메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 81, Issue 3, 2001, Pages 495-522

Distrust

(1)  Hardin, Russell a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0035634044     PISSN: 00068047     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (26)

References (98)
  • 1
    • 0000149138 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Altruistic trust
    • Mark E. Warren ed.
    • See Jane Mansbridge, Altruistic Trust, in DEMOCRACY AND TRUST 290, 290-301 (Mark E. Warren ed., 1999) (arguing that trust can be morally praiseworthy if altruistic reasons motivate trusting beyond what objective probabilistic expectations would call for).
    • (1999) Democracy and Trust , vol.290 , pp. 290-301
    • Mansbridge, J.1
  • 2
    • 0004289432 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • forthcoming
    • RUSSELL HARDIN, TRUST AND TRUSTWORTHINESS (forthcoming 2001) (manuscript at 5, on file with author). I have spelled out varied implications of such trust and compare this conception to others elsewhere. See id. at 32-74 (discussing the multiple grounds of trustworthiness).
    • (2001) Trust and Trustworthiness
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 3
    • 0004078737 scopus 로고
    • JAMES S. COLEMAN, FOUNDATIONS OF SOCIAL THEORY 100-01 (1990) (providing a mathematical explanation for the difference between misplaced and foregone trust).
    • (1990) Foundations of Social Theory , pp. 100-101
    • Coleman, J.S.1
  • 4
    • 0004202497 scopus 로고
    • 2d ed.
    • See ERIK H. ERIKSON, CHILDHOOD AND SOCIETY 247-51 (2d ed. 1963) (discussing the implications that result from a lack of trust during infancy). See generally HARDIN, supra note 2, at 143-69 (reflecting on the implications of distrust).
    • (1963) Childhood and Society , pp. 247-251
    • Erikson, E.H.1
  • 5
    • 0039695677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 143-69
    • See ERIK H. ERIKSON, CHILDHOOD AND SOCIETY 247-51 (2d ed. 1963) (discussing the implications that result from a lack of trust during infancy). See generally HARDIN, supra note 2, at 143-69 (reflecting on the implications of distrust).
    • Hardin1
  • 6
    • 0040881835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3, at 99
    • See, e.g., COLEMAN, supra note 3, at 99 (explaining that foregoing trust creates no change in utility while placing trust creates an opportunity to benefit).
    • Coleman1
  • 7
    • 0040287465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nov. 28, § 4
    • Ted Rall, N.Y. TIMES, Nov. 28, 1999, § 4, at 6.
    • (1999) N.Y. Times , pp. 6
    • Rall, T.1
  • 8
    • 0141883580 scopus 로고
    • Trust: A mechanism for the reduction of social complexity
    • photo reprint
    • Thresholds for behavior may be important and asymmetric here. We may tip from trust to distrust only when big enough news comes in. It may be generally harder to tip from distrust to trust. See NIKLAS LUHMANN, Trust: A Mechanism for the Reduction of Social Complexity, in TRUST AND POWER: TWO WORKS BY NIKLAS LUHMANN 73-75 (photo reprint 1988) (1979) (noting that distrust occurs when subjectively created thresholds are passed).
    • (1979) Trust and Power: Two Works by Niklas Luhmann , pp. 73-75
    • Luhmann, N.1
  • 9
    • 0040287468 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 143
    • See HARDIN, supra note 2, at 143 (stating that a person's past experience with trust will affect that person's willingness to trust in the future); see also John G. Holmes, Trust and the Appraisal Process in Close Relationships, in 2 ADVANCES IN PERSONAL RELATIONSHIPS 57, 63 (Warren H. Jones and Daniel Perlman eds., 1991) (stating that "[c]ooperators indeed showed a 'readiness to trust'").
    • Hardin1
  • 10
    • 0002959522 scopus 로고
    • Trust and the appraisal process in close relationships
    • Warren H. Jones and Daniel Perlman eds.
    • See HARDIN, supra note 2, at 143 (stating that a person's past experience with trust will affect that person's willingness to trust in the future); see also John G. Holmes, Trust and the Appraisal Process in Close Relationships, in 2 ADVANCES IN PERSONAL RELATIONSHIPS 57, 63 (Warren H. Jones and Daniel Perlman eds., 1991) (stating that "[c]ooperators indeed showed a 'readiness to trust'").
    • (1991) Advances in Personal Relationships , vol.2 , pp. 57
    • Holmes, J.G.1
  • 11
    • 0039695672 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 95.
    • Id. at 95.
  • 13
    • 0004174070 scopus 로고
    • See generally RUSSELL HARDIN, COLLECTIVE ACTION 200-05 (1982) (explaining the changes in behavior that result when end-game effects are applied to the prisoner's dilemma).
    • (1982) Collective Action , pp. 200-205
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 14
    • 0040881831 scopus 로고
    • Kurt H. Wolff trans. & ed., Free Press
    • GEORG SIMMEL, THE SOCIOLOGY OF GEORG SIMMEL 311-12 (Kurt H. Wolff trans. & ed., Free Press 1950) (1908).
