메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 55, Issue 4, 2001, Pages 1051-1082

Rational design: Looking back to move forward

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0035568372     PISSN: 00208183     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1162/002081801317193691     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (84)

References (49)
  • 1
    • 0041107056 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the volume's introduction we define international institution broadly enough to include treaties but not so broadly as to include tacit bargaining; Koremenos, Lipson, and Snidal, this volume.
    • In the volume's introduction we define international institution broadly enough to include treaties but not so broadly as to include tacit bargaining; Koremenos, Lipson, and Snidal, this volume.
  • 2
    • 0039920194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Van Evera 1997
    • Van Evera 1997.
  • 3
    • 0039920195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We had pragmatic reasons for sticking to a "two-cornered" fight between our conjectures and the evidence. First, we did not want to expend the energies of our contributors on "meta-" and "-ology" debates; we asked them instead to focus on what the rational perspective could accomplish. Second, we did not feel competent to present, for example, the constructivist or realist conjectures about institutional design. If they "lost" such a fight, we would be accused of rigging the contest through our incompetence. While we welcome third parties to join this intellectual effort, we argue below that there is more payoff from doing so as allies than as adversaries.
  • 4
    • 0041107057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We thank an anonymous reviewer for reminding us of this point.
  • 5
    • 0041107058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Rational Design approach can include nonstate actors and does not inherently restrict the autonomous capacity of international institutions. Multinational firms and transnational interest groups can and do act at the international level and sometimes shape specific institutions, as Mattli makes clear. The Rational Design approach can include any type of intentional actor. In practice, however, states shape nearly all important international institutions, and for simplicity we sometimes limit our analysis to them. We also recognize that states can deliberately choose to endow international institutions with more autonomous powers to serve their purposes. According to Andrew Moravcsik, the principal members of the EU have done exactly that. Moravcsik 1998.
  • 6
    • 0040513063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • According to the influential work of George Stigler, Mancur Olson, Douglass North, and others, rent seeking is central to the organization of the state and state-society relations. Their insights about domestic politics could be extended to international cartels, including producer organizations like OPEC, and perhaps to a wider range of international institutions.
  • 7
    • 0039920193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many of these issues are taken up in Lake and Powell 1999
    • Many of these issues are taken up in Lake and Powell 1999.
  • 8
    • 0040513064 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These silences do raise another issue, however: the potential for selection bias. Results from cases where both the independent variable (X) and the dependent institutional variable (Y) are present might be overinterpreted as suggesting a "sufficient" condition that "X leads to Y." But a "silence" indicates that X can be present without Y necessarily occurring, so the "sufficiency" claim would be wrong. Ideally, we need to compare across cases to understand what other factors determine when X has the hypothesized effect Y, and when it does not. Although we are not aware of any situations where this problem arises, any interpretation of these results needs to be appropriately bounded in this way. Even with silences, however, a preponderance of positive findings still tells us that a factor does influence institutional design under some circumstances.
  • 9
    • 0039920192 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Finally, we stress that the Rational Design conjectures were not retrofitted to the findings. We developed the framework before the case studies began. We subsequently refined our terminology, dropped one conjecture where we found its derivation poorly grounded, and dropped another where we found its logic to be identical to one of our other conjectures. Otherwise the conjectures were all derived before the evaluations. The conjecture we dropped on theoretical grounds dealt with the effects of distribution on centralization and had weak empirical support. The other addressed the effect of distribution on control and had strong empirical support. Dropping these conjectures does not affect the overall results.
  • 10
    • 0041107054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Abbott and Snidal 2000
    • Abbott and Snidal 2000.
  • 11
    • 0039920190 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Morrow defines noise as "the inability to determine exactly what happened and so to determine precisely the other side's responsibility for the event."
  • 12
    • 0041107055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The rationale for this kind of flexibility can be found in Downs and Rocke 1990; they argue that in the face of uncertainty about behavior the optimal strategies are often those that specify thresholds that trigger retaliation.
  • 13
    • 0039327814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wendt, this volume, 1028
    • Wendt, this volume, 1028.
  • 14
    • 0040513057 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid.
    • Ibid.
  • 15
    • 0041107047 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Koremenos 2000, which analyzes a random sample of 149 international agreements. Similar results on the flexibility of human rights agreements also emerge when we look at renegotiation provisions, withdrawal clauses, and amendment provisions
    • See Koremenos 2000, which analyzes a random sample of 149 international agreements. Similar results on the flexibility of human rights agreements also emerge when we look at renegotiation provisions, withdrawal clauses, and amendment provisions.
  • 16
    • 0039327809 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An additional problem arises because we do not present an exhaustive set of conjectures. Nor, as we state in the introduction, do the ones presented all flow from one carefully-specified model.
  • 17
    • 0039327810 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Fearon and Wendt point out that parallel critiques of rational choice in terms of bounded rationality (such as Simon's) have since been significantly clarified and narrowed by subsequent work on incomplete information games. See Fearon and Wendt 2001; and Simon 1957. Ongoing game-theoretic work in the evolutionary tradition is exploring the implications of limits to rationality - including ignorance about possible outcomes. Fudenberg and Levine 1998; and Rubinstein 1998.
  • 18
