메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 3, Issue 2, 2000, Pages 235-255

Regulatory co-opetition

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0034379971     PISSN: 13693034     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1093/jiel/3.2.235     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (74)

References (107)
  • 1
    • 0001654516 scopus 로고
    • Pyramids of Sacrifice? Problems of Federalism in Mandating State Implementation of National Environmental Policy
    • See Richard B. Steward 'Pyramids of Sacrifice? Problems of Federalism in Mandating State Implementation of National Environmental Policy', 86 Yale LJ 1196 (1977).
    • (1977) Yale LJ , vol.86 , pp. 1196
    • Steward, R.B.1
  • 2
    • 1842753917 scopus 로고
    • 'Hastening Slowly: The Communities' Path Towards Harmonization
    • Helen Wallace, William Wallace, and Carole Webb (eds)
    • See Alan Dashwood, 'Hastening Slowly: The Communities' Path Towards Harmonization' in Helen Wallace, William Wallace, and Carole Webb (eds), Policy-Making in the European Communities 273 (1977).
    • (1977) Policy-Making in the European Communities , vol.273
    • Dashwood, A.1
  • 3
    • 84933479479 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade and Environmental Protection in the Context of World Trade Rules: A View from the European Union
    • See Damien Geradin, 'Trade and Environmental Protection in the Context of World Trade Rules: A View from the European Union', Eur Foreign Affairs Rev 33 (1997).
    • (1997) Eur Foreign Affairs Rev , vol.33
    • Geradin, D.1
  • 4
    • 0000821053 scopus 로고
    • Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle
    • hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product'
    • See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
    • (1985) J l Econ & Organization , vol.1 , pp. 225
    • Romano, R.1
  • 5
    • 0000015761 scopus 로고
    • Economic Competition among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing
    • See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
    • (1988) J Pub Econ , vol.35 , pp. 333
    • Oates, W.B.1    Schwab, R.M.2
  • 6
    • 0000821053 scopus 로고
    • Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation
    • hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'
    • See Roberta Romano, 'Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle', 1 J L Econ & Organization 225 (1985) [hereinafter Romano, 'Law as a Product']; Wallace B. Oates and Robert M. Schwab, 'Economic Competition Among Jurisdictions: Efficiency Enhancing or Distortion Inducing', 35 J Pub Econ 333 (1988); Richard L. Revesz, 'Rehabilitating Interstate Competition: Rethinking the "Race to the Bottom" Rationale for Federal Environmental Regulation', 67 NYU L Rev 1210 (1992) [hereinafter Revesz, 'Rehabilitating'].
    • (1992) NYU l Rev , vol.67 , pp. 1210
    • Revesz, R.L.1
  • 7
    • 0002575839 scopus 로고
    • State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1977) J Legal Stud , vol.6 , pp. 25
    • Winter, R.K.1
  • 8
    • 0042881439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 4
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • Law as a Product
    • Romano1
  • 9
    • 0003207194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1998) Yale LJ , vol.107 , pp. 2359
    • Romano, R.1
  • 10
    • 0002636355 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism
    • hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1983) J l & Econ , vol.26 , pp. 23
    • Easterbrook, F.H.1
  • 11
    • 0041378509 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System
    • hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1988) Cornell l Rev , vol.73 , pp. 677
    • Butler, H.N.1    Macey, J.R.2
  • 12
    • 85037503649 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 4
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • Rehabilitating
    • Revesz1
  • 13
    • 0042380439 scopus 로고
    • Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1985) BU l Rev , vol.65 , pp. 1
    • Rice, D.A.1
  • 14
    • 0001191913 scopus 로고
    • The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics
    • hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity'
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1994) Maastricht J Eur & Comp l , vol.1 , pp. 337
    • Van Den Bergh, R.1
  • 15
    • 0031696813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1998) Eur Env l Rev , vol.6 , pp. 169
    • Faure, M.1
  • 16
    • 0042881405 scopus 로고
    • Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1994) Int'l Rev l & Econ , vol.14 , pp. 177
    • Hertig, G.1
  • 17
    • 85050833168 scopus 로고
    • International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1993) Harv Int'l LJ , vol.34 , pp. 47
    • Trachtman, J.P.1
  • 18
    • 0040569876 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy
    • hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1996) Yale l & Policy Rev , vol.14 , pp. 177
    • Klevorick, A.K.1
  • 19
    • 0031476662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1997) Fordham l Rev , vol.65 , pp. 1855
    • Choi, S.J.1    Guzman, A.T.2
  • 20
    • 0041378454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds
    • The regulatory competition model has had a major impact on the federalism debate in the United States. The regulatory competition-based argument for decentralized governance has been applied by its proponents to regulatory areas as diverse as corporation, securities, antitrust, banking, environmental, and product safety law. See Ralph K. Winter, 'State Law, Shareholder Protection, and the Theory of the Corporation', 6 J Legal Stud 25 (1977) (corporation); Romano, 'Law as a Product', above n 4 (corporation); Roberta Romano, 'Empowering Investors: A Market Approach to Securities Regulation', 107 Yale LJ 2359 (1998) (securities); Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Antitrust and the Economics of Federalism', 26 J L & Econ 23 (1983) [hereinafter Easterbrook, 'Antitrust'] (antitrust); Henry N. Butler and Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Myth of Competition in the Dual Banking System', 73 Cornell L Rev 677 (1988) [hereinafter Butler and Macey, 'The Myth'] (banking); Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 (environmental); David A. Rice, 'Product Quality Laws and the Economics of Federalism', 65 BU L Rev 1 (1985) (product safety). The regulatory competition model has also crossed the Atlantic and become a source of reference for those searching to define the scope of the obscure principle of 'subsidiarity'. See Roger Van den Bergh, 'The Subsidiarity Principle in European Economic Law: Some Insights from Law and Economics', 1 Maastricht J Eur & Comp L 337 (1994) [hereinafter Van den Bergh, 'Subsidiarity']; Michael Faure, 'Harmonisation of Environmental Law and Market Integration: Harmonising for the Wrong Reasons?', 6 Eur Env L Rev 169 (1998); Gerard Hertig, 'Imperfect Mutual Recognition for EC Financial Services', 14 Int'l Rev L & Econ 177 (1994). EU-based regulatory competition theorists argue that, contrary to the ambitious policy of regulatory harmonization that has been pursued for several decades by the European Commission, decentralized regulation should be the rule and centralization the exception. Regulatory competition theory has begun to penetrate academic discussions in the area of international law, as authors use this model to praise the virtues of regulatory heterogeneity in areas such as environmental law and international finance. See Joel P. Trachtman, 'International Regulatory Competition, Externalization and Jurisdiction', 34 Harv Int'l LJ 47 (1993) (international law); Alvin K. Klevorick, 'The Race to the Bottom in a Federal System: Lessons from the World of Trade Policy', 14 Yale L & Policy Rev 177 (1996) [hereinafter Klevorick, 'Lessons'] (environmental law); Steven J. Choi and Andrew T. Guzman, 'National Laws, International Money: Regulation in a Global Capital Market', 65 Fordham L Rev 1855 (1997) (international finance); Christopher B. Bernard, 'Towards an International Market in Mutual Funds', 36 Va J Int'l L 467 (1996) (international finance).
    • (1996) Va J Int'l l , vol.36 , pp. 467
    • Bernard, C.B.1
  • 22
    • 0004170749 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We borrow the concept of 'co-opetition' from Adam Brandenburg and Barry Nalebuff's recent book of the same name. See Adam M. Brandenburg and Barry J. Nalebuff, Co-opetition (1996). The book explains that the optimal strategy for business is often a mix of competitive and cooperative actions.
    • (1996) Co-opetition
    • Brandenburg, A.M.1    Nalebuff, B.J.2
  • 23
    • 0346307773 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The New Economics of Jurisdictional Competition: Devolutionary Federalism in a Second Best World
    • See William W. Bratton and Joseph A. McCahery, 'The New Economics of Jurisdictional Competition: Devolutionary Federalism in a Second Best World', 86 Georgetown LJ 201 (1997).
