메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 13, Issue 8, 2000, Pages 38-58

Flow-based transmission rights and congestion management

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

CONGESTIONS MANAGEMENTS; FLOW BASED; RIGHTS MANAGEMENT; TRANSMISSION CONGESTION; TRANSMISSION RIGHTS;

EID: 0034288029     PISSN: 10406190     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1016/S1040-6190(00)00146-9     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (143)

References (52)
  • 1
    • 85167856733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Regional Transmission Organizations, Final Order No. 2000, RM99-2-000, Washington, DC, Dec. 15
    • 1. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Regional Transmission Organizations, Final Order No. 2000, RM99-2-000, Washington, DC, Dec. 15, 1999.
    • (1999)
  • 2
    • 85167847159 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2. Centralized market organizations often emphasize short-run operational efficiency while maintaining system reliability and security, but neglect the demand-side participation essential for long-term economic benefits.
  • 3
    • 85167847395 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 3. A contract path from node i to node j refers to the transfer of a certain amount of power from node i to node j along a path that is specified administratively without considering the actual flow of power.
  • 4
    • 21344465796 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A market mechanism for electric power transmission
    • July
    • 4. Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, A Market Mechanism for Electric Power Transmission, J. REG. ECON., July 1996, at 25-59; Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, An Institutional Design for an Electricity Contract Market with Central Dispatch, ENERGY J., Jan. 1997, at 85-110; and Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, Reliability Management in Competitive Electricity Markets, J. REG. ECON., Sept. 1998, at 89-200.
    • (1996) J. Reg. Econ. , pp. 25-59
    • Chao, H.-P.1    Peck, S.C.2
  • 5
    • 0030649148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An institutional design for an electricity contract market with central dispatch
    • Jan.
    • 4. Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, A Market Mechanism for Electric Power Transmission, J. REG. ECON., July 1996, at 25-59; Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, An Institutional Design for an Electricity Contract Market with Central Dispatch, ENERGY J., Jan. 1997, at 85-110; and Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, Reliability Management in Competitive Electricity Markets, J. REG. ECON., Sept. 1998, at 89-200.
    • (1997) Energy J. , pp. 85-110
    • Chao, H.-P.1    Peck, S.C.2
  • 6
    • 0032364643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Reliability management in competitive electricity markets
    • Sept.
    • 4. Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, A Market Mechanism for Electric Power Transmission, J. REG. ECON., July 1996, at 25-59; Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, An Institutional Design for an Electricity Contract Market with Central Dispatch, ENERGY J., Jan. 1997, at 85-110; and Hung-po Chao and Stephen C. Peck, Reliability Management in Competitive Electricity Markets, J. REG. ECON., Sept. 1998, at 89-200.
    • (1998) J. Reg. Econ. , pp. 89-200
    • Chao, H.-P.1    Peck, S.C.2
  • 7
    • 85167850404 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 5. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 8
    • 85167845323 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A competitive mechanism for the distribution of electric power through a network and the determination of network capacity: Experimental tests and performance
    • San Francisco, Feb. 7
    • 6. Hung-po Chao and Charles R. Plott, A Competitive Mechanism for the Distribution of Electric Power Through a Network and the Determination of Network Capacity: Experimental Tests and Performance, working paper presented at California Public Utility Commission/ORA Seminar, San Francisco, Feb. 7, 2000.
    • (2000) California Public Utility Commission/ORA Seminar
    • Chao, H.-P.1    Plott, C.R.2
  • 11
    • 34249835223 scopus 로고
    • Contract networks for electric power transmission
    • Dec.
    • 8. William Hogan, Contract Networks for Electric Power Transmission, J. REG. ECON., Dec. 1992, at 211-42.
    • (1992) J. Reg. Econ. , pp. 211-242
    • Hogan, W.1
  • 12
    • 0030675936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic inefficiency of passive transmission rights in congested electricity systems with competitive generation
    • Jan.
    • 9. Shmuel Oren, Economic Inefficiency of Passive Transmission Rights in Congested Electricity Systems with Competitive Generation, ENERGY J., Jan. 1997, at 63-84.
    • (1997) Energy J. , pp. 63-84
    • Oren, S.1
  • 14
    • 85167844929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hogan, supra note 8
    • 11. Hogan, supra note 8.
  • 15
    • 0001924717 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Tabors, a market-based proposal for transmission pricing
    • Nov.
    • 12. Richard D. Tabors, A Market-Based Proposal for Transmission Pricing, ELEC. J., Nov. 1996, at 61-67.
    • (1996) Elec. J. , pp. 61-67
    • Richard, D.1
  • 16
    • 85167851290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 13. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 17
    • 85167854027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • private communication, Aug.
