메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 68, Issue 1, 2000, Pages 187-201

The first principles approach to antitrust, Kodak, and antitrust at the millennium

(1)  Salop, Steven C a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0034418484     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (30)

References (43)
  • 1
    • 0345839536 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Serv. Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992)
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Serv. Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992).
  • 2
    • 0347731220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, we have now learned from the prequel to the trilogy, that the Star Wars depicted in the George Lucas films apparently started with a dispute over monopolized trade routes. Perhaps if the Jedi warriors of the Galactic Republic had developed a stronger and more credible antitrust policy, the resulting violence, high prices, and deadweight losses could have been avoided.
  • 3
    • 0347100790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kodak, 504 U.S. at 499 n.3
    • Kodak, 504 U.S. at 499 n.3.
  • 4
    • 0345839526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 496
    • Id. at 496.
  • 5
    • 0347100795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 479 n.29
    • Id. at 479 n.29.
  • 6
    • 84934453628 scopus 로고
    • The Limits of Antitrust
    • Frank E. Easterbrook, The Limits of Antitrust, 63 TEX. L. REV. 1, 14-16 (1984).
    • (1984) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.63 , pp. 1
    • Easterbrook, F.E.1
  • 7
    • 0342311510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wanted: A Market Definition Paradigm for Monopolization Cases
    • A number of these points have been made in recent articles, including Lawrence J. White, Wanted: A Market Definition Paradigm for Monopolization Cases, 4 COMPUTER INDUS. 1 (1999); Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation Under the Merger Guidelines: Monopoly Cases and Alternative Approaches, 16 REV. INDUS. ORG. 211 (2000).
    • (1999) Computer Indus. , vol.4 , pp. 1
    • White, L.J.1
  • 8
    • 0034036072 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Delineation under the Merger Guidelines: Monopoly Cases and Alternative Approaches
    • A number of these points have been made in recent articles, including Lawrence J. White, Wanted: A Market Definition Paradigm for Monopolization Cases, 4 COMPUTER INDUS. 1 (1999); Gregory J. Werden, Market Delineation Under the Merger Guidelines: Monopoly Cases and Alternative Approaches, 16 REV. INDUS. ORG. 211 (2000).
    • (2000) Rev. Indus. Org. , vol.16 , pp. 211
    • Werden, G.J.1
  • 9
    • 0347100750 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • To keep the exposition simpler in this essay, I generally will use the term market power, even in discussing Section 2 allegations. 9 504 U.S. at 480.
  • 10
    • 0040130485 scopus 로고
    • Market Power and Monopoly Power in Antitrust Law
    • For an earlier treatment of a number of the ideas in this section, see Thomas G. Krattenmaker, Robert H. Lande & Steven C. Salop, Market Power and Monopoly Power in Antitrust Law, 76 GEO. L.J. 241 (1987). The market definition discussion of price-down cases there, however, is superceded to some extent by the analysis in this essay. For a general approach that is similar to the first principles approach described here, see also A. Douglas Melamed, Exclusionary Vertical Agreements, Speech Before the ABA Antitrust Section (Apr. 2, 1998), available at 〈http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/speeches/1623 .htm〉.
    • (1987) Geo. L.J. , vol.76 , pp. 241
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1    Lande, R.H.2    Salop, S.C.3
  • 11
    • 0347731207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a tying claim, proof of distinct products and market power in the tying product market are required. In his dissent, Justice Scalia argued that replacement parts (the alleged tying product) and service (the alleged tied product) are not distinct products because all service may involve the installation of parts. Kodak, 504 U.S. at 495 n.2. Kodak itself argued that there is no demand for parts separate from service. Id. at 463.
  • 12
    • 0345839516 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As discussed below, analyses of merger cases can be problematic when the relevant anticompetitive allegation is that the merger will prevent prices from falling in the future.
  • 13
    • 0347100780 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. at 456-59, 480-85
    • 504 U.S. at 456-59, 480-85.
  • 14
    • 0347100776 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 482
    • Id. at 482.
  • 15
    • 84934452640 scopus 로고
    • Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Gain Power over Price
    • For a more detailed analysis of this two-step approach, see Thomas G. Krattenmaker & Steven C. Salop, Anticompetitive Exclusion: Raising Rivals' Costs to Gain Power Over Price, 96 YALE L.J. 209 (1986).
    • (1986) Yale L.J. , vol.96 , pp. 209
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 16
    • 0347731204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Court also pointed out that the inquiry could be framed in terms of either market power or market definition. Kodak, 504 U.S. at 469 n.15
    • The Court also pointed out that the inquiry could be framed in terms of either market power or market definition. Kodak, 504 U.S. at 469 n.15.
  • 17
    • 0347100781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 477-78
    • Id. at 477-78.
  • 18
    • 0346470403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • All of these traps also could be applied to analyses of the collective market power of a group of firms.