    • (1997) Georgetown LJ , vol.86 , pp. 201
    • Bratton, W.W.1    McCahery, J.A.2
  • 24
    • 0442296928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Non-Governmental Organizations at the World Trade Organization: Cooperation Competition, or Exclusion
    • hereinafter Esty, 'Cooperation'
    • See Daniel C. Esty, 'Non-Governmental Organizations at the World Trade Organization: Cooperation Competition, or Exclusion', 1 J Int'l Econ L 123 (1998) [hereinafter Esty, 'Cooperation'].
    • (1998) J Int'l Econ l , vol.1 , pp. 123
    • Esty, D.C.1
  • 25
    • 22844456465 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Toward Optimal Environmental Governance
    • hereinafter Esty, 'Optimal'
    • See Daniel C. Esty, 'Toward Optimal Environmental Governance', 74 NYU L Rev 1495 (1999) [hereinafter Esty, 'Optimal'].
    • (1999) NYU l Rev , vol.74 , pp. 1495
    • Esty, D.C.1
  • 26
    • 0000778367 scopus 로고
    • A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures
    • See Charles Tiebout, 'A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures', 64 J Pol Econ 416 (1956).
    • (1956) J Pol Econ , vol.64 , pp. 416
    • Tiebout, C.1
  • 29
    • 0038992258 scopus 로고
    • A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers: In Defense of United States v. Lopez
    • See Stephen G. Calabresi, 'A Government of Limited and Enumerated Powers: In Defense of United States v. Lopez', 94 Mich L Rev 752 (1995).
    • (1995) Mich l Rev , vol.94 , pp. 752
    • Calabresi, S.G.1
  • 30
    • 77958396817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control
    • See Matthew D. McCubbins, Roger G. Noll, and Barry R. Weingast, 'Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control', 3 J L Econ & Organization 243 (1987); Jerry L. Mashaw, Greed, Chaos, and Governance: Using Public Choice to Improve Public Law (1997).
    • (1987) J l Econ & Organization , vol.3 , pp. 243
    • McCubbins, M.D.1    Noll, R.G.2    Weingast, B.R.3
  • 32
    • 0346673033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Symposium: The Allocation of Government Authority: Environmental Federalism in a Global Economy
    • If faithfully applied, the regulatory competition model would suggest that global free trade agreements are also unnecessary, since localities should adopt optimal trade policies on their own. Yet in the WTO arena, regulatory competition advocates recognize market failures of the kind discussed below. For a discussion of this apparent contradiction, see Daniel Farber, 'Symposium: The Allocation of Government Authority: Environmental Federalism in a Global Economy', 83 Va L Rev 1283 (1997).
    • (1997) Va l Rev , vol.83 , pp. 1283
    • Farber, D.1
  • 34
    • 85037491950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 10
    • See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
    • Optimal
    • Esty1
  • 37
    • 0042881412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions
    • hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers'
    • See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions', 1992 U Chi Legal F 41 [hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers']; Wouter Wils, 'Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously', 6 J Env L 85 (1994).
    • U Chi Legal f , vol.1992 , pp. 41
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 38
    • 0028569297 scopus 로고
    • Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously
    • See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Law in the United States and the European Community: Spillovers, Cooperation, Rivalry, Institutions', 1992 U Chi Legal F 41 [hereinafter Stewart, 'Spillovers']; Wouter Wils, 'Subsidiarity and EC Environmental Policy: Taking People's Concerns Seriously', 6 J Env L 85 (1994).
    • (1994) J Env l , vol.6 , pp. 85
    • Wils, W.1
  • 39
    • 0042380469 scopus 로고
    • Environmental Protection, Economic Conflict and the European Community
    • See Owen Lomas, 'Environmental Protection, Economic Conflict and the European Community', 33 McGill LJ 506 (1988).
    • (1988) McGill LJ , vol.33 , pp. 506
    • Lomas, O.1
  • 40
    • 3142731193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 4
    • There is an ongoing debate, which we will not rehash here, about whether economic externalities are 'real' or merely pecuniary. Compare Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 with Daniel C. Esty, 'Revitalizing Environmental Federalism' 95 Mich L Rev 570 (1996) [hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing].