    • (1908) The Sociology of Georg Simmel , pp. 311-312
    • Simmel, G.1
  • 15
    • 0002863111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Concealment and exposure
    • Thomas Nagel, Concealment and Exposure, 27 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 3, 6 (1998).
    • (1998) Phil. & Pub. Aff. , vol.27 , pp. 3
    • Nagel, T.1
  • 16
    • 0040881832 scopus 로고
    • Everyman's Library
    • Virginia Woolf comments on the thoughts of a family listening to the paterfamilias expound on politics: "All of them bending themselves to listen thought: 'Pray heaven that the inside of my mind may not be exposed,' for each thought, 'The others are feeling this. They are outraged and indignant with the government about the fishermen. Whereas, I feel nothing at all.'" VIRGINIA WOOLF, TO THE LIGHTHOUSE 109 (Everyman's Library 1992) (1938).
    • (1938) To the Lighthouse , vol.109
    • Woolf, V.1
  • 17
    • 0039695615 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Animal Legal Defense Fund, Inc. v. Shalala, 104 F.3d 424, 431 (D.C. Cir. 1997) (holding that the Research Council of the National Academy of Sciences was "utilized" by the Department of Health and Human Services within the meaning of the term as used in the Federal Advisory Committee Act, and thus is subject to its provisions).
  • 18
    • 0030815529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Government bows out of academy case
    • See Andrew Lawler, Government Bows Out of Academy Case, 278 SCIENCE 28, 28 (1997) (summarizing concerns of Academy officials in response to the D.C. Circuit's decision).
    • (1997) Science , vol.278 , pp. 28
    • Lawler, A.1
  • 19
    • 0037550435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Arguing and bargaining in two constituent assemblies
    • See Jon Elster, Arguing and Bargaining in Two Constituent Assemblies, 2 U. PA. J. CONST. L. 345, 410-12 (2000) (stating that the secrecy of the American Constitutional Convention resulted in debates "remarkably free from cant and remarkably grounded in rational argument," while the French Assemblee Constituante was "heavily tainted by rhetoric, demagoguery, and overbidding").
    • (2000) U. PA. J. Const. L. , vol.2 , pp. 345
    • Elster, J.1
  • 20
    • 0040881829 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Nagel, supra note 13, at 6 ("If I don't tell you everything I think and feel about you, that is not a case of deception, since you don't expect me to do so and would probably be appalled if I did.").
  • 21
    • 0039695670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7, at 71
    • LUHMANN, supra note 7, at 71 ("Distrust . . . is also a functional equivalent for trust.").
    • Luhmann1
  • 22
    • 0040881830 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See supra notes 3-8 and accompanying text (discussing the differences between trust and distrust).
  • 23
    • 0040287466 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 7, at 4-8
    • See, e.g., LUHMANN, supra note 7, at 4-8 (claiming that trust reduces complexity in society and creates "increased possibilities for experience and action").
    • Luhmann1
  • 26
    • 0039695668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 109 (explaining that members "absent themselves periodically from their wives").
  • 27
    • 0040881828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 22
    • See BARTH, supra note 22.
    • Barth1
  • 28
    • 0003258808 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exotic oman opens its doors
    • Feb. 8, § 5
    • See Judith Miller, Exotic Oman Opens Its Doors, N.Y. TIMES, Feb. 8, 1998, § 5, at 11 (noting the trading history of the country).
    • (1998) N.Y. Times , pp. 11
    • Miller, J.1
  • 29
    • 0040287464 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Oman opened to tourists only in the mid-1990s, and it now seems, in one account, to be a remarkably hospitable society. Presumably the change is largely due to a relatively benign ruler, Sultan Qabus bin Said. See id. at 11 (relating the experience of a trip to Oman).
  • 30
  • 31
    • 0039695664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 38. (describing Southern conduct and social norms)
    • See id. at 38. (describing Southern conduct and social norms).
  • 32
    • 0000459121 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Liberty against the democratic state: On the historical and contemporary sources of American distrust
    • Mark E. Warren ed.
    • See Orlando Patterson, Liberty Against the Democratic State: On the Historical and Contemporary Sources of American Distrust, in DEMOCRACY AND TRUST 151, 175, 190-91(Mark E. Warren ed., 1999) (citing data from the General Social Survey for the years 1972-1994). On the idea of generalized trust, see generally HARDIN, supra note 2, at 68-113; 237-75 (discussing trust in society).
    • (1999) Democracy and Trust , vol.151 , Issue.175 , pp. 190-191
    • Patterson, O.1
  • 33
    • 0040287428 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 68-113; 237-75
    • See Orlando Patterson, Liberty Against the Democratic State: On the Historical and Contemporary Sources of American Distrust, in DEMOCRACY AND TRUST 151, 175, 190-91(Mark E. Warren ed., 1999) (citing data from the General Social Survey for the years 1972-1994). On the idea of generalized trust, see generally HARDIN, supra note 2, at 68-113; 237-75 (discussing trust in society).
