-
1
-
-
0001654516
-
Pyramids of Sacrifice? Problems of Federalism in Mandating State Implementation of National Environmental Policy
-
See Richard B. Steward 'Pyramids of Sacrifice? Problems of Federalism in Mandating State Implementation of National Environmental Policy', 86 Yale LJ 1196 (1977).
-
(1977)
Yale LJ
, vol.86
, pp. 1196
-
-
Steward, R.B.1
-
2
-
-
1842753917
-
'Hastening Slowly: The Communities' Path Towards Harmonization
-
Helen Wallace, William Wallace, and Carole Webb (eds)
-
See Alan Dashwood, 'Hastening Slowly: The Communities' Path Towards Harmonization' in Helen Wallace, William Wallace, and Carole Webb (eds), Policy-Making in the European Communities 273 (1977).
-
(1977)
Policy-Making in the European Communities
, vol.273
-
-
Dashwood, A.1
-
3
-
-
84933479479
-
Trade and Environmental Protection in the Context of World Trade Rules: A View from the European Union
-
See Damien Geradin, 'Trade and Environmental Protection in the Context of World Trade Rules: A View from the European Union', Eur Foreign Affairs Rev 33 (1997).
-
(1997)
Eur Foreign Affairs Rev
, vol.33
-
-
Geradin, D.1
-
4
-
-
0000821053
-
Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle
-
hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product'
-
See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
-
(1985)
J l Econ & Organization
, vol.1
, pp. 225
-
-
Romano, R.1
-
5
-
-
0000015761
-
Economic Competition among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing
-
See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
-
(1988)
J Pub Econ
, vol.35
, pp. 333
-
-
Oates, W.B.1
Schwab, R.M.2
-
6
-
-
0000821053
-
Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation
-
hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'
-
See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
-
(1992)
NYU l Rev
, vol.67
, pp. 1210
-
-
Revesz, R.L.1
-
7
-
-
0002575839
-
State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1977)
J Legal Stud
, vol.6
, pp. 25
-
-
Winter, R.K.1
-
8
-
-
0042881439
-
-
above n 4
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
Law as a Product
-
-
Romano1
-
9
-
-
0003207194
-
Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1998)
Yale LJ
, vol.107
, pp. 2359
-
-
Romano, R.1
-
10
-
-
0002636355
-
Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism
-
hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1983)
J l & Econ
, vol.26
, pp. 23
-
-
Easterbrook, F.H.1
-
11
-
-
0041378509
-
The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System
-
hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1988)
Cornell l Rev
, vol.73
, pp. 677
-
-
Butler, H.N.1
Macey, J.R.2
-
12
-
-
85037503649
-
-
above n 4
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
Rehabilitating
-
-
Revesz1
-
13
-
-
0042380439
-
Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1985)
BU l Rev
, vol.65
, pp. 1
-
-
Rice, D.A.1
-
14
-
-
0001191913
-
The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics
-
hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity'
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1994)
Maastricht J Eur & Comp l
, vol.1
, pp. 337
-
-
Van Den Bergh, R.1
-
15
-
-
0031696813
-
Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1998)
Eur Env l Rev
, vol.6
, pp. 169
-
-
Faure, M.1
-
16
-
-
0042881405
-
Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1994)
Int'l Rev l & Econ
, vol.14
, pp. 177
-
-
Hertig, G.1
-
17
-
-
85050833168
-
International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1993)
Harv Int'l LJ
, vol.34
, pp. 47
-
-
Trachtman, J.P.1
-
18
-
-
0040569876
-
The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy
-
hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1996)
Yale l & Policy Rev
, vol.14
, pp. 177
-
-
Klevorick, A.K.1
-
19
-
-
0031476662
-
National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1997)
Fordham l Rev
, vol.65
, pp. 1855
-
-
Choi, S.J.1
Guzman, A.T.2
-
20
-
-
0041378454
-
Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds
-
The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
-
(1996)
Va J Int'l l
, vol.36
, pp. 467
-
-
Bernard, C.B.1
-
22
-
-
0004170749
-
-
We borrow the concept of 'co-opetition' from Adam Brandenburg and Barry Nalebuff's recent book of the same name. See Adam M. Brandenburg and Barry J. Nalebuff, Co-opetition (1996). The book explains that the optimal strategy for business is often a mix of competitive and cooperative actions.
