-
1
-
-
33847561532
-
-
Economic Bachvardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962), pp. 12-20; Tony Smith, "The underdevelopment of development literature: the case of dependency theory," World Politics, Vol. 31, No. 2 (January 1979), pp. 251-59; and Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990).
-
See Alexander Gerschenkron, Economic Bachvardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962), pp. 12-20; Tony Smith, "The underdevelopment of development literature: the case of dependency theory," World Politics, Vol. 31, No. 2 (January 1979), pp. 251-59; and Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990).
-
Gerschenkron
-
-
Alexander, S.1
-
2
-
-
33847535467
-
-
1992, pp. 387-392, and Highway and Byivays: Studies on Reform and Poslcommunht Transition (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995), p. 99; and Steven L. Solnick, "The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: a neoinstitutional perspective," World Politics, Vol. 48, No. 2 (January 1996), pp. 209-238.
-
Jdnos Komai, The Socialist System (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992), pp. 387-392, and Highway and Byivays: Studies on Reform and Poslcommunht Transition (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1995), p. 99; and Steven L. Solnick, "The breakdown of hierarchies in the Soviet Union and China: a neoinstitutional perspective," World Politics, Vol. 48, No. 2 (January 1996), pp. 209-238.
-
The Socialist System Princeton: Princeton University Press
-
-
Komai, J.1
-
3
-
-
33847534569
-
-
"Coalitions, institutions, and linkage sequencing - toward a Strategic capacity model of East Asian development," in Frederic C. Deyo (ed.). The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1987), pp. 227-247; T.J. Pempel, "Of dragons and development," Journal of Public Policy, Vol. 12, No. 1 (January-March 1992), pp. 79-95; and Anis Chowdhury and lyanatul Islam, The Newly Industrialising Economies of East Asia (London: Routledge, 1993), chs. 3, 5-8.
-
See Frederic C. Deyo, "Coalitions, institutions, and linkage sequencing - toward a Strategic capacity model of East Asian development," in Frederic C. Deyo (ed.). The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1987), pp. 227-247; T.J. Pempel, "Of dragons and development," Journal of Public Policy, Vol. 12, No. 1 (January-March 1992), pp. 79-95; and Anis Chowdhury and lyanatul Islam, The Newly Industrialising Economies of East Asia (London: Routledge, 1993), chs. 3, 5-8.
-
C. Deyo
-
-
Frederic, S.1
-
4
-
-
33847531446
-
-
see David S. G. Goodman, 'The People's Republic of China: the party-state, capitalist revolution and new entrepreneurs," in Richard Robison and David S. G. Goodman (eds.). The New Rich in Asia: Mobile Phones, AfcDonalds and Middle-Class Revolution (London: Routledge, 1996), pp. 225-242. For an assessment of China's business elites as possessing a considerable degree of structural autonomy from government, see Margaret M. Pearson, China 's New Business Elite: The Political Consequences of Economic Reform (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997).
-
For the business elites in China as a growing social group but still subject to the party-state, see David S. G. Goodman, 'The People's Republic of China: the party-state, capitalist revolution and new entrepreneurs," in Richard Robison and David S. G. Goodman (eds.). The New Rich in Asia: Mobile Phones, AfcDonalds and Middle-Class Revolution (London: Routledge, 1996), pp. 225-242. For an assessment of China's business elites as possessing a considerable degree of structural autonomy from government, see Margaret M. Pearson, China 's New Business Elite: The Political Consequences of Economic Reform (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997).
-
Business Elites in China As A Growing Social Group but Still Subject to the Party-state
-
-
The, F.1
-
5
-
-
33847562169
-
-
Public Entrepreneurs: Agents for Change in American Government (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995); and Andrew G. Walder, "Local governments as industrial firms: an organizational analysis of China's transitional economy "American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 101, No. 2 (September 1995), pp. 263-301.
-
See Mark Schneider and Paul Teske, Public Entrepreneurs: Agents for Change in American Government (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995); and Andrew G. Walder, "Local governments as industrial firms: an organizational analysis of China's transitional economy "American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 101, No. 2 (September 1995), pp. 263-301.
-
Schneider and Paul Teske
-
-
Mark, S.1
-
6
-
-
33847546893
-
-
see David S. G. Goodman and Gerald Segal (eds.), China Deconstructs: Politics, Trade and Regionalism (London: Routledge, 1994); David S. G. Goodman (ed.), China 's Provinces in Reform: Class, Community and Political Culture (London: Routledge, 1997); and Peter Cheung, Jae Ho Chung and Zhimin Lin (eds.). Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform in Post-Mao China: Leadership, Politics, and Implementation (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1998).
-
For studies dealing with development at the provincial level of analysis, see David S. G. Goodman and Gerald Segal (eds.), China Deconstructs: Politics, Trade and Regionalism (London: Routledge, 1994); David S. G. Goodman (ed.), China 's Provinces in Reform: Class, Community and Political Culture (London: Routledge, 1997); and Peter Cheung, Jae Ho Chung and Zhimin Lin (eds.). Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform in Post-Mao China: Leadership, Politics, and Implementation (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1998).
-
Dealing with Development at the Provincial Level of Analysis
-
-
Studies, F.1
-
8
-
-
33847541754
-
-
by replacing prefectures (digit) which, as "field offices" (paichu jigou) of the provinces, had an ambiguous administrative status. Prefecture-level cities were formed via three ways: through the merger of a province-administered prefecture-level city (shengxia dijishî) with the prefcctural administration (diqu xingzlieng gongshu); through the upgrading of a county-level city (xianjislti); and through the upgrading of a county-turned-city (xiangaishî). See Diao Tianding, Zliongguo difang jigou gaiyao (Overview of Local Government Organizations in China) (Beijing: Falii chubanshe, 1989), pp. 169,204-208; and Liu Junde, Zliongguo xingzlieng quhua de lilunyu shijian (Theory and Practice of Administrative Zoning in China) (Shanghai: East China Normal University Press, 1996), pp. 160-69.
-
The significance of this policy resides in that the rise of prefecture-level cities (dijishi) empowered to rule counties officially heralded the formation of a new layer of authority between provinces and counties, by replacing prefectures (digit) which, as "field offices" (paichu jigou) of the provinces, had an ambiguous administrative status. Prefecture-level cities were formed via three ways: through the merger of a province-administered prefecture-level city (shengxia dijishî) with the prefcctural administration (diqu xingzlieng gongshu); through the upgrading of a county-level city (xianjislti); and through the upgrading of a county-turned-city (xiangaishî). See Diao Tianding, Zliongguo difang jigou gaiyao (Overview of Local Government Organizations in China) (Beijing: Falii chubanshe, 1989), pp. 169,204-208; and Liu Junde, Zliongguo xingzlieng quhua de lilunyu shijian (Theory and Practice of Administrative Zoning in China) (Shanghai: East China Normal University Press, 1996), pp. 160-69.
-
Of This Policy Resides in That the Rise of Prefecture-level Cities (Dijishi) Empowered to Rule Counties Officially Heralded the Formation of A New Layer of Authority between Provinces and Counties
-
-
Significance, T.1
-
9
-
-
33847537560
-
-
Dangdai Zliongguo zliengfu gailun (Overview of Contemporary China's Government) (Beijing: Gaige chubanshe, 1993), pp. 25, 182-83; Liu Junde, Theory and Practice, p. 176; Zheng Dingquan, "1995 nian woguo difang xingzheng quhua gaikuang" ("An overview of China's local administrative structure in 1995"), inJingji yanjiu cankao (Reference Materials for Economic Research), No. 994 (22 December 1996), p. 38; and Zliongguo tongji nianjian 1997 (Statistical Yearbook of China 1997) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 1997), p. 3.
-
Figures are from Wu Peilun, Dangdai Zliongguo zliengfu gailun (Overview of Contemporary China's Government) (Beijing: Gaige chubanshe, 1993), pp. 25, 182-83; Liu Junde, Theory and Practice, p. 176; Zheng Dingquan, "1995 nian woguo difang xingzheng quhua gaikuang" ("An overview of China's local administrative structure in 1995"), inJingji yanjiu cankao (Reference Materials for Economic Research), No. 994 (22 December 1996), p. 38; and Zliongguo tongji nianjian 1997 (Statistical Yearbook of China 1997) (Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe, 1997), p. 3.
-
From Wu Peilun
-
-
Are, F.1
-
11
-
-
33847547106
-
-
"The expanding space of provincial politics and development: thematic suggestions for the future research agenda," Provincial China, No. 4 (October 1997), pp. 8-16.
-
See Jae Ho Chung, "The expanding space of provincial politics and development: thematic suggestions for the future research agenda," Provincial China, No. 4 (October 1997), pp. 8-16.
-
Ho Chung
-
-
Jae, S.1
-
12
-
-
33847545094
-
-
"Woguo chengshi jingji yanjiu chutan" ("A preliminary investigation of China's urban economy"), Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems), No. 5 ( 1989), pp. 2-9; David Zweig, "Internationalizing China's countryside: the political economy of exports from rural industry," The China Quarterly, No. 128 (December 1992), pp. 716-741, and " 'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances," Comparative Politics, Vol. 27, No. 3 (April 1995), pp. 253-274.