  • 19
    • 0345839515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Unilateral SSNIP Trap is closely related to the Threshold Test Trap. The two traps are distinguished because the errors to which they refer occur in different contexts. For example, the Unilateral SSNIP Trap could arise in a horizontal agreement case as well as in an exclusion case. In addition, the Unilateral SSNIP Trap focuses on the market definition methodology whereas the Threshold Test Trap focuses on an erroneous finding of market power.
  • 20
    • 0347731195 scopus 로고
    • The Consideration of Economics in Merger Cases
    • The greater the difference between price and marginal cost, the larger is the effect on the deadweight loss in economic surplus (consumer plus producer surplus) that results from changing output, when other factors are held constant. This suggests the need for greater antitrust concerns in those markets where the difference between price and marginal cost is greater. See Raymond Jackson, The Consideration of Economics in Merger Cases, 43 U. CHI. J. BUS. 439 (1970).
    • (1970) U. Chi. J. Bus. , vol.43 , pp. 439
    • Jackson, R.1
  • 21
    • 0347100775 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This benchmark is similar to the standard set forth in the draft of the Competitor Collaboration Guidelines. U.S. Federal Trade Commission, Draft Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors (Oct. 1, 1999) § 1.2, reprinted in 64 Fed. Reg. 54,484 (Oct. 6, 1999)
    • This benchmark is similar to the standard set forth in the draft of the Competitor Collaboration Guidelines. U.S. Federal Trade Commission, Draft Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborations Among Competitors (Oct. 1, 1999) § 1.2, reprinted in 64 Fed. Reg. 54,484 (Oct. 6, 1999).
  • 22
    • 0347731206 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Benjamin Klein prefers a market power test based on whether a firm's prices have any significant effect on market quantities. Klein, supra note 1, at 76. If one broadens the test, going beyond price to include the alleged anticompetitive conduct and to take into account the effect of the conduct on rivals' prices and outputs, then Klein's test moves closer to the first principles approach set out here. The analysis in this article may indeed be what Klein means when he discusses changes in market power. However, Klein's focus on market quantities raises the question of whether the two approaches are consistent; the question is complicated because Klein does not set out a market definition methodology. Id. at 85.
  • 23
    • 0346462168 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Defensive Leveraging in Antitrust
    • This article's analysis focuses on the market in which the alleged anticompetitive effects occur. Tying and other leverage theories also involve the evaluation of market power in a second market, the tying/leveraging product market. The resulting analysis may still involve a comparison to the perfectly competitive price, particularly in the case of per se offenses. However, it also may involve the power to exclude competitors profitably. This is because the fundamental issue is whether a firm has the power to profitably carry out the alleged anticompetitive leveraging conduct that causes harm in the tied product market. In contrast, in the case of leveraging used to maintain (i.e., defend) market power in the tying/leveraging market, the issue does not arise in the same way. See Robin C. Feldman, Defensive Leveraging in Antitrust, 87 GEO. L.J. 2079 (1999).
    • (1999) Geo. L.J. , vol.87 , pp. 2079
    • Feldman, R.C.1
  • 24
    • 0347731203 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992, as amended 1997), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104
    • U.S. Department of Justice & Federal Trade Commission, Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992, as amended 1997), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104.
  • 25
    • 0347731199 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Policy and the Cellophane Case
    • United States v. E.I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 351 U.S 377 (1956). For the classic statement of the Supreme Court's error, see Donald Turner, Antitrust Policy and the Cellophane Case, 70 HARV. L. REV. 281 (1956). See also Krattenmaker et al., supra note 11.
    • (1956) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.70 , pp. 281
    • Turner, D.1
  • 26
    • 0346470400 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 504 U.S. at 471
    • See 504 U.S. at 471.
  • 27
    • 0347731202 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951)
    • Lorain Journal Co. v. United States, 342 U.S. 143 (1951).
  • 28
    • 0347731201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961)
    • Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961).
  • 29
    • 0347731194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066 (D.D.C. 1997). The 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines contain a sentence that could cover this scenario. 1992 Merger Guidelines, supra note 24, § 1.11; see also Draft Competitor Collaboration Guidelines, supra note 21, at § 3.32
    • FTC v. Staples, Inc., 970 F. Supp. 1066 (D.D.C. 1997). The 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines contain a sentence that could cover this scenario. 1992 Merger Guidelines, supra note 24, § 1.11; see also Draft Competitor Collaboration Guidelines, supra note 21, at § 3.32.
  • 30
    • 0347100765 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • That is, even a monopolist faces competitive constraints from substitute products, which place a ceiling on its price. For example, see Judge Hand's discussion of foreign imports in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 426-27 (2d Cir. 1945)
    • That is, even a monopolist faces competitive constraints from substitute products, which place a ceiling on its price. For example, see Judge Hand's discussion of foreign imports in United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 426-27 (2d Cir. 1945).
  • 31
    • 0004004432 scopus 로고
    • For one example applied to distribution inputs, see ROBERT BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 156 (1979).