    • Hardin1
  • 34
    • 0039103515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 4, 1995
    • Letter from Robert K. Merton to Russell Hardin (May 4, 1995) (on file with author).
    • Merton, R.K.1    Hardin, R.2
  • 36
    • 0039695662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 101 (describing the ease and success with which Smith became a "flag-wrapped symbol, inseparably associated with . . . abiding patriotism").
  • 37
    • 0039695661 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 142 (citing interview subjects as contrasting Smith's integrity with the "pretenses, deception and dissembling which they observe in their daily experience").
  • 38
  • 39
    • 0040287461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 154
    • Id. at 154.
  • 40
    • 0039103514 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 153 (relating the situation in Calais at the time)
    • See id. at 153 (relating the situation in Calais at the time).
  • 41
    • 0040881825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 410-11 (describing the impact of the letters)
    • See id. at 410-11 (describing the impact of the letters).
  • 42
    • 84936823913 scopus 로고
    • Trust and antitrust
    • Annette Baier, Trust and Antitrust, 96 ETHICS 231, 247 (1986).
    • (1986) Ethics , vol.96 , pp. 231
    • Baier, A.1
  • 43
    • 0003630580 scopus 로고
    • James W. Ellington trans., 2d ed.
    • IMMANUEL KANT, GROUNDING FOR THE METAPHYSICS OF MORALS 39-40 (James W. Ellington trans., 2d ed. 1981) (hypothesizing that rational beings will legislate universal laws to which they will be subject).
    • (1981) Grounding for the Metaphysics of Morals , pp. 39-40
    • Kant, I.1
  • 44
    • 0039103513 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 39, at 249
    • Baier, supra note 39, at 249.
    • Baier1
  • 45
    • 0039695617 scopus 로고
    • CAROLE PATEMAN, THE SEXUAL CONTRACT 1 (1988) (classifying social contract theory as "[t]he most famous and influential political story of modern times").
    • (1988) The Sexual Contract , vol.1
    • Pateman, C.1
  • 46
    • 0040881823 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 68-69 (explaining the theories of Grotius and Pufendorf)
    • See id. at 68-69 (explaining the theories of Grotius and Pufendorf).
  • 47
    • 0003364505 scopus 로고
    • Of the original contract
    • Eugene Miller, ed., Liberty Press
    • See David Hume, Of the Original Contract, in ESSAYS: MORAL, POLITICAL, AND LITERARY, 465, 465-87 (Eugene Miller, ed., Liberty Press 1987) (1748) (criticizing social contact theory); see also RUSSELL HARDIN, LIBERALISM, CONSTITUTIONALISM, AND DEMOCRACY 82-140, 149 (1999) (arguing that the United States' form of government arose out of coordination rather than contract).
    • (1748) Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary , vol.465 , pp. 465-487
    • Hume, D.1
  • 48
    • 25544459141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See David Hume, Of the Original Contract, in ESSAYS: MORAL, POLITICAL, AND LITERARY, 465, 465-87 (Eugene Miller, ed., Liberty Press 1987) (1748) (criticizing social contact theory); see also RUSSELL HARDIN, LIBERALISM, CONSTITUTIONALISM, AND DEMOCRACY 82-140, 149 (1999) (arguing that the United States' form of government arose out of coordination rather than contract).
    • (1999) Liberalism, Constitutionalism, and Democracy , vol.82-140 , pp. 149
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 49
    • 0004048289 scopus 로고
    • rev. ed. 1999
    • See, e.g., JOHN RAWLS, A THEORY OF JUSTICE 10-11, 14-15 (rev. ed. 1999) (1971) (referring to the basis for a social contract).
    • (1971) A Theory of Justice , vol.10-11 , pp. 14-15
    • Rawls, J.1
  • 50
    • 0039103512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 42, at 1-4, 221
    • See PATEMAN, supra note 42, at 1-4, 221 (describing the patriarchal roots of the social contract).
    • Pateman1
  • 51
    • 0040881788 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Norms of cooperativeness and networks of trust
    • Karl-Dieter Opp & Michael Hechter eds.
    • This discussion is taken from Karen S. Cook & Russell Hardin, Norms of Cooperativeness and Networks of Trust, in SOCIAL NORMS 329-46 (Karl-Dieter Opp & Michael Hechter eds., 2001).