-
See Yao Shimou, "Woguo chengshi jingji yanjiu chutan" ("A preliminary investigation of China's urban economy"), Chengshi wenti (Urban Problems), No. 5 ( 1989), pp. 2-9; David Zweig, "Internationalizing China's countryside: the political economy of exports from rural industry," The China Quarterly, No. 128 (December 1992), pp. 716-741, and " 'Developmental communities" on China's coast: the impact of trade, investment, and transnational alliances," Comparative Politics, Vol. 27, No. 3 (April 1995), pp. 253-274.
-
Shimou
-
-
Yao, S.1
-
14
-
-
33847546215
-
-
see Barry Naughton, "Cities in the Chinese economic system: changing roles and conditions for autonomy," in Deborah S. Davis, Richard Kraus, Barry Naughton and Elizabeth J. Perry (eds.). Urban Spaces in Contemporary China: The Potential for Autonomy and Community in Post-Mao China (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995), pp. 61-89; and Kam Wing Chan, "Urbanization and urban infrastructure services in the PRC," in Christine P. W. Wong (ed.). Financing Local Government in the People 's Republic of China (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1997), pp. 83-125.
-
For overviews of the issue, see Barry Naughton, "Cities in the Chinese economic system: changing roles and conditions for autonomy," in Deborah S. Davis, Richard Kraus, Barry Naughton and Elizabeth J. Perry (eds.). Urban Spaces in Contemporary China: The Potential for Autonomy and Community in Post-Mao China (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995), pp. 61-89; and Kam Wing Chan, "Urbanization and urban infrastructure services in the PRC," in Christine P. W. Wong (ed.). Financing Local Government in the People 's Republic of China (Hong Kong: Oxford University Press, 1997), pp. 83-125.
-
Of the Issue
-
-
Overviews, F.1
-
15
-
-
33847571988
-
-
Joseph Fewsmith, "Special Economic Zones in the PRC," Problems of Communism, Vol. 35, No. 6 (1986), pp. 78-85; George T. Crane, The Political Economy of China's Special Economic Zones (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1990); and Jude Howell, China Opens Its Doors: The Politics of Economic Transition (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1993), ch. 4.
-
See, for instance, Joseph Fewsmith, "Special Economic Zones in the PRC," Problems of Communism, Vol. 35, No. 6 (1986), pp. 78-85; George T. Crane, The Political Economy of China's Special Economic Zones (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1990); and Jude Howell, China Opens Its Doors: The Politics of Economic Transition (Boulder: Lynne Rienner, 1993), ch. 4.
-
Instance
-
-
See, F.1
-
16
-
-
33847559387
-
-
"Territorial actors as competitors for power: the case of Hubei and Wuhan," in Kenneth G. Lieberthal and David M. Lampton (eds.), Bureaucracy, Politics and Decision Making in Post-Mao China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992), pp. 283-307; Dorothy J. Solinger, "City, province and region: the case of Wuhan," in Bruce L. Reynolds (ed.), Chinese Economic Policy (New York: Paragon, 1988), pp. 233-284, "China's new economic policies and the local industrial political process: the case of Wuhan," Comparative Politics, Vol. 18, No. 4 (July 1986), pp. 379-399, and "Despite decentralization: Wuhan's disadvantages and dependence, and ongoing central power in the Inland," The China Quarterly, No. 145 (March 1996), pp. 1-34.
-
Examples include Paul E. Schroeder, "Territorial actors as competitors for power: the case of Hubei and Wuhan," in Kenneth G. Lieberthal and David M. Lampton (eds.), Bureaucracy, Politics and Decision Making in Post-Mao China (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992), pp. 283-307; Dorothy J. Solinger, "City, province and region: the case of Wuhan," in Bruce L. Reynolds (ed.), Chinese Economic Policy (New York: Paragon, 1988), pp. 233-284, "China's new economic policies and the local industrial political process: the case of Wuhan," Comparative Politics, Vol. 18, No. 4 (July 1986), pp. 379-399, and "Despite decentralization: Wuhan's disadvantages and dependence, and ongoing central power in the Inland," The China Quarterly, No. 145 (March 1996), pp. 1-34.
-
Paul E. Schroeder
-
-
Include, E.1
-
17
-
-
0030461367
-
-
"Autonomy and growth in China: county experience in Guangdong province," Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 5 (1996), pp. 7-22; Marc Blecherand Vivienne Shue, Tethered Deer: Government and Economy in a Chinese County (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1996) and Andrew G. Walder (ed.), Zouping in Transition: The Process of Reform in Rural North China (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998).
-
See John Fitzgerald, "Autonomy and growth in China: county experience in Guangdong province," Journal of Contemporary China, Vol. 5 (1996), pp. 7-22; Marc Blecherand Vivienne Shue, Tethered Deer: Government and Economy in a Chinese County (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1996) and Andrew G. Walder (ed.), Zouping in Transition: The Process of Reform in Rural North China (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1998).
-
Fitzgerald
-
-
John, S.1
-
18
-
-
33847539240
-
-
Qingdao, occasional references will be made to several other cities whenever comparison is possible and necessary.
-
While this study has one major case study, Qingdao, occasional references will be made to several other cities whenever comparison is possible and necessary.
-
Study Has One Major Case Study
-
-
This, W.1
-
19
-
-
33847535681
-
-
Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1990), pp. 23-t8.
-
See Stephen Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1990), pp. 23-t8.
-
Haggard
-
-
Stephen, S.1
-
20
-
-
33847554829
-
-
see eight case studies in Cheung, Chung and Lin, Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform.
-
For provincial variations, see eight case studies in Cheung, Chung and Lin, Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform.
-
Variations
-
-
Provincial, F.1
-
21
-
-
33847566132
-
-
see Jae Ho Chung (ed.), Cities in China: Recipes for Economic Development in the Reform Era (London: Routledge, 1999).
-
For a comparative study of 14 cities (of which 12 are coastal ones), see Jae Ho Chung (ed.), Cities in China: Recipes for Economic Development in the Reform Era (London: Routledge, 1999).
-
Comparative Study of 14 Cities (Of Which 12 Are Coastal Ones)
-
-
-
22
-
-
33847568094
-
-
see "Cujin diqu jingji xietiao fazhan yanjiu" ("Study on the promotion of regionally co-ordinated development"), Jingjiyanjiu cankao. No. 914/915 (25 July 1996) and Woo Tun-oy, "Regional economic development and disparities," in Maurice Brosseau, Suzanne Pepper and Tsang Shu-ki (eds.). The China Review 1996 (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1996), pp. 281-313.
-
The importance of these factors needs no further elaboration. For exemplary studies on this issue, see "Cujin diqu jingji xietiao fazhan yanjiu" ("Study on the promotion of regionally co-ordinated development"), Jingjiyanjiu cankao. No. 914/915 (25 July 1996) and Woo Tun-oy, "Regional economic development and disparities," in Maurice Brosseau, Suzanne Pepper and Tsang Shu-ki (eds.). The China Review 1996 (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1996), pp. 281-313.
-
Of These Factors Needs No Further Elaboration. for Exemplary Studies on This Issue
-
-
Importance, T.1
-
23
-
-
84976926662
-
-
see David Stark, "Path dependence and privatization strategies in East Central Europe," East European Politics and Society, Vol. 6, No. 1 (1991), pp. 17-54. And for the inverse relationship between the past priority for state enterprises and heavy industrial development and the pace of growth, see Margot Schueller, "Liaoning: struggling with the burdens of the past," in Goodman, China's Provinces in Reform, pp. 93-121.
-
For the economic legacy of path dependence, see David Stark, "Path dependence and privatization strategies in East Central Europe," East European Politics and Society, Vol. 6, No. 1 (1991), pp. 17-54. And for the inverse relationship between the past priority for state enterprises and heavy industrial development and the pace of growth, see Margot Schueller, "Liaoning: struggling with the burdens of the past," in Goodman, China's Provinces in Reform, pp. 93-121.
-
Economic Legacy of Path Dependence
-
-
The, F.1
-
24
-
-
33847535466
-
-
see Jon Woronoff, Asia's "Miracle" Economies (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1992), 2nd ed., pp. 128,279,295-96,312. For the case of Shanghai, see Wong Siu-lun, "The entrepreneurial spirit: Shanghai and Hong Kong compared," in Y. M. Yeung and Sung Yun-wing (eds.), Shanghai: Transformation and Modernization under China 's Open Policy (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1996), pp. 26-48. For Wenzhou's entrepreneurial culture, see Li Haoran, Wenzlwu xin yueqian (Wenzliou's New Leap) (Shanghai: Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences Press, 1996), pp. 2-4; and Yia-Ling Liu, "Reform from below: the private economy and local politics in the rural industrialization of Wenzhou," The China Quarterly, No. 130 (June 1992), pp. 292,299, 307-313.