    • Rehabilitating
    • Revesz1
  • 41
    • 3142731193 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Revitalizing Environmental Federalism
    • hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing
    • There is an ongoing debate, which we will not rehash here, about whether economic externalities are 'real' or merely pecuniary. Compare Revesz, 'Rehabilitating', above n 4 with Daniel C. Esty, 'Revitalizing Environmental Federalism' 95 Mich L Rev 570 (1996) [hereinafter Esty, Revitalizing].
    • (1996) Mich l Rev , vol.95 , pp. 570
    • Esty, D.C.1
  • 44
    • 0010653735 scopus 로고
    • The State Competition Debate in Corporate Law
    • See Roberta Romano, 'The State Competition Debate in Corporate Law', 8 Cardozo L Rev 709 (1987).
    • (1987) Cardozo l Rev , vol.8 , pp. 709
    • Romano, R.1
  • 45
    • 85037491950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 10
    • See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
    • Optimal
    • Esty1
  • 47
    • 84928439790 scopus 로고
    • Competition among Jurisdictions in Formulating Corporate Rules: An American Perspective on the "Race to the Bottom" in the European Communities
    • See David Charny, 'Competition Among Jurisdictions in Formulating Corporate Rules: An American Perspective on the "Race to the Bottom" in the European Communities', 32 Harv Int'l LJ 423 (1991).
    • (1991) Harv Int'l LJ , vol.32 , pp. 423
    • Charny, D.1
  • 48
    • 0042380429 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federalism and Corporate Law
    • Ingolf Pernice (ed)
    • See Helmut Kohl, 'Federalism and Corporate Law' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 129; Friedrich Kübler, 'Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 171.
    • (1996) Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems , pp. 129
    • Kohl, H.1
  • 49
    • 25344432306 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective
    • Ingolf Pernice (ed)
    • See Helmut Kohl, 'Federalism and Corporate Law' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 129; Friedrich Kübler, 'Legislative Competition and Corporate Law Reform: Some Questions from a European Perspective' in Ingolf Pernice (ed), Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems (1996) 171.
    • (1996) Harmonization of Legislation in Federal Systems , pp. 171
    • Kübler, F.1
  • 50
    • 0004188201 scopus 로고
    • Industry sectors where large economies of scale can be achieved (e.g. electricity production and transmission) are generally considered to be 'natural monopolies'. See Alfred Kahn, The Economics of Regulation (1970). Similarly, areas where important regulatory economies of scale can be achieved may be considered to be 'natural legal monopolies'.
    • (1970) The Economics of Regulation
    • Kahn, A.1
  • 53
    • 0040810951 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Limited Role of Regulatory Harmonization in International Goods and Services Markets
    • See Alan O. Sykes, Product Standards for Internationally Integrated Goods and Markets (1995); Alan O. Sykes, 'The Limited Role of Regulatory Harmonization in International Goods and Services Markets', 2 J Int'l Econ L 49 (1999).
    • (1999) J Int'l Econ l , vol.2 , pp. 49
  • 54
    • 22044443889 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework
    • Esty and Geradin explain that 'harmonization' need not imply absolutely uniform standards. Alternative forms of harmonization or regulatory 'convergence' may permit some degree of standardization without the concomitant efficiency losses that single standards that do not match local needs generate. See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework', 32 J World Trade 5 (1998). Harmonization debates themselves often entail competition over whose standards should be adopted. And agreement on a common standard need not bring an end to regulatory competition. Many forms of harmonization are flexible and open enough to allow continued debate over and refinement of the standards selected. See also Piet Jan Slot, 'Harmonization', 21 Eur L Rev 378 (1996).
    • (1998) J World Trade , vol.32 , pp. 5
    • Esty, D.C.1    Geradin, D.2
  • 55
    • 0042881403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harmonization
    • Esty and Geradin explain that 'harmonization' need not imply absolutely uniform standards. Alternative forms of harmonization or regulatory 'convergence' may permit some degree of standardization without the concomitant efficiency losses that single standards that do not match local needs generate. See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Environmental Protection and International Competitiveness: A Conceptual Framework', 32 J World Trade 5 (1998). Harmonization debates themselves often entail competition over whose standards should be adopted. And agreement on a common standard need not bring an end to regulatory competition. Many forms of harmonization are flexible and open enough to allow continued debate over and refinement of the standards selected. See also Piet Jan Slot, 'Harmonization', 21 Eur L Rev 378 (1996).