    • 14. Paul R. Gribik and Dariush Shirmohammadi (Perot Systems Corp.), and James Kritikson (California Power Exchange), private communication, Aug. 1999.
    • (1999)
    • Gribik, P.R.1    Shirmohammadi, D.2
  • 18
    • 85167847365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • prepared by NERC Transaction Reservation and Scheduling Self Directed Work Team, Nov.
    • 15. Energy transfers among the control areas of the interconnection are traditionally scheduled using the contract path method. The limitations of this method are well known. In the past, when the volume of transactions was relatively small and the transactions were mostly between adjacent control areas, parallel flows were tolerable. As a result of deregulation, however, the energy transfers increase in both volume and geographical span, with the result that parallel flows begin to exert serious operational and economic impacts. See NERC, Aligning Transmission Reservations and Energy Schedules to Actual Flows: Proposal to Mitigate Current Problems Associated with Transmission Reservation and Scheduling Practices In the Eastern Interconnection, prepared by NERC Transaction Reservation and Scheduling Self Directed Work Team, Nov. 1998.
    • (1998) Aligning Transmission Reservations and Energy Schedules to Actual Flows: Proposal to Mitigate Current Problems Associated with Transmission Reservation and Scheduling Practices In the Eastern Interconnection
  • 19
    • 85167855416 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 16. Scaled marginal losses are used to avoid the surplus that results from application of full marginal losses. That is, just as pricing transmission at the margin produces a surplus (congestion rent) that is paid to a transmission rights holder, losses charged or supplied at the marginal rate of loss would produce a surplus (marginal losses are approximately twice average/total losses). The "scaled marginal loss" approach provides an approximate locational price signal because the forward estimate of marginal rate of loss is scaled down equally at all locations to produce a loss factor that is intended to collect total system losses while maintaining a different loss factor at each location.
  • 20
    • 0003544592 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Harvard Electricity Policy Group working paper (Oct.)
    • 17. Michael B. Cadwalader, Scott M. Harvey, William W. Hogan, and Susan L. Pope, Coordinating Congestion Relief across Multiple Regions, Harvard Electricity Policy Group working paper (Oct. 1999); and Shmuel S. Oren and Andrew M. Ross, Economic Congestion Relief across Multiple Regions Requires Tradable Physical Flowgate Rights, working paper, Mar. 21, 2000.
    • (1999) Coordinating Congestion Relief Across Multiple Regions
    • Cadwalader, M.B.1    Harvey, S.M.2    Hogan, W.W.3    Pope, S.L.4
  • 22
    • 85167857738 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 18. In this article, prices are expressed in $/MWh, the power flows in MW, and the electricity outputs in MWh.
  • 23
    • 85167846041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 19. These fractions are known as the power transfer distribution factors. Roughly speaking, power flow is inversely proportional to the impedance along the path. Since the path along link 1 → 3 is half as long as the path 1 → 2 and 2 → 3, it has half the impedance. Therefore, the ratio of the power flows between them is 2 to 1.
  • 24
    • 85167845580 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1997), supra note 4
    • 20. Chao and Peck (1997), supra note 4.
  • 25
    • 85167855613 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 21. For instance, in California the Power Exchange's price is used to settle some grandfathered contracts, and affects payments for recovery of stranded costs. Requiring the incumbent utilities to trade through the PX also makes it easier to monitor market power. In Britain first, and in Alberta still, hedging contracts used to mitigate the incentives of incumbents with substantial market power are based on the exchange price.
  • 26
    • 85167855567 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 22. To hedge against the volatility of the spot price, buyers and sellers of electricity may enter into bilateral hedging contracts at a mutually agreed price. These contracts are financial instruments outside of the system operator's purview and do not affect the real-time dispatch by the system operator. Two common types of hedge contracts are the swap contract (two-way hedge) and option contract (one-way hedge).
  • 27
    • 85167854164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • mimeo, Electric Power Research Institute, Palo Alto, CA, and Stanford University, Stanford, CA
    • 23. In California, the adjustment bids may be obtained from the traders in the forward markets for congestion management, while the reserves price schedules may be obtained through separate forward auctions, as described in Hung-po Chao and Robert Wilson, Multi-Dimensional Procurement Auctions for Power Reserves: Incentive-Compatible Evaluation and Settlement Rules, mimeo, Electric Power Research Institute, Palo Alto, CA, and Stanford University, Stanford, CA, 2000.
    • (2000) Multi-Dimensional Procurement Auctions for Power Reserves: Incentive-Compatible Evaluation and Settlement Rules
    • Chao, H.-P.1    Wilson, R.2
  • 28
    • 0030654792 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Implementation of priority insurance in power exchange markets
    • Chao and Peck (1997), supra note 4, Jan.