-
For cultural arguments on the East Asian NIEs, see Jon Woronoff, Asia's "Miracle" Economies (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1992), 2nd ed., pp. 128,279,295-96,312. For the case of Shanghai, see Wong Siu-lun, "The entrepreneurial spirit: Shanghai and Hong Kong compared," in Y. M. Yeung and Sung Yun-wing (eds.), Shanghai: Transformation and Modernization under China 's Open Policy (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1996), pp. 26-48. For Wenzhou's entrepreneurial culture, see Li Haoran, Wenzlwu xin yueqian (Wenzliou's New Leap) (Shanghai: Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences Press, 1996), pp. 2-4; and Yia-Ling Liu, "Reform from below: the private economy and local politics in the rural industrialization of Wenzhou," The China Quarterly, No. 130 (June 1992), pp. 292,299, 307-313.
-
Arguments on the East Asian NIEs
-
-
Cultural, F.1
-
26
-
-
33847565223
-
-
see Sang Baichuan, Quyu kaifang zhanlüe Inn: qlngxle zJiengce yu quanfangwei kaifang (On the Strategy of Regional Opening - Discriminating Policies and All-Directional Opening) (Beijing: Zhongguo qingnian chubanshe, 1996). The disadvantages of lacking these privileges in inland cities are well illustrated in Solinger, "Despite decentralization," pp. 16-32. For the disparities between coastal and inland cities in Shandong due to discriminant preferential policies, see Jae Ho Chung, 'The political economy of development and inequality in Shandong," in Goodman, China's Provinces in Reform, pp. 127-157.
-
For an excellent Chinese account of this policy factor, see Sang Baichuan, Quyu kaifang zhanlüe Inn: qlngxle zJiengce yu quanfangwei kaifang (On the Strategy of Regional Opening - Discriminating Policies and All-Directional Opening) (Beijing: Zhongguo qingnian chubanshe, 1996). The disadvantages of lacking these privileges in inland cities are well illustrated in Solinger, "Despite decentralization," pp. 16-32. For the disparities between coastal and inland cities in Shandong due to discriminant preferential policies, see Jae Ho Chung, 'The political economy of development and inequality in Shandong," in Goodman, China's Provinces in Reform, pp. 127-157.
-
Excellent Chinese Account of This Policy Factor
-
-
An, F.1
-
28
-
-
33847567904
-
-
see China Daily, 15 January 1997; Cheng Li, Rediscovering China: Dynamics and Dilemmas ofRefortn (Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield, 1997), pp. 153-164; and David Zweig, "Institutional constraints, path dependence, and entrepreneurship: comparing Nantong and Zhangjiagang, 1984-1996," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 7. And for Wenzhou, see Keith Forster and Yao Xianguo, "A comparative analysis of economic reform and development in Hangzhou and Wenzhou cities," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 3.
-
For Zhangjiagang's success, see China Daily, 15 January 1997; Cheng Li, Rediscovering China: Dynamics and Dilemmas ofRefortn (Lanham: Rowman and Littlefield, 1997), pp. 153-164; and David Zweig, "Institutional constraints, path dependence, and entrepreneurship: comparing Nantong and Zhangjiagang, 1984-1996," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 7. And for Wenzhou, see Keith Forster and Yao Xianguo, "A comparative analysis of economic reform and development in Hangzhou and Wenzhou cities," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 3.
-
Success
-
-
Zhangjiagang'S, F.1
-
29
-
-
33847541309
-
-
Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform; and Peter T. Y. Cheung, "The political context of Shanghai's economic development," in Yeung and Sung, Shanghai, pp. 66-75.
-
See Cheung, Chung and Lin, Provincial Strategies of Economic Reform; and Peter T. Y. Cheung, "The political context of Shanghai's economic development," in Yeung and Sung, Shanghai, pp. 66-75.
-
Chung and Lin
-
-
Cheung, S.1
-
30
-
-
33847531878
-
-
see Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 283-307; and for Chongqing's such efforts, see Hong, "A tale of two cities: a comparative study of the political and economic development in Chengdu and Chongqing," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 6.
-
For Wuhan's lobbying efforts, see Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 283-307; and for Chongqing's such efforts, see Hong, "A tale of two cities: a comparative study of the political and economic development in Chengdu and Chongqing," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 6.
-
Lobbying Efforts
-
-
Wuhan'S, F.1
-
31
-
-
33847563064
-
-
ch. 10; and Christopher Ellison and Gary Gereffi, "Explaining strategies and patterns of industrial development," in Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman (eds.), Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990), pp. 391-94.
-
See Wade, Governing the Market, ch. 10; and Christopher Ellison and Gary Gereffi, "Explaining strategies and patterns of industrial development," in Gary Gereffi and Donald L. Wyman (eds.), Manufacturing Miracles: Paths of Industrialization in Latin America and East Asia (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990), pp. 391-94.
-
Governing the Market
-
-
Wade, S.1
-
32
-
-
33847550252
-
-
see Howell, China Opens Its Doors, ch. 4. And for the adverse impact of ideological issues on Ningbo's development, see Ge Hongsheng, You Zliongguo tesedeyanhai chengshifazhan zhi lu (The Road to Coastal City Development with Chinese Characteristics) (Beijing: Renmin chubanshe, 1997), pp. 230-240.
-
For the ideological constraints on local leaders in Xiamen in the earlier years of reform, see Howell, China Opens Its Doors, ch. 4. And for the adverse impact of ideological issues on Ningbo's development, see Ge Hongsheng, You Zliongguo tesedeyanhai chengshifazhan zhi lu (The Road to Coastal City Development with Chinese Characteristics) (Beijing: Renmin chubanshe, 1997), pp. 230-240.
-
Ideological Constraints on Local Leaders in Xiamen in the Earlier Years of Reform
-
-
The, F.1
-
33
-
-
33847547820
-
-
coastal Fujian and Shandong - is known for its heavy dependence on foreign trade and investment. In contrast, the "southern Jiangsu model" (Siinan moshi) and "Wenzhou model" (Wenzliou nioshi) have depended less on foreign economic linkages, although their dependence seems to have increased in the 1990s. For the three models, see Zhou Erjin and Zhang Yulin, Cheng-xiang xietiaofazlian yanjiu (Study of Co-ordinated Development bet\veen Cities and Townships) (Nanjing: Jiangsu rcnmin chubanshe, 1991), chs. 1-3.
-
Considerable variations exist regarding the importance of foreign economic relations in local economic development. The so-called "Pearl [Zhu] River model" (Zhtijiang moshi) -applicable to southern Guangdong, coastal Fujian and Shandong - is known for its heavy dependence on foreign trade and investment. In contrast, the "southern Jiangsu model" (Siinan moshi) and "Wenzhou model" (Wenzliou nioshi) have depended less on foreign economic linkages, although their dependence seems to have increased in the 1990s. For the three models, see Zhou Erjin and Zhang Yulin, Cheng-xiang xietiaofazlian yanjiu (Study of Co-ordinated Development bet\veen Cities and Townships) (Nanjing: Jiangsu rcnmin chubanshe, 1991), chs. 1-3.
-
Exist Regarding the Importance of Foreign Economic Relations in Local Economic Development. the So-called "Pearl [Zhu] River Model" (Zhtijiang Moshi) -Applicable to Southern Guangdong
-
-
Variations, C.1
-
34
-
-
33847540536
-
-
see Chowdhury and Islam, The Newly Industrialising Economies of East Asia, ch. 7; chapters by Womack and Zhao, Yahuda, Ferdinand and d'Hooghe in Goodman and Segal, China Deconstructs; and Zweig, "Developmental communities on China's coast," pp. 253-274.
-
For the importance of international linkages, see Chowdhury and Islam, The Newly Industrialising Economies of East Asia, ch. 7; chapters by Womack and Zhao, Yahuda, Ferdinand and d'Hooghe in Goodman and Segal, China Deconstructs; and Zweig, "Developmental communities on China's coast," pp. 253-274.
-
Importance of International Linkages
-
-
The, F.1
-
35
-
-
33847546446
-
-
Restniciuring Net\mrks in Post-Socialism: Legacies, Linkages and Localities (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997).
-
See Gernot Grabher and David Stark (eds.), Restniciuring Net\mrks in Post-Socialism: Legacies, Linkages and Localities (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997).
-
Grabher and David Stark (Eds.)
-
-
Gernot, S.1
-
36
-
-
33847561754
-
-
30 May 1993; and Dexter Roberts, "From Mao central to capitalist hotbed," Business Week, 9 October 1995, pp. 60-61.
-
Qingdao's rapid growth was noted in Hong Kong as well as Western media. See "Heady times for Qingdao," China Business Review Special in South China Morning Post, 30 May 1993; and Dexter Roberts, "From Mao central to capitalist hotbed," Business Week, 9 October 1995, pp. 60-61.
