-
Edella Schlager and Elinor Ostrom, "Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis," Land Economics 68 (1992), 254-60.
-
(1992)
Land Economics
, vol.68
, pp. 254-260
-
-
Schlager, E.1
Ostrom, E.2
-
66
-
-
0003570937
-
-
Larson and Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation"; Schlager and Ostrom, "Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources"; and Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources.
-
Common Property Resources
-
-
Berkes1
-
67
-
-
0039871992
-
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Common Property Resources
, pp. 235
-
-
-
68
-
-
0002476973
-
Institutional arrangements for management for rural resources: Common property regimes
-
Berkes, ed.
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Common Property Resources
, pp. 23
-
-
Gibbs, C.J.N.1
Bromley, D.W.2
-
69
-
-
0024788552
-
Graphs and gaffs: A cautionary tale in the common property resources debate
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Common Property Resources
, pp. 92
-
-
Freeman, M.M.R.1
-
70
-
-
0024843266
-
Solving the common property dilemma: Village fisheries rights in japanese coastal waters
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Common Property Resources
, pp. 168
-
-
Ruddle, K.1
-
71
-
-
0041059051
-
-
personal correspondence
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
(1994)
-
-
Rogers, R.A.1
-
72
-
-
0039871990
-
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Where Have all the Exploiters Gone: Co-management of the Maine Lobster Industry
, pp. 199
-
-
Acheson, J.M.1
-
73
-
-
0024928243
-
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines
, pp. 218
-
-
Cruz, M.A.C.1
-
74
-
-
0040464926
-
-
Ibid., 235; C. J. N. Gibbs and D. W. Bromley, "Institutional Arrangements for Management for Rural Resources: Common Property Regimes," in Berkes, ed., Common Property Resources, 23. The superiority of many group-ownership arrangements over "scientific management approaches" are offered by many national governments (M. M. R. Freeman, "Graphs and Gaffs: A Cautionary Tale in the Common Property Resources Debate," in ibid., 92). The Iriai people's traditional fishing systems in the coastal waters of Japan have been adapted to modern licensing for efficient, conservationist shared use of the fishery (Kenneth Ruddle, "Solving the Common Property Dilemma: Village Fisheries Rights in Japanese Coastal Waters," in ibid., 168). The Nova Scotia and Maine Lobster fisheries have effectively and sustainably managed their resource using quite informal methods of restricting access such as tied buoy warnings on first offences and destroyed gear on second (R. A. Rogers, personal correspondence, 1994; and James M. Acheson, "Where Have All the Exploiters Gone: Co-Management of the Maine Lobster Industry," in ibid., 199). The Zanjera irrigation system in the Philippines shows groups making cooperative use of water for irrigation with equity, consent and efficiency (M. A. Concepcion Cruz, "Water as Common Property: The Case of Irrigation Water Rights in the Philippines," in ibid., 218). The Swiss Alps and the English Open Field system are two other examples of a very effective and structured system of common property where investment and enforcement are on a par with those which private property would predict (Stevenson, Common Property Economics, 91, 156).
-
Common Property Economics
, vol.91
, pp. 156
-
-
Stevenson1
-
77
-
-
0041059049
-
-
Larson and Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation," 235. One recent example is the Chesapeake Bay oyster fishery. See G. D. Santopietro and L. A. Shabman, "Can Privatization Be Inefficient: The Case of the Chesapeake Bay Oyster Fishery," Journal of Economic Issues 26 (1992), 407-19.
-
Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation
, pp. 235
-
-
Larson1
Bromley2
-
78
-
-
84933494011
-
Can privatization be inefficient: The case of the Chesapeake Bay Oyster Fishery
-
Larson and Bromley, "Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation," 235. One recent example is the Chesapeake Bay oyster fishery. See G. D. Santopietro and L. A. Shabman, "Can Privatization Be Inefficient: The Case of the Chesapeake Bay Oyster Fishery," Journal of Economic Issues 26 (1992), 407-19.