    • 24. Chao and Peck (1997), supra note 4, and Robert Wilson, Implementation of Priority Insurance in Power Exchange Markets, ENERGY J., Jan. 1997, at 111-23.
    • (1997) Energy J. , pp. 111-123
    • Wilson, R.1
  • 29
    • 85167851822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 25. In an optimally dispatched system the spot value of the two types of rights are mathematically linked via the matrix of PTDF that specifies the fractions of power injected at any particular bus and taken out at a reference bus that flows through each flow gate. Specifically, the value of a point-to-point right from any given bus to the reference bus is the sum of the values of the congested flowgate rights multiplied by the corresponding PTDF. The value of a point-to-point right between any two arbitrary buses is given by the difference of the point-to-point right from the corresponding buses to the reference bus.
  • 30
    • 85167855656 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gribik, Angelidis, and Kovacs, supra note 7
    • 26. Gribik, Angelidis, and Kovacs, supra note 7.
  • 31
    • 85167855747 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 27. An example is the Federal Communications Commission's auction for selling spectrum licenses.
  • 32
    • 85167852470 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Plott (2000), supra note 6
    • 28. Chao and Plott (2000), supra note 6.
  • 33
    • 85167849044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 29. However, if the counterflow is scheduled but not delivered, the seller could be subject to a severe penalty because of the impact on reliability.
  • 34
    • 85167849938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 30. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 36
    • 85167857407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 32. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 37
    • 85167854853 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 33. In NordPool, there is no difference between the energy bids and the adjustment bids. In California, however, the traders can submit adjustment bids different from the energy bids. See Chao and Wilson (1999), supra note 23, for a description of how a reserve auction could provide a supply curve for adjustments.
  • 38
    • 85167854194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 34. These nodal prices can be easily calculated from the hub price and the flowgate prices using the distribution factors; however, given only the nodal prices, there isn't a unique set of flowgate prices.
  • 39
    • 85167857590 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 35. The allocation of financial risks does not affect market efficiency, but should have a direct effect on the results of the initial transmission rights auction.
  • 40
    • 0032065668 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congestion pricing with fewer prices than zones
    • May
    • 36. Steven Stoft, Congestion Pricing with Fewer Prices than Zones, ELEC. J., May 1998, at 23-31.
    • (1998) ELEC. J. , pp. 23-31
    • Stoft, S.1
  • 41
    • 85167846454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hogan, supra note 11
    • 37. Hogan, supra note 11.
  • 42
    • 85167856952 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 38. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 43
    • 0002297197 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The power market: E-commerce for all electricity products
    • Feb. 1
    • 39. Edward G. Cazalet and Ralph D. Samuelson, The Power Market: E-Commerce for All Electricity Products, PUB. UTIL. FORTNIGHTLY, Feb. 1, 2000.
    • (2000) Pub. Util. Fortnightly
    • Cazalet, E.G.1    Samuelson, R.D.2
  • 45
    • 85167857294 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gribik, Kritikson, and Shirmohammadi, supra note 14
    • 40. Paul R. Gribik, Enhancing the Power Exchange's Day-Ahead Markets: Binding Results at 7:00 AM Prior to ISO Congestion Management, Trading of Transmission Rights, Developing Physically Feasible Schedules, Block Trading, mimeo, California Power Exchange and Perot Systems Corporation, June 1999; and Gribik, Kritikson, and Shirmohammadi, supra note 14.
  • 46
    • 85167853124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 41. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4
    • 41. Chao and Peck (1996), supra note 4.
  • 47
    • 85167855982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gribik, Kritikson, and Shirmohammadi, supra note 14
    • 42. Gribik, Kritikson, and Shirmohammadi, supra note 14.
  • 48
    • 85167853698 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gribik, supra note 40
    • 43. Gribik, supra note 40.
  • 49
    • 85167851648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, supra note 1
    • 44. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, supra note 1.
  • 50
    • 85167855255 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Capacity Reservation Open Access Transmission Tariffs, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, RM96-11-000, Washington, DC, Apr. 24
    • 45. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Capacity Reservation Open Access Transmission Tariffs, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, RM96-11-000, Washington, DC, Apr. 24, 1996.
    • (1996)
  • 52
    • 0002381690 scopus 로고
    • Responsive pricing of public utilities
    • Jan.
    • 47. William Vickrey Responsive Pricing of Public Utilities, 2 BELL J. ECON. & MGMT. SCI., Jan. 1971, at 1,337-46.
    • (1971) 2 Bell J. Econ. & Mgmt. Sci. , pp. 1337-1346
    • Vickrey, W.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.