-
Growth Was Noted in Hong Kong As Well As Western Media. See "Heady Times for Qingdao," China Business Review Special in South China Morning Post
-
-
Rapid, Q.1
-
37
-
-
33847561531
-
-
see Jae Ho Chung, "Preferential policies, municipal leadership, and development strategies: a comparative analysis of Qingdao and Dalian," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 4.
-
For a one-to-one comparison between two "coastal open cities" with deputy-provincial status, see Jae Ho Chung, "Preferential policies, municipal leadership, and development strategies: a comparative analysis of Qingdao and Dalian," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 4.
-
One-to-one Comparison between Two "Coastal Open Cities" with Deputy-provincial Status
-
-
-
38
-
-
33847535680
-
-
Qingdao was already one of the six centrally administered municipalities in China, along with Beijing, Nanjing, Shanghai, Tianjin and Xi'an. See Wu Peilun, Overview of Contemporary China's Government, p. 181.
-
As early as 1928, Qingdao was already one of the six centrally administered municipalities in China, along with Beijing, Nanjing, Shanghai, Tianjin and Xi'an. See Wu Peilun, Overview of Contemporary China's Government, p. 181.
-
As 1928
-
-
Early, A.1
-
39
-
-
33847545547
-
-
Qingdao nianjian 1992 (Qingdao Yearbook 1992) (Qingdao: Zhongguo baike quanshu chubanshe, 1993), p. 43.
-
See Qingdao Municipal Office for Historical Research, Qingdao nianjian 1992 (Qingdao Yearbook 1992) (Qingdao: Zhongguo baike quanshu chubanshe, 1993), p. 43.
-
Municipal Office for Historical Research
-
-
Qingdao, S.1
-
40
-
-
33847556362
-
-
Shun-zan Ye and Shi-kuan Zhou, "Qingdao: from colonial port to export base," in Yue-man Yeung and Xu-wei Hu (eds.), China's Coastal Cities: Catalysts for Modernization (Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press, 1992), pp. 85-107.
-
See Chung-tong Wu, Shun-zan Ye and Shi-kuan Zhou, "Qingdao: from colonial port to export base," in Yue-man Yeung and Xu-wei Hu (eds.), China's Coastal Cities: Catalysts for Modernization (Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press, 1992), pp. 85-107.
-
Wu
-
-
Chung-tong, S.1
-
41
-
-
33847542411
-
-
unlike those on Wenzhou, the Zhu [Pearl] River Delta, Dalian and the Sunan region. Interviewees, too, characterized Qingdao as a highly conservative city with little entrepreneurial heritage to speak of.
-
Published materials on Qingdao used for this study made no reference at all to such cultural traits, unlike those on Wenzhou, the Zhu [Pearl] River Delta, Dalian and the Sunan region. Interviewees, too, characterized Qingdao as a highly conservative city with little entrepreneurial heritage to speak of.
-
On Qingdao Used for This Study Made No Reference at All to Such Cultural Traits
-
-
Materials, P.1
-
42
-
-
33847565924
-
-
in terms of their total output values, was 86:14 in 1950, which went down to 71:29 in 1957 and further down to 58:42 in 1960. The ratio was still 60:40 as of 1978. See Research Office of the Shandong Provincial Party Committee, Shandong shengqing (Facts and Figures of Shandong Province) (Jinan: Shandong renmin chubanshe, 1989), pp. 472-74, 485. For the adverse impact of the Great Leap and the Cultural Revolution on Qingdao's economy, see Pang Xiuzheng, Lin Shuxiang and Wang Yongchang (eds.), Shandong jingjiyanjiu (Studies ofShandong 's Economy) (Jinan: Shandong rcnmin chubanshe, 1996), Vol. 1, pp. 287-88.
-
The ratio between light and heavy industries, in terms of their total output values, was 86:14 in 1950, which went down to 71:29 in 1957 and further down to 58:42 in 1960. The ratio was still 60:40 as of 1978. See Research Office of the Shandong Provincial Party Committee, Shandong shengqing (Facts and Figures of Shandong Province) (Jinan: Shandong renmin chubanshe, 1989), pp. 472-74, 485. For the adverse impact of the Great Leap and the Cultural Revolution on Qingdao's economy, see Pang Xiuzheng, Lin Shuxiang and Wang Yongchang (eds.), Shandong jingjiyanjiu (Studies ofShandong 's Economy) (Jinan: Shandong rcnmin chubanshe, 1996), Vol. 1, pp. 287-88.
-
Between Light and Heavy Industries
-
-
Ratio, T.1
-
45
-
-
33847559612
-
-
a little more than one-quarter of the increase in Qingdao's exports. In terms of foreign direct investment, Qingdao led the province by 400%. For Qingdao's role as the "dragonhead" in Shandong's development, see South China Morning Post, 7 September 1995.
-
Shandong's exports in 1995 increased over those of 1990 by 185%, a little more than one-quarter of the increase in Qingdao's exports. In terms of foreign direct investment, Qingdao led the province by 400%. For Qingdao's role as the "dragonhead" in Shandong's development, see South China Morning Post, 7 September 1995.
-
In 1995 Increased over Those of 1990 by 185%
-
-
Exports, S.1
-
46
-
-
33847572216
-
-
Four principal prerogatives came with the designation: the exemption of duties on imports of advanced technologies and equipments for plant renovation
-
Four principal prerogatives came with the designation: the exemption of duties on imports of advanced technologies and equipments for plant renovation (50% taxes were levied since 1994); the granting of authority to establish "development zones" (kaifaqu) where enterprises were allowed "two-year tax exemption and three-year tax reduction," as well as a 15% enterprise tax rate (as opposed to usual 33 to 55%) after the initial five years; the provision of approval authority for foreign-invested projects up to USS5 million in the early years and later to US$30 million; and the authority to approve both in- and out-bound international business delegations without going through the provincial authorities. See "Zhonggong zhongyang guowuyuan guanyu pizhuan yanhai bufen chengshi zuotanhui jiyao de tongzhi" ("Circular on the dissemination by the Party centre and the State Council of summary of the discussion meeting attended by some coastal cities: 4 May 1984"), in the Special Zones Office of the State Council, Zlwngguo duiwai kaifang zJiinan (Guide to China 's Opening to the Outside) (Kunming: Yunnan renmin chubanshe, 1993), pp. 153-59. For the evolution of preferential tax policies for coastal open cities, see Zheng Yanbiao (ed.), Zhongguo yanhai kaifang chengshi liyong walzlfalil wenti (Legal Issues Pertaining to the Use of Foreign Capital by China's Coastal Open Cities) (Shanghai: Shanghai shehui kexueyuan chubanshe, 1994), pp. 102-104.
-
-
-
-
47
-
-
33847551271
-
-
assembly-and-processing projects and foreign loans. Another important attachment to the designation was the permission for Qingdao to enact local legislation. In 1984-94, Qingdao enacted a total of 32 local laws and regulations mostly concerning foreign economic relations. See Qingdao ribao (Qingdao Daily), 17 December 1994.
-
Investment statistics are from interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and the figures include joint-equity and co-operative ventures, assembly-and-processing projects and foreign loans. Another important attachment to the designation was the permission for Qingdao to enact local legislation. In 1984-94, Qingdao enacted a total of 32 local laws and regulations mostly concerning foreign economic relations. See Qingdao ribao (Qingdao Daily), 17 December 1994.
-
Are from Interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and the Figures Include Joint-equity and Co-operative Ventures
-
-
Statistics, I.1
-
48
-
-
33847554219
-
-
Dangdai Zhongguo xlngdieng (Contemporary China's Public Administration) (Shanghai: Fudan University Press, 1993), p. 327. For the content of the CEC policy, see State Economic System Reform Commission (ed.), Zliongguo gaige kaifang shidian (Compendia of Issues and Events in China's Reform and Opening) (Foshan: Guangdong renmin chubanshe, 1993), pp. 133-140.
-
Thisjihua danlie policy had been implemented twice in the pre-reform era: on six cities during 1954-58; and on nine cities during 1964-67. SeeZhu Ganwei and Pu Xingzu, Dangdai Zhongguo xlngdieng (Contemporary China's Public Administration) (Shanghai: Fudan University Press, 1993), p. 327. For the content of the CEC policy, see State Economic System Reform Commission (ed.), Zliongguo gaige kaifang shidian (Compendia of Issues and Events in China's Reform and Opening) (Foshan: Guangdong renmin chubanshe, 1993), pp. 133-140.
-
Policy Had Been Implemented Twice in the Pre-reform Era: on Six Cities during 1954-58; and on Nine Cities during 1964-67. SeeZhu Ganwei and Pu Xingzu
-
-
Danlie, T.1
-
49
-
-
33847538639
-
-
Nanjing and Chengdu did not get such privileges in fiscal arrangements.
-
Three CECs of Guangzhou, Nanjing and Chengdu did not get such privileges in fiscal arrangements.