-
(1996)
Co-opetition
-
-
Brandenburg, A.M.1
Nalebuff, B.J.2
-
23
-
-
0346307773
-
The New Economics of Jurisdictional Competition: Devolutionary Federalism in a Second Best World
-
See William W. Bratton and Joseph A. McCahery, 'The New Economics of Jurisdictional Competition: Devolutionary Federalism in a Second Best World', 86 Georgetown LJ 201 (1997).
-
(1997)
Georgetown LJ
, vol.86
, pp. 201
-
-
Bratton, W.W.1
McCahery, J.A.2
-
24
-
-
0442296928
-
Non-Governmental Organizations at the World Trade Organization: Cooperation Competition, or Exclusion
-
hereinafter Esty, 'Cooperation'
-
See Daniel C. Esty, 'Non-Governmental Organizations at the World Trade Organization: Cooperation Competition, or Exclusion', 1 J Int'l Econ L 123 (1998) [hereinafter Esty, 'Cooperation'].
-
(1998)
J Int'l Econ l
, vol.1
, pp. 123
-
-
Esty, D.C.1
-
25
-
-
22844456465
-
Toward Optimal Environmental Governance
-
hereinafter Esty, 'Optimal'
-
See Daniel C. Esty, 'Toward Optimal Environmental Governance', 74 NYU L Rev 1495 (1999) [hereinafter Esty, 'Optimal'].
-
(1999)
NYU l Rev
, vol.74
, pp. 1495
-
-
Esty, D.C.1
-
26
-
-
0000778367
-
A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures
-
See Charles Tiebout, 'A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures', 64 J Pol Econ 416 (1956).
-
(1956)
J Pol Econ
, vol.64
, pp. 416
-
-
Tiebout, C.1
-
29
-
-
0038992258
-
A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers: In Defense of United States v. Lopez
-
See Stephen G. Calabresi, 'A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers: In Defense of United States v. Lopez', 94 Mich L Rev 752 (1995).
-
(1995)
Mich l Rev
, vol.94
, pp. 752
-
-
Calabresi, S.G.1
-
30
-
-
77958396817
-
Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control
-
See Matthew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast, 'Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control', 3 J L Econ & Organization 243 (1987); Jerry L. Mashaw, Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law (1997).
-
(1987)
J l Econ & Organization
, vol.3
, pp. 243
-
-
McCubbins, M.D.1
Noll, R.G.2
Weingast, B.R.3
-
31
-
-
77958396817
-
-
See Matthew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast, 'Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control', 3 J L Econ & Organization 243 (1987); Jerry L. Mashaw, Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law (1997).
-
(1997)
Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law
-
-
Mashaw, J.L.1
-
32
-
-
0346673033
-
Symposium: The Allocation of Government Authority: Environmental Federalism in a Global Economy
-
If faithfully applied, the regulatory competition model would suggest that global free trade agreements are also unnecessary, since localities should adopt optimal trade policies on their own. Yet in the WTO arena, regulatory competition advocates recognize market failures of the kind discussed below. For a discussion of this apparent contradiction, see Daniel Farber, 'Symposium: The Allocation of Government Authority: Environmental Federalism in a Global Economy', 83 Va L Rev 1283 (1997).
-
(1997)
Va l Rev
, vol.83
, pp. 1283
-
-
Farber, D.1
-
34
-
-
85037491950
-
-
above n 10
-
See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
-
Optimal
-
-
Esty1
-
37
-
-
0042881412
-
Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions
-
hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers'
-
See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions', 1992 U Chi Legal F 41 [hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers']; Wouter Wils, 'Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously', 6 J Env L 85 (1994).
-
U Chi Legal f
, vol.1992
, pp. 41
-
-
Stewart, R.B.1
-
38
-
-
0028569297
-
Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously
-
See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions', 1992 U Chi Legal F 41 [hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers']; Wouter Wils, 'Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously', 6 J Env L 85 (1994).