    • (2001) Social Norms , pp. 329-346
    • Cook, K.S.1    Hardin, R.2
  • 52
    • 0039695616 scopus 로고
    • EDWARD C. BANFIELD, THE MORAL BASIS OF A BACKWARD SOCIETY 83 (1958) (defining an amoral familist as one who seeks to "[m]aximize the material, short-run advantage of the nuclear family"). In his 1950's study of the fictional Southern Italian village of Montegrano, Banfield chronicled a pervasive distrust of all social units beyond the family. Terming this paradigm "amoral familism," Banfield noted that in communities where its practice was prevalent, social cooperation was limited, as "no one [would] further the interest of the group or community except as it [was] to his private advantage to do so." Id. at 83-84. Likewise, moral and ethical obligations were strictly confined to the family, diminishing notions of community interest or public good. In fact, according to Banfield, "the hope of material gain in the short-run [would] be the only motive for concern with public affairs." Id. at 84 (emphasis added); see also John L. Aguilar, Trust and Exchange: Expressive and Instrumental Dimensions of Reciprocity in a Peasant Community, 12 ETHOS 3, 3-29 (1984) (identifying the presence of amoral familistic tendencies in peasant Mexican communities): George H. Westacott & Lawrence K. Williams, Interpersonal Trust and Modern Attitudes in Peru, 13 INT'L. J. CONTEMP. SOC. 117. 117-137 (1976) (finding, a similar paradigm in Peruvian subsistence communities). See generally TRUDY GOVIER, SOCIAL TRUST AND HUMAN COMMUNITIES 135-146 (1997) (providing an overview of anthropological literature surrounding amoral familism, and arguing that the harsh constraint of poverty may itself create a limitation on societal cooperation).
    • (1958) The Moral Basis of a Backward Society , vol.83
    • Banfield, E.C.1
  • 53
    • 84982595606 scopus 로고
    • Trust and exchange: Expressive and instrumental dimensions of reciprocity in a peasant community
    • EDWARD C. BANFIELD, THE MORAL BASIS OF A BACKWARD SOCIETY 83 (1958) (defining an amoral familist as one who seeks to "[m]aximize the material, short-run advantage of the nuclear family"). In his 1950's study of the fictional Southern Italian village of Montegrano, Banfield chronicled a pervasive distrust of all social units beyond the family. Terming this paradigm "amoral familism," Banfield noted that in communities where its practice was prevalent, social cooperation was limited, as "no one [would] further the interest of the group or community except as it [was] to his private advantage to do so." Id. at 83-84. Likewise, moral and ethical obligations were strictly confined to the family, diminishing notions of community interest or public good. In fact, according to Banfield, "the hope of material gain in the short-run [would] be the only motive for concern with public affairs." Id. at 84 (emphasis added); see also John L. Aguilar, Trust and Exchange: Expressive and Instrumental Dimensions of Reciprocity in a Peasant Community, 12 ETHOS 3, 3-29 (1984) (identifying the presence of amoral familistic tendencies in peasant Mexican communities): George H. Westacott & Lawrence K. Williams, Interpersonal Trust and Modern Attitudes in Peru, 13 INT'L. J. CONTEMP. SOC. 117. 117-137 (1976) (finding, a similar paradigm in Peruvian subsistence communities). See generally TRUDY GOVIER, SOCIAL TRUST AND HUMAN COMMUNITIES 135-146 (1997) (providing an overview of anthropological literature surrounding amoral familism, and arguing that the harsh constraint of poverty may itself create a limitation on societal cooperation).
    • (1984) Ethos , vol.12 , pp. 3
    • Aguilar, J.L.1
  • 54
    • 84925899998 scopus 로고
    • Interpersonal trust and modern attitudes in Peru
    • EDWARD C. BANFIELD, THE MORAL BASIS OF A BACKWARD SOCIETY 83 (1958) (defining an amoral familist as one who seeks to "[m]aximize the material, short-run advantage of the nuclear family"). In his 1950's study of the fictional Southern Italian village of Montegrano, Banfield chronicled a pervasive distrust of all social units beyond the family. Terming this paradigm "amoral familism," Banfield noted that in communities where its practice was prevalent, social cooperation was limited, as "no one [would] further the interest of the group or community except as it [was] to his private advantage to do so." Id. at 83-84. Likewise, moral and ethical obligations were strictly confined to the family, diminishing notions of community interest or public good. In fact, according to Banfield, "the hope of material gain in the short-run [would] be the only motive for concern with public affairs." Id. at 84 (emphasis added); see also John L. Aguilar, Trust and Exchange: Expressive and Instrumental Dimensions of Reciprocity in a Peasant Community, 12 ETHOS 3, 3-29 (1984) (identifying the presence of amoral familistic tendencies in peasant Mexican communities): George H. Westacott & Lawrence K. Williams, Interpersonal Trust and Modern Attitudes in Peru, 13 INT'L. J. CONTEMP. SOC. 117. 117-137 (1976) (finding, a similar paradigm in Peruvian subsistence communities). See generally TRUDY GOVIER, SOCIAL TRUST AND HUMAN COMMUNITIES 135-146 (1997) (providing an overview of anthropological literature surrounding amoral familism, and arguing that the harsh constraint of poverty may itself create a limitation on societal cooperation).