-
Of Guangzhou
-
-
Cecs, T.1
-
50
-
-
33847571584
-
-
see Dorothy J. Solinger, "The place of the central city in China's economic reform: from hierarchy to network?" in China's Transition from Socialism: Statist Legacies and Market Reforms 1980-1990 (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1993), p. 212
-
Perhaps, the CEC policy was initially intended as an administrative compensation for inland provincial capitals svith limited oversea access. For the designation of CECs, see Dorothy J. Solinger, "The place of the central city in China's economic reform: from hierarchy to network?" in China's Transition from Socialism: Statist Legacies and Market Reforms 1980-1990 (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1993), p. 212
-
CEC Policy Was Initially Intended As An Administrative Compensation for Inland Provincial Capitals Svith Limited Oversea Access. for the Designation of CECs
-
-
Perhaps, T.1
-
51
-
-
33847557023
-
-
suggests that it was Shandong that blocked Qingdao's bid for the CEC designation. According to this version, it was Li Chang'an who objected to Qingdao's joining the prestigious club of CECs.
-
Another version, however, suggests that it was Shandong that blocked Qingdao's bid for the CEC designation. According to this version, it was Li Chang'an who objected to Qingdao's joining the prestigious club of CECs.
-
However
-
-
Version, A.1
-
52
-
-
33847531445
-
-
see Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 293-304; Solinger, "City, province, and region," pp. 172-181 and "The place of the central city in China's economic reform," pp. 216-218; and Zhou Xuewen and Fang Xin, "Jihua danlie shi yu zhongyang he sheng shiquan huafen wenti" ("Problems of delineating the boundaries of authority for the center, provinces and central economic cities") in the Ministry of Personnel (ed.), Difangjigou gaige yanjiu (Study of Local Administrative Reform) (Beijing: Central Party School Press, 1992), pp. 281-87.
-
For such tension and conflict, see Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 293-304; Solinger, "City, province, and region," pp. 172-181 and "The place of the central city in China's economic reform," pp. 216-218; and Zhou Xuewen and Fang Xin, "Jihua danlie shi yu zhongyang he sheng shiquan huafen wenti" ("Problems of delineating the boundaries of authority for the center, provinces and central economic cities") in the Ministry of Personnel (ed.), Difangjigou gaige yanjiu (Study of Local Administrative Reform) (Beijing: Central Party School Press, 1992), pp. 281-87.
-
Tension and Conflict
-
-
Such, F.1
-
54
-
-
85028558658
-
-
remittances were determined not by the sharing rate but by the fixed amount. Therefore, the provinces were greatly encouraged to raise more revenues, which would then be reinvested and retained within the region. See Song Xinzhong, Zliongguo caizlieng tizlii gaige yanjiu (A Study of China 's Fiscal Reform) (Beijing: Zhongguo caizheng jingji chubanshe, 1992), pp. 59-62.
-
Under this arrangement, remittances were determined not by the sharing rate but by the fixed amount. Therefore, the provinces were greatly encouraged to raise more revenues, which would then be reinvested and retained within the region. See Song Xinzhong, Zliongguo caizlieng tizlii gaige yanjiu (A Study of China 's Fiscal Reform) (Beijing: Zhongguo caizheng jingji chubanshe, 1992), pp. 59-62.
-
Arrangement
-
-
This, U.1
-
55
-
-
33847550585
-
-
"Fenshuizhi yanjiu zhuanji" ("Special edition on the study of the tax-sharing system"), Jingji yanjiu cankao. No. 401 (1 January 1994), p. 41.
-
Interviews in Jinan and Qingdao in 1994; and Guo Yanzhong, "Fenshuizhi yanjiu zhuanji" ("Special edition on the study of the tax-sharing system"), Jingji yanjiu cankao. No. 401 (1 January 1994), p. 41.
-
Jinan and Qingdao in 1994; and Guo Yanzhong
-
-
In, I.1
-
56
-
-
33847568905
-
-
the State Council decided to deprive the eight provincial capitals of their CEC status, leaving only six non-capital CECs of Qingdao, Ningbo, Dalian, Chongqing, Xiamen and Shenzhen. See Jae Ho Chung, "Central-provincial relations," in Lo Chi Kin, Suzanne Pepper and Tsui Kai Yuen (eds.), China Review 1995 (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1995), pp. 3.18-21.
-
In August 1993, the State Council decided to deprive the eight provincial capitals of their CEC status, leaving only six non-capital CECs of Qingdao, Ningbo, Dalian, Chongqing, Xiamen and Shenzhen. See Jae Ho Chung, "Central-provincial relations," in Lo Chi Kin, Suzanne Pepper and Tsui Kai Yuen (eds.), China Review 1995 (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 1995), pp. 3.18-21.
-
-
-
August, I.1
-
58
-
-
33847538409
-
-
see State Economic System Reform Commission, Compendia of Issues and Events, pp. 137-38; and for the case of Wuhan which received 56 enterprises from Beijing and Hubei, see Solinger, "Despite decentralization," pp. 19-20.
-
For such a package measure, see State Economic System Reform Commission, Compendia of Issues and Events, pp. 137-38; and for the case of Wuhan which received 56 enterprises from Beijing and Hubei, see Solinger, "Despite decentralization," pp. 19-20.
-
A Package Measure
-
-
Such, F.1
-
62
-
-
33847571801
-
-
the zone's approval ceiling for foreign-invested projects was US$30 million, the same as those for Qingdao and Shandong. Information from Q'mgdao Yearbook 1992, pp. 47, 49; Wang Shengde, 'Tan Qingdao jingji jishu kaifaqu baoshuiqu he gaoxin jishu chanye kaifa shiyanqu de kaifa moshi he xiangguan zhengce" ("On Qingdao's development model and relevant policies for the economic and technological development zone, bonded zone and high-tech industrial development experimental zone") in Yanhai jingmao (Coastal Economy and Trade), No. 5 (1993), p. 34; and interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and 1996.
-
foreign-invested firms in the ETDZ were exempted for the first three years. Moreover, the zone's approval ceiling for foreign-invested projects was US$30 million, the same as those for Qingdao and Shandong. Information from Q'mgdao Yearbook 1992, pp. 47, 49; Wang Shengde, 'Tan Qingdao jingji jishu kaifaqu baoshuiqu he gaoxin jishu chanye kaifa shiyanqu de kaifa moshi he xiangguan zhengce" ("On Qingdao's development model and relevant policies for the economic and technological development zone, bonded zone and high-tech industrial development experimental zone") in Yanhai jingmao (Coastal Economy and Trade), No. 5 (1993), p. 34; and interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and 1996.
-
In the ETDZ Were Exempted for the First Three Years. Moreover
-
-
Firms, F.-I.1
-
63
-
-
33847558116
-
-
Zliongguo duiwai kaifang diqu touzl huanjing lie zliengce (Investment Environments and Policies in China 's Opened Areas)
-
For the most preferential terms granted to the "bonded zones," see the Special Zones Office of the State Council (ed.), Zliongguo duiwai kaifang diqu touzl huanjing lie zliengce (Investment Environments and Policies in China 's Opened Areas) (Kunming: Yunnan renmin chubanshe, 1993), pp. 170-183; and Ling Gao, "Bi tequ geng te de baoshuiqu" ("Bonded zones that are more special than the Special Economic Zones") in Yanhai jingmao. No. 6 (1993), pp. 41-42. Unlike the ETDZ which specialized more in exports, the "hi-tech science park" is devoted to manufacturing industries - like electronics, machinery and biochemical products - more for domestic sales and technology transfer. The "state tourism and leisure zone" is empowered to provide lower tax rates (usually 24%) for tourism enterprises located within the zone and to approve projects on golf clubs, foreign-invested department stores and so on. For "state tourism and leisure zones," see Pang Shaofeng, "Luyou wenhua yu guojia luyou dujiaqu" ('Tourism culture and state tourism and leisure zones") in Yanhai jingmao, No. 6 (1993), pp. 48-50. For Qingdao's high-tech technological and industrial development zone, see Qingdao Yearbook 1992, pp. 66-69 and Qingdao ribao, 17 December 1994. For favourable tax arrangements for these state-designated zones, see the Ministry of Finance (ed.), Zliongguo shuishou Mdu (China's Taxation System) (Beijing: Qiye guanli chubanshe, 1996), pp. 221-26.
-
Most Preferential Terms Granted to the "Bonded Zones," See the Special Zones Office of the State Council (Ed.)
-
-
The, F.1
-
65
-
-
33847545546
-
-
only Guangzhou and Dalian were able to share this privilege. China Dally, 12 January 1996.
-
Other than SEZs and three provincial-level municipalities, only Guangzhou and Dalian were able to share this privilege. China Dally, 12 January 1996.
-
SEZs and Three Provincial-level Municipalities
-
-
Than, O.1
-
67
-
-
33847535924
-
-
Shenyang (36.9%), Harbin (38.12%) and Dalian (34.14%), and even lower than Wuhan's 20%. See DangdaiZhongguo caizlieng (Contemporary China 's Finance) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1988), Vol. 1, p. 377.