-
(1994)
J Env l
, vol.6
, pp. 85
-
-
Wils, W.1
-
39
-
-
0042380469
-
Environmental Protection, Economic Conflict and the European Community
-
See Owen Lomas, 'Environmental Protection, Economic Conflict and the European Community', 33 McGill LJ 506 (1988).
-
(1988)
McGill LJ
, vol.33
, pp. 506
-
-
Lomas, O.1
-
40
-
-
3142731193
-
-
above n 4
-
There is an ongoing debate, which we will not rehash here, about whether economic externalities are 'real' or merely pecuniary. Compare Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 with Daniel C. Esty, 'Revitalizing Environmental Federalism' 95 Mich L Rev 570 (1996) [hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing].
-
Rehabilitating
-
-
Revesz1
-
41
-
-
3142731193
-
Revitalizing Environmental Federalism
-
hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing
-
There is an ongoing debate, which we will not rehash here, about whether economic externalities are 'real' or merely pecuniary. Compare Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 with Daniel C. Esty, 'Revitalizing Environmental Federalism' 95 Mich L Rev 570 (1996) [hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing].
-
(1996)
Mich l Rev
, vol.95
, pp. 570
-
-
Esty, D.C.1
-
44
-
-
0010653735
-
The State Competition Debate in Corporate Law
-
See Roberta Romano, 'The State Competition Debate in Corporate Law', 8 Cardozo L Rev 709 (1987).
-
(1987)
Cardozo l Rev
, vol.8
, pp. 709
-
-
Romano, R.1
-
45
-
-
85037491950
-
-
above n 10
-
See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
-
Optimal
-
-
Esty1
-
47
-
-
84928439790
-
Competition among Jurisdictions in Formulating Corporate Rules: An American Perspective on the "Race to the Bottom" in the European Communities
-
See David Charny, 'Competition Among Jurisdictions in Formulating Corporate Rules: An American Perspective on the "Race to the Bottom" in the European Communities', 32 Harv Int'l LJ 423 (1991).
-
(1991)
Harv Int'l LJ
, vol.32
, pp. 423
-
-
Charny, D.1
-
48
-
-
0042380429
-
Federalism and Corporate Law
-
Ingolf Pernice (ed)
-
See Helmut Kohl, 'Federalism and Corporate Law' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 129; Friedrich Kübler, 'Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 171.
-
(1996)
Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems
, pp. 129
-
-
Kohl, H.1
-
49
-
-
25344432306
-
Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective
-
Ingolf Pernice (ed)
-
See Helmut Kohl, 'Federalism and Corporate Law' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 129; Friedrich Kübler, 'Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 171.
-
(1996)
Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems
, pp. 171
-
-
Kübler, F.1
-
50
-
-
0004188201
-
-
Industry sectors where large economies of scale can be achieved (e.g. electricity production and transmission) are generally considered to be 'natural monopolies'. See Alfred Kahn, The Economics of Regulation (1970). Similarly, areas where important regulatory economies of scale can be achieved may be considered to be 'natural legal monopolies'.
-
(1970)
The Economics of Regulation
-
-
Kahn, A.1
-
53
-
-
0040810951
-
The Limited Role of Regulatory Harmonization in International Goods and Services Markets
-
See Alan O. Sykes, Product Standards for Internationally Integrated Goods and Markets (1995); Alan O. Sykes, 'The Limited Role of Regulatory Harmonization in International Goods and Services Markets', 2 J Int'l Econ L 49 (1999).
-
(1999)
J Int'l Econ l
, vol.2
, pp. 49
-
-
-
54
-
-
22044443889
-
Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework
-
Esty and Geradin explain that 'harmonization' need not imply absolutely uniform standards. Alternative forms of harmonization or regulatory 'convergence' may permit some degree of standardization without the concomitant efficiency losses that single standards that do not match local needs generate. See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework', 32 J World Trade 5 (1998). Harmonization debates themselves often entail competition over whose standards should be adopted. And agreement on a common standard need not bring an end to regulatory competition. Many forms of harmonization are flexible and open enough to allow continued debate over and refinement of the standards selected. See also Piet Jan Slot, 'Harmonization', 21 Eur L Rev 378 (1996).