    • (1976) Int'l. J. Contemp. Soc. , vol.13 , pp. 117
    • Westacott, G.H.1    Williams, L.K.2
  • 55
    • 0003711417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • EDWARD C. BANFIELD, THE MORAL BASIS OF A BACKWARD SOCIETY 83 (1958) (defining an amoral familist as one who seeks to "[m]aximize the material, short-run advantage of the nuclear family"). In his 1950's study of the fictional Southern Italian village of Montegrano, Banfield chronicled a pervasive distrust of all social units beyond the family. Terming this paradigm "amoral familism," Banfield noted that in communities where its practice was prevalent, social cooperation was limited, as "no one [would] further the interest of the group or community except as it [was] to his private advantage to do so." Id. at 83-84. Likewise, moral and ethical obligations were strictly confined to the family, diminishing notions of community interest or public good. In fact, according to Banfield, "the hope of material gain in the short-run [would] be the only motive for concern with public affairs." Id. at 84 (emphasis added); see also John L. Aguilar, Trust and Exchange: Expressive and Instrumental Dimensions of Reciprocity in a Peasant Community, 12 ETHOS 3, 3-29 (1984) (identifying the presence of amoral familistic tendencies in peasant Mexican communities): George H. Westacott & Lawrence K. Williams, Interpersonal Trust and Modern Attitudes in Peru, 13 INT'L. J. CONTEMP. SOC. 117. 117-137 (1976) (finding, a similar paradigm in Peruvian subsistence communities). See generally TRUDY GOVIER, SOCIAL TRUST AND HUMAN COMMUNITIES 135-146 (1997) (providing an overview of anthropological literature surrounding amoral familism, and arguing that the harsh constraint of poverty may itself create a limitation on societal cooperation).
    • (1997) Social Trust and Human Communities , pp. 135-146
    • Govier, T.1
  • 56
    • 0004236347 scopus 로고
    • William Popple trans., Bobbs-Merrill Co., Inc., 2d. ed.
    • See JOHN LOCKE, A LETTER CONCERNING TOLERATION 52 (William Popple trans., Bobbs-Merrill Co., Inc., 2d. ed. 1955) ("Promises, covenants, and oaths, which are the bonds of human society, can have no hold upon an atheist.").
    • (1955) A Letter Concerning Toleration , vol.52
    • Locke, J.1
  • 57
    • 0001919728 scopus 로고
    • The destruction of trust and its economic consequences in the case of eighteenth-century Naples
    • Diego Gambetta ed.
    • Anthony Pagden, The Destruction of Trust and Its Economic Consequences in the Case of Eighteenth-century Naples, in TRUST: MAKING AND BREAKING COOPERATIVE RELATIONS 127, 127-28 (Diego Gambetta ed., 1988).
    • (1988) Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations , vol.127 , pp. 127-128
    • Pagden, A.1
  • 60
    • 0039695595 scopus 로고
    • related the visit to the author in Bellagio, Italy, in May
    • Elkin related the visit to the author in Bellagio, Italy, in May 1988.
    • (1988)
    • Elkin1
  • 61
    • 0039103461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 50, at 128
    • See Pagden, supra note 50, at 128 (discussing Doria's work).
    • Pagden1
  • 62
    • 0040287356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 133 (describing honor as "the single defining characteristic of Spanish culture").
  • 63
    • 84972700447 scopus 로고
    • Hobbesian political order
    • See Russell Hardin, Hobbesian Political Order, 19 POL. THEORY 156, 169 (1991) (discussing Hobbes's view on the function of government as a means to secure order).
    • (1991) Pol. Theory , vol.19 , pp. 156
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 64
    • 0039103467 scopus 로고
    • See FRANK HENDERSON STEWART, HONOR 54 (1994) (defining an "honor group" as members of a population that follow the same code of honor and recognize each other as doing so). In Bedouin society, Stewart argues that honor is itself status-conferring, guaranteeing "the right to be treated with a certain worth." Id. at 21. For an examination of the role of honor in Swat Pathan culture, see BARTH, supra note 23, at 115-17 (discussing personal identity and social structure in Pathan society). The rise of dueling as a practice defending individual honor in seventeenth century France may also illustrate the exclusive status honor sanctions. Only aristocrats could legally participate in the activity, and it served as a principal method of upper-class dispute resolution, distinguishing French nobility from commoners. See RUSSELL HARDIN, ONE FOR ALL: THE LOGIC OF GROUP CONFLICT 90-100 (1995) (describing the practice of dueling).
    • (1994) Honor , vol.54
    • Stewart, F.H.1
  • 65
    • 0039695528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 23, at 115-17
    • See FRANK HENDERSON STEWART, HONOR 54 (1994) (defining an "honor group" as members of a population that follow the same code of honor and recognize each other as doing so). In Bedouin society, Stewart argues that honor is itself status-conferring, guaranteeing "the right to be treated with a certain worth." Id. at 21. For an examination of the role of honor in Swat Pathan culture, see BARTH, supra note 23, at 115-17 (discussing personal identity and social structure in Pathan society). The rise of dueling as a practice defending individual honor in seventeenth century France may also illustrate the exclusive status honor sanctions. Only aristocrats could legally participate in the activity, and it served as a principal method of upper-class dispute resolution, distinguishing French nobility from commoners. See RUSSELL HARDIN, ONE FOR ALL: THE LOGIC OF GROUP CONFLICT 90-100 (1995) (describing the practice of dueling).