-
Qingdao's retention rate of 11.7% in 1985 was less than a third of Chongqing (37.5%), Shenyang (36.9%), Harbin (38.12%) and Dalian (34.14%), and even lower than Wuhan's 20%. See DangdaiZhongguo caizlieng (Contemporary China 's Finance) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1988), Vol. 1, p. 377.
-
Rate of 11.7% in 1985 Was Less Than A Third of Chongqing (37.5%)
-
-
Retention, Q.1
-
68
-
-
33847563722
-
-
calculated on the basis of the data provided by the Qingdao Finance Bureau, fell from 77.6% in 1986 to 68.4% in 1990 and to 55.7% in 1993. See Christopher Heady, "Municipal public finance," in Wong, Financing Local Government, p. 155.
-
The ratio of actual remittances over total revenues, calculated on the basis of the data provided by the Qingdao Finance Bureau, fell from 77.6% in 1986 to 68.4% in 1990 and to 55.7% in 1993. See Christopher Heady, "Municipal public finance," in Wong, Financing Local Government, p. 155.
-
Of Actual Remittances over Total Revenues
-
-
Ratio, T.1
-
69
-
-
33847549577
-
-
p. 235 and interviews in Qingdao in 1996.
-
Qingdao Statistical Yearbook 1995, p. 235 and interviews in Qingdao in 1996.
-
Yearbook 1995
-
-
Statistical, Q.1
-
70
-
-
33847566323
-
-
Jiaonan, Pingdu, Laixi and Jimo. The seven districts are Huangdao, Laoshan, Chengyang, Lichang, Sifang, Northern and Southern.
-
Currently, the five cities refer to Jiaozhou, Jiaonan, Pingdu, Laixi and Jimo. The seven districts are Huangdao, Laoshan, Chengyang, Lichang, Sifang, Northern and Southern.
-
Five Cities Refer to Jiaozhou
-
-
Currently, T.1
-
71
-
-
33847543956
-
-
see Hong, "A tale of two cities"; Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 293-304; and Lam Tao-chiu, "Institutional constraints, leadership and development strategies: Panyu and Nanhai under reform," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 8.
-
For structural constraints imposed by higher-level units, see Hong, "A tale of two cities"; Schroeder, 'Territorial actors as competitors for power," pp. 293-304; and Lam Tao-chiu, "Institutional constraints, leadership and development strategies: Panyu and Nanhai under reform," in Chung, Cities in China, ch. 8.
-
Constraints Imposed by Higher-level Units
-
-
Structural, F.1
-
72
-
-
85041023019
-
-
see Jae Ho Chung, "The political economy of development and inequality in Shandong," pp. 138-142.
-
For Shandong's regional development strategy, see Jae Ho Chung, "The political economy of development and inequality in Shandong," pp. 138-142.
-
Regional Development Strategy
-
-
Shandong'S, F.1
-
73
-
-
33847536133
-
-
Huanbohai jingjiquan: Q'mgdao juan (The Bohai-Rim Economic Circle: Volume on Q'mgdao) (Qingdao: Qingdao chubanshe, 1996), pp. 98, 102.
-
Yu Dajiang and Li Xingdi (eds.), Huanbohai jingjiquan: Q'mgdao juan (The Bohai-Rim Economic Circle: Volume on Q'mgdao) (Qingdao: Qingdao chubanshe, 1996), pp. 98, 102.
-
And Li Xingdi (Eds.)
-
-
Dajiang, Y.1
-
74
-
-
33847533845
-
-
"An Pudong moshi jianshe Huangdao xin jingjiqu" ("Establish the new Huangdao Economic Zone in accordance with the Pudong model") in Yanhai jingmao. No. 7 (1993), pp. 11-12.
-
See Wang Shengde, "An Pudong moshi jianshe Huangdao xin jingjiqu" ("Establish the new Huangdao Economic Zone in accordance with the Pudong model") in Yanhai jingmao. No. 7 (1993), pp. 11-12.
-
Shengde
-
-
Wang, S.1
-
75
-
-
33847547819
-
-
see Research Office of the Shandong Provincial Party Committee, Shandong sishi nian (Last Forty Years in Shandong) (Jinan: Shandong renmin chubanshe, 1989), p. 140. For Shandong's self-assessment of its conservatism during the earlier period of reform, see Renmin ribao, 15 May 1988.
-
For the pervasive "leftist" influence in Shandong during the 1980s, see Research Office of the Shandong Provincial Party Committee, Shandong sishi nian (Last Forty Years in Shandong) (Jinan: Shandong renmin chubanshe, 1989), p. 140. For Shandong's self-assessment of its conservatism during the earlier period of reform, see Renmin ribao, 15 May 1988.
-
Pervasive "Leftist" Influence in Shandong during the 1980s
-
-
The, F.1
-
78
-
-
33847539237
-
-
see Malcomb Lamb, Directory of Officials and Organizations in China (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1994), p. 1132. Compared with Fuzhou (five each), Xiamen (four and five), and Dalian (five and three), Qingdao's turn-over rate was certainly much higher.
-
For the reshuffle, see Malcomb Lamb, Directory of Officials and Organizations in China (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 1994), p. 1132. Compared with Fuzhou (five each), Xiamen (four and five), and Dalian (five and three), Qingdao's turn-over rate was certainly much higher.
-
Reshuffle
-
-
The, F.1
-
79
-
-
33847545328
-
-
and he was also a vice-chairman of the Jiangsu Branch of the Chinese People's Political Consultative Conference until his death in 1994. ForZhang's biographical profile, see Wolfgang Bartke, Who 's Who in the People's Republic of China, 3rd ed. (München: Saur, 1991), Vol. 2, p. 829; and Zhongguo gongchandang retiming dacidian 1921-1991 (Who's Who in the Chinese Communist Party, 1921-1991) (Beijing: Zhongguo guoji guangbo chubanshe, 1991), p. 436.
-
Zhang Zhenhuan also served as the deputy head of the Leading Group for the Development of Electronics and Computers under the State Council, and he was also a vice-chairman of the Jiangsu Branch of the Chinese People's Political Consultative Conference until his death in 1994. ForZhang's biographical profile, see Wolfgang Bartke, Who 's Who in the People's Republic of China, 3rd ed. (München: Saur, 1991), Vol. 2, p. 829; and Zhongguo gongchandang retiming dacidian 1921-1991 (Who's Who in the Chinese Communist Party, 1921-1991) (Beijing: Zhongguo guoji guangbo chubanshe, 1991), p. 436.
-
Also Served As the Deputy Head of the Leading Group for the Development of Electronics and Computers under the State Council
-
-
Zhenhuan, Z.1
-
80
-
-
33847557897
-
-
see He Pin and Gao Xin, Zlionggong taitidang (Princelings in Communist China) (Hong Kong: Mingjing Publishing House, 1992), pp. 243-246; Zliongguo retiming dacidian (Who's Who in China: Current Leaders) (Beijing: Waiwen chubanshe, 1994) p. 819; and Qingdao nianjian 1995 (Qingdao Yearbook 1995) (Qingdao: Shandong youyi chubanshe, 1995), p. 309.
-
For Yu's biographical backgrounds, see He Pin and Gao Xin, Zlionggong taitidang (Princelings in Communist China) (Hong Kong: Mingjing Publishing House, 1992), pp. 243-246; Zliongguo retiming dacidian (Who's Who in China: Current Leaders) (Beijing: Waiwen chubanshe, 1994) p. 819; and Qingdao nianjian 1995 (Qingdao Yearbook 1995) (Qingdao: Shandong youyi chubanshe, 1995), p. 309.
-
Biographical Backgrounds
-
-
Yu'S, F.1
-
83
-
-
33847548499
-
-
see "Yantai shizhang Yu Zhengsheng" ("Yantai's Mayor - Yu Zhengsheng") in Guangjiaojing yuekan (Magnifying Glass Monthly), September 1988, pp. 82-83.
-
For Hong Kong media's coverage of Yu's accomplishments in Yantai, see "Yantai shizhang Yu Zhengsheng" ("Yantai's Mayor - Yu Zhengsheng") in Guangjiaojing yuekan (Magnifying Glass Monthly), September 1988, pp. 82-83.
-
Kong Media's Coverage of Yu's Accomplishments in Yantai
-
-
Hong, F.1
-
85
-
-
0024874724
-
-
Yu seems more exceptional than typical, as he is an "outsider" without extensive local work experience before assuming the mayoral position. As of 1986, almost 60% of all China's mayors were natives and another 13% were from the neighbouring provinces, although larger cities tended to have higher proportions of outsiders. See Cheng Li and David Bachman, "Localism, elitism, and immobilism: elite formation and social change in post-Mao China," World Politics, Vol. 42, No. 1 (October 1989), pp. 71, 78-79, 81. For the importance of family backgrounds in the politics of recruitment, see Jae Ho Chung, "The politics of prerogatives in socialism: the case of Taizidang in China," Studies in Comparative Communism, Vol. 24, No. 1 (March 1991), pp. 58-76.