    • (1996) Eur l Rev , vol.21 , pp. 378
    • Slot, P.J.1
  • 60
    • 0027047960 scopus 로고
    • Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade
    • See Steve Charnovitz, 'Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade', 15 World Economy 335 (1992); Brian Langille, 'Eight Ways to Think About International Labour Standards', 31 J World Trade 27 (1997).
    • (1992) World Economy , vol.15 , pp. 335
    • Charnovitz, S.1
  • 61
    • 0003135754 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Eight Ways to Think about International Labour Standards
    • See Steve Charnovitz, 'Environmental and Labor Standards in Trade', 15 World Economy 335 (1992); Brian Langille, 'Eight Ways to Think About International Labour Standards', 31 J World Trade 27 (1997).
    • (1997) J World Trade , vol.31 , pp. 27
    • Langille, B.1
  • 63
    • 0027073647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?
    • Patrick Low (ed)
    • See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
    • (1992) International Trade and the Environment , pp. 89
    • Low, P.1    Yeats, A.2
  • 64
    • 0027073647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?
    • See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
    • (1995) J Econ Literature , vol.33 , pp. 132
    • Jaffe, A.B.1
  • 65
    • 0027073647 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 5
    • See Patrick Low and Alexander Yeats, 'Do "Dirty" Industries Migrate?' Patrick Low (ed), International Trade and the Environment (1992) 89; Adam B. Jaffe et al., 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness of U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evidence Tell Us?', 33 J Econ Literature 132 (1995); Klevorick, 'Lessons', above n 5.
    • Lessons
    • Klevorick1
  • 66
    • 0002282460 scopus 로고
    • Let Them Eat Pollution
    • 22 February
    • See, for example, Lawrence Summers's (in)famous World Bank internal memorandum leaked to the press, explaining that it is economically efficient to encourage migration of dirty industries to less developed nations. See 'Let Them Eat Pollution', The Economist 66 (22 February 1992).
    • (1992) The Economist , vol.66
  • 67
    • 0030825666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows
    • See Cees van Beers and Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh, 'An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows', 50 Kyklos 29 (1997); Muthukumara Mani and David Wheeler, 'In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995' in Per G. Fredriksson (ed), Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment (1999) 115.
    • (1997) Kyklos , vol.50 , pp. 29
    • Van Beers, C.1    Van Den Bergh, J.C.J.M.2
  • 68
    • 0003902583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995
    • Per G. Fredriksson (ed)
    • See Cees van Beers and Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh, 'An Empirical Multi-Country Analysis of the Impact of Environmental Regulations on Foreign Trade Flows', 50 Kyklos 29 (1997); Muthukumara Mani and David Wheeler, 'In Search of Pollution Havens? Dirty Industry in the World Economy, 1960-1995' in Per G. Fredriksson (ed), Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment (1999) 115.
    • (1999) Trade, Global Policy, and the Environment , pp. 115
    • Mani, M.1    Wheeler, D.2
  • 69
    • 0346615644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market Access, Competitiveness, and Harmonization: Environmental Protection in Regional Trade Agreements
    • hereinafter Esty and Geradin, 'Market Access'
    • See Daniel C. Esty and Damien Geradin, 'Market Access, Competitiveness, and Harmonization: Environmental Protection in Regional Trade Agreements', 21 Harv Env L Rev 265 (1997) [hereinafter Esty and Geradin, 'Market Access'].
    • (1997) Harv Env l Rev , vol.21 , pp. 265
    • Esty, D.C.1    Geradin, D.2
  • 71
    • 85037491950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 10
    • See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
    • Optimal
    • Esty1
  • 74
    • 85037520403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • France Imposes Emergency Bans on Phtalates in Baby Toys
    • 16 July
    • See 'France Imposes Emergency Bans on Phtalates in Baby Toys', Environment Watch 9 (16 July 1999).