    • Barth1
  • 66
    • 0003772817 scopus 로고
    • See FRANK HENDERSON STEWART, HONOR 54 (1994) (defining an "honor group" as members of a population that follow the same code of honor and recognize each other as doing so). In Bedouin society, Stewart argues that honor is itself status-conferring, guaranteeing "the right to be treated with a certain worth." Id. at 21. For an examination of the role of honor in Swat Pathan culture, see BARTH, supra note 23, at 115-17 (discussing personal identity and social structure in Pathan society). The rise of dueling as a practice defending individual honor in seventeenth century France may also illustrate the exclusive status honor sanctions. Only aristocrats could legally participate in the activity, and it served as a principal method of upper-class dispute resolution, distinguishing French nobility from commoners. See RUSSELL HARDIN, ONE FOR ALL: THE LOGIC OF GROUP CONFLICT 90-100 (1995) (describing the practice of dueling).
    • (1995) One for All: The Logic of Group Conflict 90-100
    • Hardin, R.1
  • 67
    • 0040881780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 50, at 136-37
    • See Pagden, supra note 50, at 136-37 (discussing the Spanish judicial system).
    • Pagden1
  • 68
    • 0040881781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 127 (explaining that the Spanish destroyed trust in Naples "in order to increase their social and political control over the kingdom").
  • 69
    • 0002353506 scopus 로고
    • Mafia: The price of distrust
    • Diego Gambetta ed.
    • See Diego Gambetta, Mafia: The Price of Distrust, in TRUST: MAKING AND BREAKING COOPERATIVE RELATIONS 158, 162-63 (Diego Gambetta ed., 1988) (explaining that the Sicilian Mafia was formed because distrust of the State led people to seek social mobility in small groups at the expense of other groups).
    • (1988) Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations , vol.158 , pp. 162-163
    • Gambetta, D.1
  • 70
    • 0040287426 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57, at 142-82
    • See HARDIN, supra note 57, at 142-82 (explaining the motivation for numerous violent conflicts).
    • Hardin1
  • 71
    • 0039695606 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 48, at 116
    • Banfield notes that the threat of community violence may spur Montegranan villagers to keep their ventures strictly within the family. Because successful villagers frequently suffer from acts of vandalism at the hands of jealous onlookers, community members frequently make their ventures private and open only to the family, so that neighbors and community members remain unaware - and hence, unenvious - of any gains. See BANFIELD, supra note 48, at 116.
    • Banfield1
  • 72
    • 0003487848 scopus 로고
    • See generally ANTON BLOK, THE MAFIA OF A SICILIAN VILLAGE, 1860-1960: A STUDY OF VIOLENT PEASANT ENTREPRENEURS 89-102 (1974) (describing the creation and evolving function of the Mafia). This anthropological look at a century of Mafia behavior (defined as unlicensed public violence aimed to affect the community) explores the rise of the mafiosi (members of the Mafia) and their relationship to corporate legal structures. While often immune from formal law, the mafiosi linked the otherwise isolated political establishment with society itself. They served as political power brokers between citizens and national leaders whose success depended on community support. In return, they acquired an extra-legal position and a symbiotic relationship with the government that sustained a malfunctioning political order.
    • (1974) The Mafia of a Sicilian Village, 1860-1960: A Study of Violent Peasant Entrepreneurs , pp. 89-102
    • Blok, A.1
  • 73
    • 0039695605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 60, at 163-64
    • See Gambetta, supra note 60, at 163-64 (explaining that the Mafia exploited distrust by positioning itself as "men capable of enforcing privately that public justice that the Spaniards had eroded).
    • Gambetta1
  • 74
    • 0040287429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 166-67 (describing how democratic leaders used the Mafia for its vote-mobilizing capability).
  • 75
    • 0039103481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 10, at 140-46
    • BRETON & WINTROBE, supra note 10, at 140-46. Large Japanese firms have cultivated a work atmosphere in which workers face intense pressure to, remain loyal to the firm. These firms provide incentives such as seniority-based promotion and awards of luxury benefits to senior associates in the hope of discouraging individuals from leaving the firm. Moreover, intense supervision and co-opted, industry-run labor unions prevent laborers from organizing themselves and demanding reform.
    • Breton1    Wintrobe2
  • 76
    • 0004287799 scopus 로고
    • Penguin
    • THOMAS HOBBES, LEVIATHAN 184 (Penguin 1986) (1651) ("[T]herefore if any two men desire the same thing, which neverthelesse [sic] they cannot both enjoy, they become enemies; and . . . endeavor to destroy or subdue one an other [sic].").