-
Compared with the nation-wide data on mayors for 1986, Yu seems more exceptional than typical, as he is an "outsider" without extensive local work experience before assuming the mayoral position. As of 1986, almost 60% of all China's mayors were natives and another 13% were from the neighbouring provinces, although larger cities tended to have higher proportions of outsiders. See Cheng Li and David Bachman, "Localism, elitism, and immobilism: elite formation and social change in post-Mao China," World Politics, Vol. 42, No. 1 (October 1989), pp. 71, 78-79, 81. For the importance of family backgrounds in the politics of recruitment, see Jae Ho Chung, "The politics of prerogatives in socialism: the case of Taizidang in China," Studies in Comparative Communism, Vol. 24, No. 1 (March 1991), pp. 58-76.
-
The Nation-wide Data on Mayors for 1986
-
-
With, C.1
-
86
-
-
33847542628
-
-
there are hundreds, if not thousands, of "princelings" who all look for good opportunities to prove themselves. Yet not all of them succeed. That is, even among the princelings, there is fierce competition. He suggested that a good example is a competitive relationship between Yu Zhengsheng of Qingdao and Bo Xilai (Bo Yibo's son) of Dalian. He further argued that, given the handicap Yu has - his brother, Yu Qiangsheng, formerly with the Ministry of Public Security, had escaped to America in 1986 - Yu could not have made it without extraordinary efforts and accomplishments of his own. Yu's accomplishments in Qingdao landed him in the positions of a full member of the 15th Central Committee and Minister of Construction in 1997. For Jiang Zemin's positive assessment of Yu's record in Qingdao, see South China Morning Post, 21 March 1998.
-
An interviewee provided a telling insight. According to him, there are hundreds, if not thousands, of "princelings" who all look for good opportunities to prove themselves. Yet not all of them succeed. That is, even among the princelings, there is fierce competition. He suggested that a good example is a competitive relationship between Yu Zhengsheng of Qingdao and Bo Xilai (Bo Yibo's son) of Dalian. He further argued that, given the handicap Yu has - his brother, Yu Qiangsheng, formerly with the Ministry of Public Security, had escaped to America in 1986 - Yu could not have made it without extraordinary efforts and accomplishments of his own. Yu's accomplishments in Qingdao landed him in the positions of a full member of the 15th Central Committee and Minister of Construction in 1997. For Jiang Zemin's positive assessment of Yu's record in Qingdao, see South China Morning Post, 21 March 1998.
-
Provided A Telling Insight. According to Him
-
-
Interviewee, A.1
-
87
-
-
33847543955
-
-
while Guo Songnian as the Party secretary presumably had the final say on all crucial issues. Yu's role became more clearly identifiable after he replaced Guo in 1992 to serve concurrently as mayor and Party secretary.
-
Yu's role during 1989-91 remains veiled as he was the second-ranking official, while Guo Songnian as the Party secretary presumably had the final say on all crucial issues. Yu's role became more clearly identifiable after he replaced Guo in 1992 to serve concurrently as mayor and Party secretary.
-
During 1989-91 Remains Veiled As He Was the Second-ranking Official
-
-
Role, Y.1
-
88
-
-
33847567211
-
-
but no leadership dared to act upon it. Shanghai's Pudong Development is alleged to have worked as a catalyst for the decision. Interviews in Qingdao in 1994.
-
The idea of moving the government complex to the eastern area had been floated since the late 1970s, but no leadership dared to act upon it. Shanghai's Pudong Development is alleged to have worked as a catalyst for the decision. Interviews in Qingdao in 1994.
-
Of Moving the Government Complex to the Eastern Area Had Been Floated since the Late 1970s
-
-
Idea, T.1
-
92
-
-
33847563063
-
-
however, is that Qingdao's MPO gets involved only in the process of initiating projects. Once the contract is signed, the main responsibility goes to the functional departments of the municipal government. On the other hand, Shanghai's MPO (zliongdian gongcheng bangongshf) gets involved only in the post-contract phase. Interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and 1996.
-
The idea of MPO originated from Shanghai where Zhu Rongji first established a unit called MPO. The idea was soon adopted by Nanjing and later by Qingdao. One key difference, however, is that Qingdao's MPO gets involved only in the process of initiating projects. Once the contract is signed, the main responsibility goes to the functional departments of the municipal government. On the other hand, Shanghai's MPO (zliongdian gongcheng bangongshf) gets involved only in the post-contract phase. Interviews in Qingdao in 1994 and 1996.
-
Of MPO Originated from Shanghai Where Zhu Rongji First Established A Unit Called MPO. the Idea Was Soon Adopted by Nanjing and Later by Qingdao. One Key Difference
-
-
Idea, T.1
-
95
-
-
33847561978
-
-
pp. 70-71. Items 1 and 4 are particularly interesting since they make it no secret that the city wants to sustain a good working relationship with the central government and the State Council and to exert influence over the centre's policy.
-
These five functions are listed in Qingdao Yearbook 1992, pp. 70-71. Items 1 and 4 are particularly interesting since they make it no secret that the city wants to sustain a good working relationship with the central government and the State Council and to exert influence over the centre's policy.
-
Functions Are Listed in Qingdao Yearbook 1992
-
-
Five, T.1
-
97
-
-
33847571988
-
-
for You-tien Hsing, Making Capitalism in China: The Taiwan Connection (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998), chs. 5-7.
-
See, for instance, You-tien Hsing, Making Capitalism in China: The Taiwan Connection (New York: Oxford University Press, 1998), chs. 5-7.
-
Instance
-
-
See1
-
99
-
-
33847569344
-
-
see South China Morning Post, 25 October 1988.
-
For the designation, see South China Morning Post, 25 October 1988.
-
Designation
-
-
The, F.1
-
100
-
-
33847551938
-
-
Zlianhou Hanguojingjiyu Zliong-Han jinginao guaim (Korea's Post-war Economy and Sino-Korean Economic Relations) (Qingdao: Qingdao haiyang daxue chubanshe, 1995), pp. 222-25. For the visa-issuing privileges granted to Qingdao with respect to South Koreans, see Qingdao Municipal Archives Office (ed.), Qingdao shiztii: waishi qiaowu z/ii (Qingdao Historical Gazeteer: Volume on Foreign Affairs and Overseas Chinese) (Beijing: Xinhua chubanshe, 1995), p. 19.
-
See Han Limin and Wu Gang (eds.), Zlianhou Hanguojingjiyu Zliong-Han jinginao guaim (Korea's Post-war Economy and Sino-Korean Economic Relations) (Qingdao: Qingdao haiyang daxue chubanshe, 1995), pp. 222-25. For the visa-issuing privileges granted to Qingdao with respect to South Koreans, see Qingdao Municipal Archives Office (ed.), Qingdao shiztii: waishi qiaowu z/ii (Qingdao Historical Gazeteer: Volume on Foreign Affairs and Overseas Chinese) (Beijing: Xinhua chubanshe, 1995), p. 19.
-
Limin and Wu Gang (Eds.)
-
-
Han, S.1
-
101
-
-
33847548706
-
-
see Howell, China Opens Its Doors, p. 25.
-
For such perceptions in general, see Howell, China Opens Its Doors, p. 25.
-
Perceptions in General
-
-
Such, F.1
-
103
-
-
33847544879
-
-
Han Yanwei, Wang Dongkai and Li Binglie, "Qingdaoshi sanzi qiye fazhan de sikao" ("Thoughts on the development of foreign-invested firms in Qingdao"), in Gitojijingji hezuo (International Economic Co-operation), No. 9 (1991), p. 14.
-
See He Lianhua, Han Yanwei, Wang Dongkai and Li Binglie, "Qingdaoshi sanzi qiye fazhan de sikao" ("Thoughts on the development of foreign-invested firms in Qingdao"), in Gitojijingji hezuo (International Economic Co-operation), No. 9 (1991), p. 14.
-
Lianhua
-
-
He, S.1
-
104
-
-
33847554640
-
-
chairman of the Qingdao Sub-Council of the China Council for the Promotion of International Trade (CCP1T) in 1994.
-
The following paragraphs are based upon the interview with Wang Yan, chairman of the Qingdao Sub-Council of the China Council for the Promotion of International Trade (CCP1T) in 1994.
-
Paragraphs Are Based Upon the Interview with Wang Yan
-
-
Following, T.1
-
105
-
-
33847562168
-
-
the chronic problems with steady supply of electricity and water for industrial production were basically resolved. Jiqing Super Highway linked Qingdao with Jinan and Dezhou, and the capacity of Qingdao's harbour was raised from 28 million tons in 1987 to 42 million tons in 1994. See Ma Yannong, "Qingdao fazhan waixiangxing jingji de zhanlüe shexiang" ("Strategic thinking about the development of 'outward-oriented economy' in Qingdao") in Shandongjihuajingji (Shandong 's Planned Economy), No. 4 ( 1987), pp. 20-22; and Qingdao Yearbook 1995, p. 222.
