메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 43, Issue 1, 2001, Pages 26-34

Ally or acquire? How technology leaders decide

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0039484640     PISSN: 15329194     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (69)

References (21)
  • 1
    • 0035274601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Benchmarking global strategic management of technology
    • March-April
    • E.B. Roberts, "Benchmarking Global Strategic Management of Technology," Research-Technology Management 44 (March-April 2001): 25-36.
    • (2001) Research-technology Management , vol.44 , pp. 25-36
    • Roberts, E.B.1
  • 2
    • 84923751408 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The authors appreciate the financial support of the global industrial sponsors of the MIT International Center for Research on the Management of Technology, as well as funding from the National Science Foundation to the MIT Center for Innovation in Product Development.
  • 3
    • 34748827706 scopus 로고
    • Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: A cyclical model of technological change
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1990) Administrative Science Quarterly , vol.35 , pp. 604-633
    • Anderson, P.1    Tushman, M.L.2
  • 4
    • 0003503061 scopus 로고
    • Boston: Harvard Business School Press
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1994) Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation
    • Utterback, J.M.1
  • 5
    • 21844507587 scopus 로고
    • Organizational determinants of technological change: Towards a sociology of technological evolution
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1992) Research in Organizational Behavior , vol.14 , pp. 311-347
    • Tushman, M.L.1    Rosenkopf, L.2
  • 6
    • 0003532955 scopus 로고
    • Simulation of schumpeterian competition
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1977) American Economic Review , vol.67 , pp. 271-276
    • Nelson, R.R.1    Winter, S.G.2
  • 7
    • 84868968961 scopus 로고
    • The schumpeterian tradeoff revisited
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1982) American Economic Review , vol.72 , pp. 114-132
    • Nelson, R.R.1    Winter, S.G.2
  • 8
    • 0012651592 scopus 로고
    • Technological paradigms and technological trajectories: A suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1982) Research Policy , vol.11 , pp. 147-162
    • Dosi, G.1
  • 9
    • 0003499898 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1982) Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics
    • Rosenberg, N.1
  • 10
    • 38549086633 scopus 로고
    • Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1986) Research Policy , vol.15 , pp. 285-305
    • Teece, D.J.1
  • 11
    • 0003351079 scopus 로고
    • Capturing value from technological innovation: Integration, strategic partnering and licensing decisions
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1988) Interfaces , vol.18 , pp. 46-61
    • Teece, D.J.1
  • 12
    • 0002474259 scopus 로고
    • Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change
    • For a comprehensive literature review on different models of the technology life cycle, see P. Anderson and M.L. Tushman, "Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change," Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1990): 604-633. Further discussion of the model's evolution is provided by J.M. Utterback, "Mastering the Dynamics of Innovation" (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1994). Utterback's pioneering life-cycle work, begun in the 1970s, is best summarized by his book. Following Utterback, Tushman and Rosenkopf propose a similar technology-life-cycle model with four stages: eras of ferment, dominant designs, eras of incremental change, and technological discontinuities. See M.L. Tushman and L. Rosenkopf, "Organizational Determinants of Technological Change: Towards a Sociology of Technological Evolution," Research in Organizational Behavior 14 (1992): 311-347. See also R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "Simulation of Schumpeterian Competition," American Economic Review 67 (1977): 271-276; R.R. Nelson and S.G. Winter, "The Schumpeterian Tradeoff Revisited," American Economic Review 72 (1982): 114-132; G. Dosi, "Technological Paradigms and Technological Trajectories: A Suggested Interpretation of the Determinants and Directions of Technical Change," Research Policy 11 (1982): 147-162; N. Rosenberg, "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics" (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982); D.J. Teece, "Profiting From Technological Innovation: Implications for Integration, Collaboration, Licensing and Public Policy," Research Policy 15 (1986): 285-305; D.J. Teece, "Capturing Value From Technological Innovation: Integration, Strategic Partnering and Licensing Decisions," Interfaces 18 (1988): 46-61; and R.R. Nelson, "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing About Economic Change," Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1995): 48-90.
    • (1995) Journal of Economic Literature , vol.33 , pp. 48-90
    • Nelson, R.R.1
  • 14
    • 84869431550 scopus 로고
    • Underinvestment and incompetence as responses to radical innovation: Evidence from the photolithographic alignment equipment
    • R.M. Henderson, "Underinvestment and Incompetence as Responses to Radical Innovation: Evidence From the Photolithographic Alignment Equipment," Rand Journal of Economics 24 (1993): 248-269.
    • (1993) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.24 , pp. 248-269
    • Henderson, R.M.1
  • 15
    • 84923751407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • http://www.cisco.com/warp/public/750/acquisition.
  • 16
    • 84881946969 scopus 로고
    • Technological discontinuities and organizational environments
    • M.L. Tushman and P. Anderson, "Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments," Administrative Science Quarterly 31 (1986): 439-465.
    • (1986) Administrative Science Quarterly , vol.31 , pp. 439-465
    • Tushman, M.L.1    Anderson, P.2
  • 17
    • 84923751406 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We define "propensity to ally" as the likelihood that a company will participate in joint ventures and alliances. Several ways for post hoc measurement of a company's propensity to ally seem plausible - for example, by examining its total number of alliances normalized by sales. We define "propensity to acquire" as the likelihood that a company will make an acquisition, perhaps measured similarly by the total number of acquisitions normalized by sales.
  • 18
    • 84923751405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • http://www.microsoft.com.
  • 19
    • 84923751404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
  • 20
    • 84923751403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Data from the Securities Data Company's (SDC) joint-venture data-base. Many joint ventures involve multiple agreements
    • Data from the Securities Data Company's (SDC) joint-venture data-base. Many joint ventures involve multiple agreements.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.