-
(1998)
J World Trade
, vol.32
, pp. 5
-
-
Esty, D.C.1
Geradin, D.2
-
55
-
-
0042881403
-
Harmonization
-
Esty and Geradin explain that 'harmonization' need not imply absolutely uniform standards. Alternative forms of harmonization or regulatory 'convergence' may permit some degree of standardization without the concomitant efficiency losses that single standards that do not match local needs generate. See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework', 32 J World Trade 5 (1998). Harmonization debates themselves often entail competition over whose standards should be adopted. And agreement on a common standard need not bring an end to regulatory competition. Many forms of harmonization are flexible and open enough to allow continued debate over and refinement of the standards selected. See also Piet Jan Slot, 'Harmonization', 21 Eur L Rev 378 (1996).
-
(1996)
Eur l Rev
, vol.21
, pp. 378
-
-
Slot, P.J.1
-
60
-
-
0027047960
-
Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade
-
See Steve Charnovitz, 'Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade', 15 World Economy 335 (1992); Brian Langille, 'Eight Ways to Think About International Labour Standards', 31 J World Trade 27 (1997).
-
(1992)
World Economy
, vol.15
, pp. 335
-
-
Charnovitz, S.1
-
61
-
-
0003135754
-
Eight Ways to Think about International Labour Standards
-
See Steve Charnovitz, 'Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade', 15 World Economy 335 (1992); Brian Langille, 'Eight Ways to Think About International Labour Standards', 31 J World Trade 27 (1997).
-
(1997)
J World Trade
, vol.31
, pp. 27
-
-
Langille, B.1
-
63
-
-
0027073647
-
Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?
-
Patrick Low (ed)
-
See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
-
(1992)
International Trade and the Environment
, pp. 89
-
-
Low, P.1
Yeats, A.2
-
64
-
-
0027073647
-
Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?
-
See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
-
(1995)
J Econ Literature
, vol.33
, pp. 132
-
-
Jaffe, A.B.1
-
65
-
-
0027073647
-
-
above n 5
-
See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
-
Lessons
-
-
Klevorick1
-
66
-
-
0002282460
-
Let Them Eat Pollution
-
22 February
-
See, for example, Lawrence Summers's (in)famous World Bank internal memorandum leaked to the press, explaining that it is economically efficient to encourage migration of dirty industries to less developed nations. See 'Let Them Eat Pollution', The Economist 66 (22 February 1992).
-
(1992)
The Economist
, vol.66
-
-
-
67
-
-
0030825666
-
An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows
-
See Cees van Beers and Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh, 'An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows', 50 Kyklos 29 (1997); Muthukumara Mani and David Wheeler, 'In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995' in Per G. Fredriksson (ed), Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment (1999) 115.
-
(1997)
Kyklos
, vol.50
, pp. 29
-
-
Van Beers, C.1
Van Den Bergh, J.C.J.M.2
-
68
-
-
0003902583
-
In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995
-
Per G. Fredriksson (ed)
-
See Cees van Beers and Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh, 'An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows', 50 Kyklos 29 (1997); Muthukumara Mani and David Wheeler, 'In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995' in Per G. Fredriksson (ed), Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment (1999) 115.
-
(1999)
Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment
, pp. 115
-
-
Mani, M.1
Wheeler, D.2
-
69
-
-
0346615644
-
Market Access, Competitiveness, and Harmonization: Environmental Protection in Regional Trade Agreements
-
hereinafter Esty and Geradin, 'Market Access'
-
See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Market Access, Competitiveness, and Harmonization: Environmental Protection in Regional Trade Agreements', 21 Harv Env L Rev 265 (1997) [hereinafter Esty and Geradin, 'Market Access'].