    • (1999) Environment Watch , vol.9
  • 76
    • 0005264157 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Collaborative Government in the Administrative State
    • See Jody Freeman, 'Collaborative Government in the Administrative State', 45 UCLA L Rev 1 (1997).
    • (1997) UCLA l Rev , vol.45 , pp. 1
    • Freeman, J.1
  • 78
    • 77953495821 scopus 로고
    • Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness
    • See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness', 102 Yale LJ 2039 (1993). See also, Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr. and Eric W. Orts, 'Environmental Contracts in the United States' (unpublished manuscript) (1999).
    • (1993) Yale LJ , vol.102 , pp. 2039
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 79
    • 0042380438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • unpublished manuscript
    • See Richard B. Stewart, 'Environmental Regulation and International Competitiveness', 102 Yale LJ 2039 (1993). See also, Geoffrey C. Hazard, Jr. and Eric W. Orts, 'Environmental Contracts in the United States' (unpublished manuscript) (1999).
    • (1999) Environmental Contracts in the United States
    • Hazard, G.C.1    Jr2    Orts, E.W.3
  • 81
    • 85037509953 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Regulatory Competition: Promoting Trade while Facilitating Consumer Protection
    • 5 December (on file with author)
    • See 'Regulatory Competition: Promoting Trade While Facilitating Consumer Protection', Joint Statement of US-EU Summit (5 December 1997) (on file with author).
    • (1997) Joint Statement of US-EU Summit
  • 82
    • 34548658887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy
    • Fordham Corporate Law Institute
    • See Douglas Melamed, 'Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy', 25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, Fordham Corporate Law Institute (1998); Alex Schaub, 'International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings', Competition Policy Newsletter 1, 3 (1998) (on file with author).
    • (1998) 25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy
    • Melamed, D.1
  • 83
    • 0002159256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings
    • on file with author
    • See Douglas Melamed, 'Antitrust Enforcement in a Global Economy', 25th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy, Fordham Corporate Law Institute (1998); Alex Schaub, 'International Co-operation in Antitrust Matters: Making the Point in the Wake of the Boeing/MDD Proceedings', Competition Policy Newsletter 1, 3 (1998) (on file with author).
    • (1998) Competition Policy Newsletter , vol.1-3
    • Schaub, A.1
  • 84
    • 0041879214 scopus 로고
    • TRIPS: Adequate Protection, Inadequate Trade, Adequate Competition Policy
    • See Hans Ullrich, 'TRIPS: Adequate Protection, Inadequate Trade, Adequate Competition Policy', 4 Pac Rim L & Policy J 153 (1995).
    • (1995) Pac Rim l & Policy J , vol.4 , pp. 153
    • Ullrich, H.1
  • 85
    • 21744441837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Telecommunications Services and the World Trade Organization
    • See Marco Bronckers and Pierre Larouche, 'Telecommunications Services and the World Trade Organization', 31 J World Trade 5 (1997).
    • (1997) J World Trade , vol.31 , pp. 5
    • Bronckers, M.1    Larouche, P.2
  • 86
    • 21344459958 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business
    • See Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann, 'International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business', 30 J World Trade 5 (1996); Aaditya Mattoo and Arvind Subramanian, 'Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward', 31 J World Trade 129 (1997).
    • (1996) J World Trade , vol.30 , pp. 5
    • Petersmann, E.-U.1
  • 87
    • 18744428409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward
    • See Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann, 'International Competition Rules for Governments and Private Business', 30 J World Trade 5 (1996); Aaditya Mattoo and Arvind Subramanian, 'Multilateral Rules on Competition Policy - A Possible Way Forward', 31 J World Trade 129 (1997).
    • (1997) J World Trade , vol.31 , pp. 129
    • Mattoo, A.1    Subramanian, A.2
  • 88
    • 0023520760 scopus 로고
    • The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview
    • See Steve Charnovitz, 'The Influence of International Labour Standards on the World Trading Regime: A Historical Overview', 126 Int'l Labor Rev 565 (1987).