    • (1986) Leviathan , vol.184
    • Hobbes, T.1
  • 77
    • 0039695607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 60, at 158
    • See Gambetta, supra note 60, at 158 (outlining the harmful social effects of the Mafia-controlled society). As Gambetta notes, the Mafia might grant someone's request to fraudulently sell goods. See id. at 173 (relating how the "Mafioso succeeded in helping [people] to sell a blind horse as a good one"). This implicitly makes clear that distrust of one's fellows is rational even without Mafia protection, although competition that would benefit almost everyone is undercut.
    • Gambetta1
  • 78
    • 0040287424 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ee id at 158-59 (describing the Mafia as "the quintessence" of the structure of behavioral patterns). Moreover, Gambetta cites other factors that further burden Sicilian society. For example, economic backwardness produces little opportunity for advancement. A standard way to advance is to prevail over others in one's own society - hence, advancement is a positional good. See id. at 163 (explaining the economic factors that led to the creation of, and enduring support for, the Mafia).
  • 79
    • 0039695608 scopus 로고
    • For example, John Hart Ely argues that the framers of the Constitution favored judicial intervention when the political system itself malfunctioned and became "undeserving of trust." JOHN HART ELY, DEMOCRACY AND DISTRUST: A THEORY OF JUDICIAL REVIEW 103 (1980) (citing majority-sanctioned obstacles that leave minorities unable to participate in the political process as an example of a situation calling for judicial intervention); see also, Mark E. Warren, Democratic Theory and Trust, in DEMOCRACY AND TRUST 310, 310-45 (Mark E. Warren ed., 1999) (concluding that democracy is grounded in social distrust and public suspicion of a powerful government).
    • (1980) Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial Review , vol.103
    • Hart Ely, J.1
  • 80
    • 0003283670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Democratic theory and trust
    • Mark E. Warren ed.
    • For example, John Hart Ely argues that the framers of the Constitution favored judicial intervention when the political system itself malfunctioned and became "undeserving of trust." JOHN HART ELY, DEMOCRACY AND DISTRUST: A THEORY OF JUDICIAL REVIEW 103 (1980) (citing majority-sanctioned obstacles that leave minorities unable to participate in the political process as an example of a situation calling for judicial intervention); see also, Mark E. Warren, Democratic Theory and Trust, in DEMOCRACY AND TRUST 310, 310-45 (Mark E. Warren ed., 1999) (concluding that democracy is grounded in social distrust and public suspicion of a powerful government).
    • (1999) Democracy and Trust , vol.310 , pp. 310-345
    • Warren, M.E.1
  • 81
    • 0003897575 scopus 로고
    • Anne M. Cohler et al. trans. & eds., Cambridge Univ. Press
    • See generally CHARLES DE SECONDAT, BARON DE MONTESQUIEU, THE SPIRIT OF THE LAWS (Anne M. Cohler et al. trans. & eds., Cambridge Univ. Press 1989) (1748); THE FEDERALIST No. 51 (James Madison).
    • (1748) The Spirit of The Laws
    • De Secondat, C.1    De Montesquieu, B.2
  • 82
    • 0040287427 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally CHARLES DE SECONDAT, BARON DE MONTESQUIEU, THE SPIRIT OF THE LAWS (Anne M. Cohler et al. trans. & eds., Cambridge Univ. Press 1989) (1748); THE FEDERALIST No. 51 (James Madison).
    • The Federalist , vol.51
    • Madison, J.1
  • 83
    • 0039103482 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 44, at 82-141
    • An examination of the 18th century debate surrounding the drafting of the Constitution indicates that much of the framers' deliberation centered on the complex relationship between citizen and government, and the relative distrust between them. In fact, the principal debate between Anti-Federalists and Federalists was whether the federal government could be trusted to adequately safeguard the interests of particular communities. See HARDIN, supra note 44, at 82-141 (discussing the background of the Constitutional convention).
    • Hardin1
  • 84
    • 0039103473 scopus 로고
    • Peter Laslett, ed., Cambridge University Press, 2d ed.
    • Locke held that society turns power over to its governors, "whom the society hath set over it self, with this express or tacit Trust, That it shall be imployed for their good, and the preservation of their Property[.]" JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT § 171 at 399 (Peter Laslett, ed., Cambridge University Press, 2d ed., 1967) (1690). See also HARDIN, supra note 2, at 201-35 (explaining how trust affects government functions).
    • (1690) Two Treatises of Government § 171 , pp. 399
    • Locke, J.1
  • 85
    • 0040881785 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 201-35
    • Locke held that society turns power over to its governors, "whom the society hath set over it self, with this express or tacit Trust, That it shall be imployed for their good, and the preservation of their Property[.]" JOHN LOCKE, TWO TREATISES OF GOVERNMENT § 171 at 399 (Peter Laslett, ed., Cambridge University Press, 2d ed., 1967) (1690). See also HARDIN, supra note 2, at 201-35 (explaining how trust affects government functions).