-
(1992)
Journal of Economic Issues
, vol.26
, pp. 407-419
-
-
Santopietro, G.D.1
Shabman, L.A.2
-
79
-
-
0001450320
-
The economics of over-exploitation
-
C. W. Clark, "The Economics of Over-Exploitation" Science 181 (1973), 630-34. I am not aware of any theorist who specifically argues that property rights provide an absolute or unlimited right such as that to irretrievably destroy part of the earth. Even the most strident defenders of private property institutions feel justifiably constrained by the Lockean proviso of "enough and as good" (John Locke, 1698, II §33). Yet, even in the absence of severe demand that frequently drives environmental destruction, the increasing legitimacy of economic logic in our modern imaginations makes such trade-offs all the more "rational." Resources can be destroyed (efficiently or inefficiently) regardless of de jure ownership arrangements. Experience has shown us repeatedly that de facto resource use (particularly when driven by the aspiration for global profit-maximization) often displays far less deference to Locke's moral limit. The present North American situation is one of daily environmental destruction, which results partly from incremental exploitation of free-ridership possibilities. However, much of it is done on the basis of myopic discount rates, where defection to another area of the earth is a clear option. For example, the history of aluminum production is a record of the extent to which narrow self-interested rationality can be combined with global possibilities to devastate resources permanently. Factories must be placed near large bauxite ore finds and high electricity generators, since these are the primary requirements of the process and bauxite is readily mined from the surface in tropical regions. Workers are hired and production begins. Third World politicians and governments are particularly attracted to the process since it creates jobs and an attractive influx of capital. However, once the bauxite is gone, the factory and the workers are laid off, the factory is closed and the land around it is left virtually uninhabitable. Produced in this way, aluminum production on any kind of property is unsustainable. The very term "trasnational corporations" implies the ability and even the intention to move in and out depending on resource conditions and profitability expectations. This raises the issue of other criteria for the proper use of a resource which is conspicuous by its absence in much of the neoclassical literature. The reason that other criteria (such as livelihood security, access, equity, conflict, wealth distribution, resource conservation) are not as much of a focal point goes back to Premise 2 (that efficiency is identical with sustainable use) and the fact that aggregate welfare is the normative goal of neoclassical economics. Distribution issues are secondary since it is argued that they tend to diminish private incentives to generate wealth. The neoclassicists have an impressively elegant system which they seek to uphold. As I have stated earlier, if it worked it is believed that a large amount of problems dealt with by welfare-oriented governments would resolve themselves. The achievement of efficiency is symbolic of so many other problematic issues coming together toward resolution. William of Occam would have been proud of the extent to which individual rationality can be said to explain so much in the neoclassical vision!
-
(1973)
Science
, vol.181
, pp. 630-634
-
-
Clark, C.W.1
-
82
-
-
0039871988
-
-
Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory"; Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights"; Alchian and Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm"; T. L. Anderson and P. J. Hill, "From Free Grass to Fences: Transforming the Commons of the American West," in Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., Managing the Commons (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1977), 200-16; and G. D. Libecap, Locking Up the Range (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1981).
-
The Structure of a Contract Theory
-
-
Cheung1
-
83
-
-
0039280206
-
-
Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory"; Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights"; Alchian and Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm"; T. L. Anderson and P. J. Hill, "From Free Grass to Fences: Transforming the Commons of the American West," in Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., Managing the Commons (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1977), 200-16; and G. D. Libecap, Locking Up the Range (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1981).
-
Towards a Theory of Property Rights
-
-
Demsetz1
-
84
-
-
0040464924
-
-
Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory"; Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights"; Alchian and Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm"; T. L. Anderson and P. J. Hill, "From Free Grass to Fences: Transforming the Commons of the American West," in Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., Managing the Commons (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1977), 200-16; and G. D. Libecap, Locking Up the Range (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1981).
-
The Property Rights Paradigm
-
-
Alchian1
Demsetz2
-
85
-
-
0037490815
-
From free grass to fences: Transforming the commons of the American West
-
Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., San Francisco: W. H. Freeman
-
Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory"; Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights"; Alchian and Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm"; T. L. Anderson and P. J. Hill, "From Free Grass to Fences: Transforming the Commons of the American West," in Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., Managing the Commons (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1977), 200-16; and G. D. Libecap, Locking Up the Range (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1981).
-
(1977)
Managing the Commons
, pp. 200-216
-
-
Anderson, T.L.1
Hill, P.J.2
-
86
-
-
0004165975
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger
-
Cheung, "The Structure of a Contract Theory"; Demsetz, "Towards a Theory of Property Rights"; Alchian and Demsetz, "The Property Rights Paradigm"; T. L. Anderson and P. J. Hill, "From Free Grass to Fences: Transforming the Commons of the American West," in Garrett Harding and John A. Baden, eds., Managing the Commons (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1977), 200-16; and G. D. Libecap, Locking Up the Range (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1981).
-
(1981)
Locking Up the Range
-
-
Libecap, G.D.1
-
88
-
-
0039871989
-
The failed revolution in Iraq
-
February 22
-
Mancur Olson, "The Failed Revolution in Iraq," The Wall Street Journal, February 22, 1991.
-
(1991)
The Wall Street Journal
-
-
Olson, M.1
|