-
(1997)
Harv Env l Rev
, vol.21
, pp. 265
-
-
Esty, D.C.1
Geradin, D.2
-
71
-
-
85037491950
-
-
above n 10
-
See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
-
Optimal
-
-
Esty1
-
74
-
-
85037520403
-
France Imposes Emergency Bans on Phtalates in Baby Toys
-
16 July
-
See 'France Imposes Emergency Bans on Phtalates in Baby Toys', Environment Watch 9 (16 July 1999).
-
(1999)
Environment Watch
, vol.9
-
-
-
76
-
-
0005264157
-
Collaborative Government in the Administrative State
-
See Jody Freeman, 'Collaborative Government in the Administrative State', 45 UCLA L Rev 1 (1997).
-
(1997)
UCLA l Rev
, vol.45
, pp. 1
-
-
Freeman, J.1
-
78
-
-
77953495821
-
Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness
-
See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness', 102 Yale LJ 2039 (1993). See also, Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr. and Eric W. Orts, 'Environmental Contracts in the United States' (unpublished manuscript) (1999).
-
(1993)
Yale LJ
, vol.102
, pp. 2039
-
-
Stewart, R.B.1
-
79
-
-
0042380438
-
-
unpublished manuscript
-
See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness', 102 Yale LJ 2039 (1993). See also, Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr. and Eric W. Orts, 'Environmental Contracts in the United States' (unpublished manuscript) (1999).
-
(1999)
Environmental Contracts in the United States
-
-
Hazard, G.C.1
Jr2
Orts, E.W.3
-
81
-
-
85037509953
-
Regulatory Competition: Promoting Trade while Facilitating Consumer Protection
-
5 December (on file with author)
-
See 'Regulatory Competition: Promoting Trade While Facilitating Consumer Protection', Joint Statement of US-EU Summit (5 December 1997) (on file with author).
-
(1997)
Joint Statement of US-EU Summit
-
-
-
82
-
-
34548658887
-
Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy
-
Fordham Corporate Law Institute
-
See Douglas Melamed, 'Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy', 25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, Fordham Corporate Law Institute (1998); Alex Schaub, 'International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings', Competition Policy Newsletter 1, 3 (1998) (on file with author).
-
(1998)
25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy
-
-
Melamed, D.1
-
83
-
-
0002159256
-
International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings
-
on file with author
-
See Douglas Melamed, 'Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy', 25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, Fordham Corporate Law Institute (1998); Alex Schaub, 'International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings', Competition Policy Newsletter 1, 3 (1998) (on file with author).
-
(1998)
Competition Policy Newsletter
, vol.1-3
-
-
Schaub, A.1
-
84
-
-
0041879214
-
TRIPS: Adequate Protection, Inadequate Trade, Adequate Competition Policy
-
See Hans Ullrich, 'TRIPS: Adequate Protection, Inadequate Trade, Adequate Competition Policy', 4 Pac Rim L & Policy J 153 (1995).
-
(1995)
Pac Rim l & Policy J
, vol.4
, pp. 153
-
-
Ullrich, H.1
-
85
-
-
21744441837
-
Telecommunications Services and the World Trade Organization
-
See Marco Bronckers and Pierre Larouche, 'Telecommunications Services and the World Trade Organization', 31 J World Trade 5 (1997).
-
(1997)
J World Trade
, vol.31
, pp. 5
-
-
Bronckers, M.1
Larouche, P.2
-
86
-
-
21344459958
-
International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business
-
See Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann, 'International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business', 30 J World Trade 5 (1996); Aaditya Mattoo and Arvind Subramanian, 'Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward', 31 J World Trade 129 (1997).
-
(1996)
J World Trade
, vol.30
, pp. 5
-
-
Petersmann, E.-U.1
-
87
-
-
18744428409
-
Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward
-
See Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann, 'International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business', 30 J World Trade 5 (1996); Aaditya Mattoo and Arvind Subramanian, 'Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward', 31 J World Trade 129 (1997).
-
(1997)
J World Trade
, vol.31
, pp. 129
-
-
Mattoo, A.1
Subramanian, A.2
-
88
-
-
0023520760
-
The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview
-
See Steve Charnovitz, 'The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview', 126 Int'l Labor Rev 565 (1987).