    • Hardin1
  • 86
    • 0039695600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 44, at 42-46
    • HUME, supra note 44, at 42-46 (discussing the organization of government institutions).
    • Hume1
  • 87
    • 0346584258 scopus 로고
    • The political structure of American government is designed to explicitly prevent government officers from assuming too much control over each other or the government itself. This system of supplying "opposite and rival interests" is designed to limit the role of each officer to her task alone. See THE FEDERALIST NO. 51. at 322-23 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961). For further discussion, see HARDIN, supra note 2, at 201-35 (arguing that, while it is plausible for a typical citizen to distrust government, it is not plausible for her to trust it in any meaningful sense of "trust").
    • (1961) The Federalist No. 51 , vol.51 , pp. 322-323
    • Madison, J.1    Rossiter, C.2
  • 88
    • 0039695597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 2, at 201-35
    • The political structure of American government is designed to explicitly prevent government officers from assuming too much control over each other or the government itself. This system of supplying "opposite and rival interests" is designed to limit the role of each officer to her task alone. See THE FEDERALIST NO. 51. at 322-23 (James Madison) (Clinton Rossiter ed., 1961). For further discussion, see HARDIN, supra note 2, at 201-35 (arguing that, while it is plausible for a typical citizen to distrust government, it is not plausible for her to trust it in any meaningful sense of "trust").
    • Hardin1
  • 89
    • 0039695602 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Organizations have, of course, many capacities for which to recommend them. In particular, they can organize collective actions that could not plausibly be organized by spontaneous individual action. But they are also very important in mediating between potential partners who do not trust each other.
  • 90
    • 0039103474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 67, at 376, 376-94
    • Hobbes argues that the state's principal purpose of procuring "the safety of the people" allows citizens to enjoy a life of competition and acquisition; by providing conditions that allow them to live securely - while still functioning autonomously-the government can foster social cooperation. HOBBES, supra note 67, at 376, 376-94 (discussing the role of the sovereign).
    • Hobbes1
  • 91
    • 0039103480 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 3, at 102-16
    • See COLEMAN, supra note 3, at 102-16 (arguing that an institution's role in providing accurate and reliable information regarding transactions, allows it to create a foundation for an individual's subsequent trust).
    • Coleman1
  • 92
    • 0040881783 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Third party established trust involves one party trusting a third party, not involved in the transaction, instead of directly trusting the promising other party. This form of trust has been critical for a variety of financial innovations, including the development of paper money and banking. See id. at 186-88.
  • 93
    • 0040287421 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • According to Coleman, "[t]hird party trust in economic systems seems to be viable only in conjunction with a generally accepted unit of account, so that some value can be placed on the obligations of the third party to make them fungible in exchange." Noneconomic social systems have difficulty developing a corollary system of valuation, a difficulty which makes third party trust relationships rare in these settings. Id. at 187.
  • 94
    • 85054897705 scopus 로고
    • Gifts and exchanges
    • By examining both a market and voluntary approach to blood donation, Arrow argues that reliance upon altruism should "be confined to those circumstances where the price system breaks down," and that "[w]holesale usage of ethical standards is apt to have undesirable consequences. We do not wish to use up recklessly the scarce resources of altruistic motivation[.]" Kenneth J. Arrow, Gifts and Exchanges, 1 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 343, 354-55 (1972).
    • (1972) Phil. & Pub. Aff. , vol.1 , pp. 343
    • Arrow, K.J.1
  • 95
    • 0004052837 scopus 로고
    • Howard Margolis proposes a model of altruism in which the individual has two different sets of desires: self-interested or selfish, and other-directed or altruistic. As humans, we balance between these, indulging more in altruism for a while and then in selfishness. See generally HOWARD MARGOLIS, SELFISHNESS, ALTRUISM, AND RATIONALITY: A THEORY OF SOCIAL CHOICE (1982).
    • (1982) Selfishness, Altruism, and Rationality: A Theory of Social Choice
    • Margolis, H.1
  • 96
    • 0040287417 scopus 로고
    • Of the first principles of government
    • Eugene Miller, ed., Liberty Press
    • Virtually the whole of political philosophy is relevant to this issue, and the political and economic philosophers of the Scottish Enlightenment in particular were almost entirely concerned with it. See David Hume, Of the First Principles of Government in ESSAYS: MORAL, POLITICAL, AND LITERARY, 32, 32-36 (Eugene Miller, ed., Liberty Press 1987) (1748) (describing the development of government in Great Britain).
    • (1748) Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary , vol.32 , pp. 32-36
    • Hume, D.1
  • 97
    • 0040287420 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 57, at 3
    • See HARDIN, supra note 57, at 3 (describing how a participant in the riot "was carried away by the spirit of the riot and lost touch with rational sense
    • Hardin1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.