    • (1979) The Antitrust Paradox , pp. 156
    • Bork, R.1
  • 32
    • 0346470398 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207 (1959)
    • Klor's, Inc. v. Broadway-Hale Stores, Inc., 359 U.S. 207 (1959).
  • 33
    • 0347731200 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 209-10
    • Id. at 209-10.
  • 34
    • 0345839508 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 213
    • Id. at 213.
  • 35
    • 0347100752 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A SSNIP is a "small but significant and non-transitory increase in price." 1992 Merger Guidelines, supra note 24, § 1.0. A unilateral price increase is one that is not followed by rivals.
  • 36
    • 0347731183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Another aspect of this error arises out of a focus on unilateral price increases. The unilateral SSNIP test assumes that rivals would respond to the firm's price increase by expanding their output to meet additional demand as consumers substitute. However, it may be more profitable for competitors instead to raise their own prices in response to the firm's price increase, and it would be erroneous to ignore this potential price response. Market power is the ability to profitably raise price, taking rivals' expected responses into account. Thus, the expected response must be examined; one cannot simply assume that rivals will maintain their prices at the initial level.
  • 37
    • 0040130489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • You Keep on Knocking but You Can't Come In: Evaluating Restrictions on Access to Input Joint Ventures
    • For an example of a test of market power based on collective market share in the context of exclusionary conduct in joint ventures, see Dennis W. Carlton & Steven C. Salop, You Keep on Knocking But You Can't Come In: Evaluating Restrictions on Access to Input Joint Ventures, 9 HARV. J.L. & TECH. 319 (1996).
    • (1996) Harv. J.L. & Tech. , vol.9 , pp. 319
    • Carlton, D.W.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 38
    • 0347100766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As evidence that this point is indeed a matter of first principles, Fred Kahn pointed out to me that it was recognized as far back as United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel, 85 F. 271, 292 (6th Cir. 1898), by Judge Taft: "Much evidence is adduced upon affidavit to prove that defendants had no power arbitrarily to fix price, and that they were always obliged to meet competition. . . . The most cogent evidence that they had this power is the fact, everywhere apparent in this record, that they exercised it."
  • 39
    • 0347100770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 504 U.S. at 477
    • 504 U.S. at 477.
  • 40
    • 0345839507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This approach also has been followed by a number of lower courts. Re/Max Int'l, Inc. v. Realty One, Inc., 173 F.3d 995, 1016-19 (6th Cir. 1999); see Coastal Fuels of Puerto Rico, Inc. v. Caribbean Petroleum Corp., 79 F.3d 182, 196-97 (1st Cir. 1996); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995); Flegel v. Christian Hosp., 4 F.3d 682, 688 (8th Cir. 1993); Reazin v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Kan., Inc., 899 F.2d 951, 966-67 (10th Cir. 1990); Byars v. Bluff City News Co., 609 F. 2d. 843, 850 (6th Cir. 1979)
    • This approach also has been followed by a number of lower courts. Re/Max Int'l, Inc. v. Realty One, Inc., 173 F.3d 995, 1016-19 (6th Cir. 1999); see Coastal Fuels of Puerto Rico, Inc. v. Caribbean Petroleum Corp., 79 F.3d 182, 196-97 (1st Cir. 1996); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995); Flegel v. Christian Hosp., 4 F.3d 682, 688 (8th Cir. 1993); Reazin v. Blue Cross & Blue Shield of Kan., Inc., 899 F.2d 951, 966-67 (10th Cir. 1990); Byars v. Bluff City News Co., 609 F. 2d. 843, 850 (6th Cir. 1979).
  • 41
    • 0347100764 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460-61 (1986) (quoting 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1511, at 429 (1986)); see also NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 109-11 n.42 (1984)
    • FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460-61 (1986) (quoting 7 PHILLIP AREEDA, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 1511, at 429 (1986)); see also NCAA v. Board of Regents, 468 U.S. 85, 109-11 n.42 (1984).
  • 42
    • 0005831064 scopus 로고
    • Horizontal Mergers: Triage and Treatment
    • For a similar commentary in the context of merger analysis, see Franklin M. Fisher, Horizontal Mergers: Triage and Treatment, 1 J. ECON. PERSP. 23, 30 (1987); Jonathan Baker, Product Differentiation Issues Through Space and Time: Some Antitrust Policy Issues, 42 ANTITRUST BULL. 177, 185 (1997).
    • (1987) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.1 , pp. 23
    • Fisher, F.M.1
  • 43
    • 0040487715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Product Differentiation Issues Through Space and Time: Some Antitrust Policy Issues
    • For a similar commentary in the context of merger analysis, see Franklin M. Fisher, Horizontal Mergers: Triage and Treatment, 1 J. ECON. PERSP. 23, 30 (1987); Jonathan Baker, Product Differentiation Issues Through Space and Time: Some Antitrust Policy Issues, 42 ANTITRUST BULL. 177, 185 (1997).
    • (1997) Antitrust Bull. , vol.42 , pp. 177
    • Baker, J.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.