-
(1987)
Int'l Labor Rev
, vol.126
, pp. 565
-
-
Charnovitz, S.1
-
90
-
-
0042380425
-
Harmonizing Phyto-sanitary and Sanitary Regulations
-
See Maury E. Bredahl and Kenneth W. Forsythe, 'Harmonizing Phyto-sanitary and Sanitary Regulations', 12 World Econ 189 (1989).
-
(1989)
World Econ
, vol.12
, pp. 189
-
-
Bredahl, M.E.1
Forsythe, K.W.2
-
93
-
-
0002056667
-
Environmental Policy from the Seventies to the Nineties: Continuity and Change
-
Norman J. Vig and Michael E. Kraft (eds)
-
See Michael E. Kraft and Norman J. Vig, 'Environmental Policy from the Seventies to the Nineties: Continuity and Change' in Norman J. Vig and Michael E. Kraft (eds), Environmental Policy in the 1990s (1990).
-
(1990)
Environmental Policy in the 1990s
-
-
Kraft, M.E.1
Vig, N.J.2
-
94
-
-
0041879207
-
Environment Ministers to Revise EMAS, Eco-Label Program to Boost Participation
-
See 'Environment Ministers to Revise EMAS, Eco-Label Program to Boost Participation', 22 Int'l Env Rptr 570 (1999).
-
(1999)
Int'l Env Rptr
, vol.22
, pp. 570
-
-
-
97
-
-
85037491950
-
-
above n 10
-
See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
-
Optimal
-
-
Esty1
-
98
-
-
54649084015
-
-
above n 48
-
See Albert Breton, Competitive Governments, above n 48; Michael Trebilock and Robert Howse, 'Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics', 6 Eur J L & Econ 5 (1998).
-
Competitive Governments
-
-
Breton, A.1
-
99
-
-
54649084015
-
Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics
-
See Albert Breton, Competitive Governments, above n 48; Michael Trebilock and Robert Howse, 'Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics', 6 Eur J L & Econ 5 (1998).
-
(1998)
Eur J l & Econ
, vol.6
, pp. 5
-
-
Trebilock, M.1
Howse, R.2
-
100
-
-
84964701087
-
Competition between National Legal Systems: A Contribution of Economic Analysis to Comparative Law
-
hereinafter Ogus, 'Competition'
-
As pointed out by Ogus, competition may also take place between different court systems with overlapping jurisdictions. For instance, the struggle between the Chancery Courts and their Common Law rivals had a significant impact on the development of legal principles in the United Kingdom. See Anthony Ogus, 'Competition Between National Legal Systems: A Contribution of Economic Analysis to Comparative Law', 48 Intl & Comp LQ 405 (1999) [hereinafter Ogus, 'Competition'].
-
(1999)
Intl & Comp LQ
, vol.48
, pp. 405
-
-
Ogus, A.1
-
102
-
-
84942233960
-
-
above n 71
-
To some extent, political parties competing for power can be compared to firms engaged in a competitive bidding for a monopolistic franchise power to provide a service, the competition serving to ensure that the firm offering the most efficient prices and services will be selected. See Ogus, 'Competition', above n 71.
-
Competition
-
-
Ogus1
-
104
-
-
0042380434
-
Thirty Firms Plan Pilot on Emissions Trading in Effort to Head off Proposed Energy Tax
-
See Peta Firth, 'Thirty Firms Plan Pilot on Emissions Trading in Effort to Head off Proposed Energy Tax', 22 Int'l Env Rptr 580 (1999).
-
(1999)
Int'l Env Rptr
, vol.22
, pp. 580
-
-
Firth, P.1
-
105
-
-
85037520550
-
Environmental Agreements: A New Instrument of Environmental Policy
-
RSC 97/45 (on file with author)
-
See Eckard Rehbinder, 'Environmental Agreements: A New Instrument of Environmental Policy', Jean Monnet Chair Paper, RSC 97/45 (1997) (on file with author).
-
(1997)
Jean Monnet Chair Paper
-
-
Rehbinder, E.1
-
107
-
-
85037502092
-
-
note
-
Thanks to Professor Dan Farber for highlighting this concept.
-
-
-
|