    • 0040512999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shubik makes an almost identical argument regarding the application of game theory to explain economic activity. Shubik 1982
    • Shubik makes an almost identical argument regarding the application of game theory to explain economic activity. Shubik 1982.
  • 19
    • 0041107049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Walt 1999
    • Walt 1999.
  • 20
    • 0041107050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A stylized fact is a summary statement of a circumstance or relationship that is observed across a wide range of situations and is taken either as an input into a modeling exercise or as something to be explained through it.
  • 21
    • 0039327811 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Pahre (pers. comm. with Koremenos and Snidal) offers the interesting observation that the more formal articles address only one or two of the conjectures, whereas the nonformal articles address between four and nine conjectures. This reflects the power of formal research in exploring the logic of a particular conjecture and the power of empirical cases in examining evidence on multiple conjectures within a case.
  • 22
    • 0040512997 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mearsheimer 1994/95
    • Mearsheimer 1994/95.
  • 23
    • 0040513059 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Power is notoriously difficult to conceptualize and theorize - both in the traditional and in the formal literature. An example of the latter is the attempt to treat patience (that is, a low discount rate) as a proxy for power in bargaining models, which we find unpersuasive from a substantive perspective.
  • 24
    • 0041106989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This example is from Kim 1999
    • This example is from Kim 1999.
  • 25
    • 0039327768 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitchell and Keilbach, this volume, 898
    • Mitchell and Keilbach, this volume, 898.
  • 26
    • 0040512998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This example draws on Wheelbarger 1999
    • This example draws on Wheelbarger 1999.
  • 27
    • 0041107048 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We thank an anonymous reviewer for bringing up this point.
  • 28
    • 0039920187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is not meant to denigrate our focus on design. Quite the contrary, design matters if the substantive provisions are going to come into effect and stay in effect.
  • 29
    • 0041106988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, one of our design features, scope, is substantive in nature. Indeed, the determination of scope may depend on the availability of powerful states to keep items off the agenda (agriculture out of GATT, for example) or to force them on the agenda (services in the WTO, for example).
  • 30
    • 0039920127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We view factors such as a state's position in the international economy or its position with respect to the international distribution of power as constraints and environmental conditions, not as preferences. Over time, of course, the environment may condition state preferences. The Rational Design conjectures, however, are comparative static hypotheses.
  • 31
    • 0039920126 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our categories are not intended to pigeonhole each article uniquely. For example, Richards' consideration of domestic factors fits both "gross characteristics" and "exogenous shocks."
  • 32
    • 0039920120 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an in-depth discussion of related issues, see Lake and Powell 1999, especially the introduction and the chapters by Peter Gourevitch and Jeffry Frieden
    • For an in-depth discussion of related issues, see Lake and Powell 1999, especially the introduction and the chapters by Peter Gourevitch and Jeffry Frieden.
  • 33
    • 0040512992 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rogowski 1989
    • Rogowski 1989.
  • 34
    • 0040512996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rosecrance 1986
    • Rosecrance 1986.
  • 35
    • 0039327760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 2001a
    • Koremenos 2001a.
  • 36
    • 0039327759 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wendt 1992
    • Wendt 1992.
  • 37
    • 0039920122 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Calvert 1995
    • Calvert 1995.
  • 38
    • 0039920123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 2001b
    • Koremenos 2001b.
  • 39
    • 0041106984 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Koremenos 1999b
    • Koremenos 1999b.
  • 40
    • 0041106977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Knight 1992; and Gruber 2000
    • See Knight 1992; and Gruber 2000.
  • 41
    • 0040512993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A highly instructive example is the long-standing difficulty that states have had in agreeing on televisions standards - even though all would benefit from a common standard - because of future implications for competitiveness. See Austin and Milner 2001; and, more generally, Abbott and Snidal 2001.
  • 42
    • 0040512989 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This echoes Krasner's change of regime and change within a regime. Krasner 1983
    • This echoes Krasner's change of regime and change within a regime. Krasner 1983.
  • 43
    • 0039327762 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axelrod and Keohane 1986, 251
    • Axelrod and Keohane 1986, 251.
  • 44
    • 0040512988 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For an overview of the complementarities and tensions between rational choice and evolutionary approaches, see Kahler 1999.
  • 45
    • 0039327756 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a fuller discussion, see the volume's introduction
    • For a fuller discussion, see the volume's introduction.
  • 46
    • 0039327761 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Abbott and Snidal 1998 and 2000. At a more technical level, Wendt misconstrues the implications of the "theory of the second best." Second best theory does not recommend that we stop trying to "maximize expected utility." Instead, it provides guidance on certain pitfalls in doing so.
  • 47
    • 0040512987 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In fact, one of the exciting areas of research in international relations has been on the role of normative factors in affecting international outcomes through persuasion and direct action. Margaret Keck and Kathryn Sikkink make the important point that normative actors must act strategically and take into account issues of institutional design if they are to achieve their goals. In short, normative actors need good designs. Keck and Sikkink 1998.
  • 48
    • 0039920124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For similar reasons, there is no need to presume that institutional designs must be all embracing. The best designs, like property rights in the market, often establish broad parameters within which individual actors determine specific outcomes through their actions.
  • 49
    • 0039327767 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Townsend 1988
    • Townsend 1988.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.