    • (1987) Int'l Labor Rev , vol.126 , pp. 565
    • Charnovitz, S.1
  • 90
    • 0042380425 scopus 로고
    • Harmonizing Phyto-sanitary and Sanitary Regulations
    • See Maury E. Bredahl and Kenneth W. Forsythe, 'Harmonizing Phyto-sanitary and Sanitary Regulations', 12 World Econ 189 (1989).
    • (1989) World Econ , vol.12 , pp. 189
    • Bredahl, M.E.1    Forsythe, K.W.2
  • 93
    • 0002056667 scopus 로고
    • Environmental Policy from the Seventies to the Nineties: Continuity and Change
    • Norman J. Vig and Michael E. Kraft (eds)
    • See Michael E. Kraft and Norman J. Vig, 'Environmental Policy from the Seventies to the Nineties: Continuity and Change' in Norman J. Vig and Michael E. Kraft (eds), Environmental Policy in the 1990s (1990).
    • (1990) Environmental Policy in the 1990s
    • Kraft, M.E.1    Vig, N.J.2
  • 94
    • 0041879207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environment Ministers to Revise EMAS, Eco-Label Program to Boost Participation
    • See 'Environment Ministers to Revise EMAS, Eco-Label Program to Boost Participation', 22 Int'l Env Rptr 570 (1999).
    • (1999) Int'l Env Rptr , vol.22 , pp. 570
  • 97
    • 85037491950 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 10
    • See Esty, 'Optimal', above n 10.
    • Optimal
    • Esty1
  • 98
    • 54649084015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 48
    • See Albert Breton, Competitive Governments, above n 48; Michael Trebilock and Robert Howse, 'Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics', 6 Eur J L & Econ 5 (1998).
    • Competitive Governments
    • Breton, A.1
  • 99
    • 54649084015 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics
    • See Albert Breton, Competitive Governments, above n 48; Michael Trebilock and Robert Howse, 'Trade Liberalization and Regulatory Diversity Competitive Markets with Competitive Politics', 6 Eur J L & Econ 5 (1998).
    • (1998) Eur J l & Econ , vol.6 , pp. 5
    • Trebilock, M.1    Howse, R.2
  • 100
    • 84964701087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competition between National Legal Systems: A Contribution of Economic Analysis to Comparative Law
    • hereinafter Ogus, 'Competition'
    • As pointed out by Ogus, competition may also take place between different court systems with overlapping jurisdictions. For instance, the struggle between the Chancery Courts and their Common Law rivals had a significant impact on the development of legal principles in the United Kingdom. See Anthony Ogus, 'Competition Between National Legal Systems: A Contribution of Economic Analysis to Comparative Law', 48 Intl & Comp LQ 405 (1999) [hereinafter Ogus, 'Competition'].
    • (1999) Intl & Comp LQ , vol.48 , pp. 405
    • Ogus, A.1
  • 102
    • 84942233960 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • above n 71
    • To some extent, political parties competing for power can be compared to firms engaged in a competitive bidding for a monopolistic franchise power to provide a service, the competition serving to ensure that the firm offering the most efficient prices and services will be selected. See Ogus, 'Competition', above n 71.
    • Competition
    • Ogus1
  • 104
    • 0042380434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Thirty Firms Plan Pilot on Emissions Trading in Effort to Head off Proposed Energy Tax
    • See Peta Firth, 'Thirty Firms Plan Pilot on Emissions Trading in Effort to Head off Proposed Energy Tax', 22 Int'l Env Rptr 580 (1999).
    • (1999) Int'l Env Rptr , vol.22 , pp. 580
    • Firth, P.1
  • 105
    • 85037520550 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Environmental Agreements: A New Instrument of Environmental Policy
    • RSC 97/45 (on file with author)
    • See Eckard Rehbinder, 'Environmental Agreements: A New Instrument of Environmental Policy', Jean Monnet Chair Paper, RSC 97/45 (1997) (on file with author).
    • (1997) Jean Monnet Chair Paper
    • Rehbinder, E.1
  • 107
    • 85037502092 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Thanks to Professor Dan Farber for highlighting this concept.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.