-
Qingdao's efforts in improving its "hard environment" are well noted. By 1990, the chronic problems with steady supply of electricity and water for industrial production were basically resolved. Jiqing Super Highway linked Qingdao with Jinan and Dezhou, and the capacity of Qingdao's harbour was raised from 28 million tons in 1987 to 42 million tons in 1994. See Ma Yannong, "Qingdao fazhan waixiangxing jingji de zhanlüe shexiang" ("Strategic thinking about the development of 'outward-oriented economy' in Qingdao") in Shandongjihuajingji (Shandong 's Planned Economy), No. 4 ( 1987), pp. 20-22; and Qingdao Yearbook 1995, p. 222.
-
In Improving Its "Hard Environment" Are Well Noted. by 1990
-
-
Efforts, Q.1
-
106
-
-
33847535679
-
-
too, Qingdao considerably simplified the inspection procedures. Instead of carrying out inspections by boarding vessels, it opened an office to conduct inspections on land. See South China Morning Post, 5 May 1995. Such measures were also closely related to the city's desire to turn itself into a "free port." See Ling Gao, "Bijian Qingdao ziyougangqu" ("Establish the free-port zone in Qingdao") in Yanhai jingmao, No. 5 (1993), pp. 38-10.
-
The figure of 20 days is only for projects handled by CCPIT. Interview in Qingdao in 1996. In the area of foreign trade, too, Qingdao considerably simplified the inspection procedures. Instead of carrying out inspections by boarding vessels, it opened an office to conduct inspections on land. See South China Morning Post, 5 May 1995. Such measures were also closely related to the city's desire to turn itself into a "free port." See Ling Gao, "Bijian Qingdao ziyougangqu" ("Establish the free-port zone in Qingdao") in Yanhai jingmao, No. 5 (1993), pp. 38-10.
-
Of 20 Days Is only for Projects Handled by CCPIT. Interview in Qingdao in 1996. in the Area of Foreign Trade
-
-
Figure, T.1
-
107
-
-
33847540898
-
-
the most complete line of services has been provided only for South Korean investors through the CCPIT system, which was originally developed during the period when China had no diplomatic relations with South Korea. According to an interviewee, the CCPIT of Qingdao recently (May 1994) established the Department of Japan Affairs (Ribeti chu) upon strong requests from Japanese firms which desired to receive the same services. For more details of the services provided by CCPIT, see "Cong shiji chufa chuangchu yi tiao you Qingdao lese de liyong waizi xin luzi" ("On the basis of the actual situation, create a new path of foreign investment with Qingdao's characteristics"), Qingdao zliengkan (Political Readings of Qingdao), March 1994, pp. 59-63.
-
Up till very recently, the most complete line of services has been provided only for South Korean investors through the CCPIT system, which was originally developed during the period when China had no diplomatic relations with South Korea. According to an interviewee, the CCPIT of Qingdao recently (May 1994) established the Department of Japan Affairs (Ribeti chu) upon strong requests from Japanese firms which desired to receive the same services. For more details of the services provided by CCPIT, see "Cong shiji chufa chuangchu yi tiao you Qingdao lese de liyong waizi xin luzi" ("On the basis of the actual situation, create a new path of foreign investment with Qingdao's characteristics"), Qingdao zliengkan (Political Readings of Qingdao), March 1994, pp. 59-63.
-
Very Recently
-
-
Till, U.1
-
111
-
-
33847561530
-
-
see Jonathan R. Woetzel, China 's Economic Opening to the Outside World: The Politics of Empowerment (New York: Praeger, 1989), pp. 114-123. The number of South Korean FWOs in Qingdao was calculated from the CCPIT list of South Korea-invested Firms in Qingdao and the percentage of FWOs in Qingdao was calculated from Qingdao Statistical Yearbook 1993, pp. 277-78; 7992, p. 278; and 7997, p. 269. Considering that Qingdao's general policy was to encourage only medium-sized to large ventures in electronics, machinery and chemical industries to adopt the FWO format, the city was clearly giving South Korean investment a special treatment for
-
For various problems related to joint-equity ventures, see Jonathan R. Woetzel, China 's Economic Opening to the Outside World: The Politics of Empowerment (New York: Praeger, 1989), pp. 114-123. The number of South Korean FWOs in Qingdao was calculated from the CCPIT list of South Korea-invested Firms in Qingdao and the percentage of FWOs in Qingdao was calculated from Qingdao Statistical Yearbook 1993, pp. 277-78; 7992, p. 278; and 7997, p. 269. Considering that Qingdao's general policy was to encourage only medium-sized to large ventures in electronics, machinery and chemical industries to adopt the FWO format, the city was clearly giving South Korean investment a special treatment for
-
Problems Related to Joint-equity Ventures
-
-
Various, F.1
-
113
-
-
33847535678
-
-
see Yu Dajiang and Li Xingdi, The Bohal-Rim Economic Circle, p. 116. The strategy of combining agriculture, processing and trade is another priority policy in Qingdao. See Gao Changli, "Shandong nongcun gaige yu xianyu jingji fazhan" ("Shandong's rural reform and its county-level economic development") in Nongye jingji wenti (Problems of Agricultural Economy), No. 8 (1991), p. 18; Dazhong ribao, 25 December 1992; and Qingdao Economic System Reform Commission, "Fahui chengshi gongneng tuidong chengxiang jingji fazhan yu gaige de yitihua" ("Develop towns and villages together by activating the energy of the city"), in He Guanghui (ed.), Chengshi gaige zhi lu (The Road to Urban Reform) (Beijing: Gaige chubanshe, 1992), pp. 272-280.
-
For the case of South Korean investment in Qingdao, see Yu Dajiang and Li Xingdi, The Bohal-Rim Economic Circle, p. 116. The strategy of combining agriculture, processing and trade is another priority policy in Qingdao. See Gao Changli, "Shandong nongcun gaige yu xianyu jingji fazhan" ("Shandong's rural reform and its county-level economic development") in Nongye jingji wenti (Problems of Agricultural Economy), No. 8 (1991), p. 18; Dazhong ribao, 25 December 1992; and Qingdao Economic System Reform Commission, "Fahui chengshi gongneng tuidong chengxiang jingji fazhan yu gaige de yitihua" ("Develop towns and villages together by activating the energy of the city"), in He Guanghui (ed.), Chengshi gaige zhi lu (The Road to Urban Reform) (Beijing: Gaige chubanshe, 1992), pp. 272-280.
-
Case of South Korean Investment in Qingdao
-
-
The, F.1
-
114
-
-
33847541752
-
-
and four of them came from South Korea. For South Korea's investment in China and the impact of diplomatic normalization on it, see Jae Ho Chung, "The political economy of South Korea-China bilateralism: origins, progress and prospects," in Ilpyong Kim and Hong Pyo Lee (eds.), Korea and China in A New World: Beyond Normalization (Seoul: The Sejong Institute, 1993), pp. 283, 301.
-
In 1993, there were six foreign-invested projects committed in Qingdao whose size exceeded US$10 million, and four of them came from South Korea. For South Korea's investment in China and the impact of diplomatic normalization on it, see Jae Ho Chung, "The political economy of South Korea-China bilateralism: origins, progress and prospects," in Ilpyong Kim and Hong Pyo Lee (eds.), Korea and China in A New World: Beyond Normalization (Seoul: The Sejong Institute, 1993), pp. 283, 301.
-
There Were Six Foreign-invested Projects Committed in Qingdao Whose Size Exceeded US$10 Million
-
-
-
117
-
-
33847533397
-
-
Quyu hezuo yu jingji gangluo (Inter-regional Co-operation and Economic Linkages) (Beijing: Jingji kexue chubanshe, 1987), pp. 185-192; Zhongguo hengxiang jingji nianjian 7992 (The Yearbook of Chinese Horizontal Economy) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1993), pp. 275,277; and interviews in Jinan in 1995 and in Qingdao in 1996.
-
Information from Zhang Wanqing, Quyu hezuo yu jingji gangluo (Inter-regional Co-operation and Economic Linkages) (Beijing: Jingji kexue chubanshe, 1987), pp. 185-192; Zhongguo hengxiang jingji nianjian 7992 (The Yearbook of Chinese Horizontal Economy) (Beijing: Zhongguo shehui kexue chubanshe, 1993), pp. 275,277; and interviews in Jinan in 1995 and in Qingdao in 1996.
-
Zhang Wanqing
-
-
From, I.1
-
120
-
-
33847559874
-
-
Hong Kong media had a very close coverage of this controversy. See South China Morning Post, 25 January, 27 April, 23 August, and 15 and 18 September 1995.
-
For obvious reasons, Hong Kong media had a very close coverage of this controversy. See South China Morning Post, 25 January, 27 April, 23 August, and 15 and 18 September 1995.
-
Reasons
-
-
Obvious, F.1
-
121
-
-
33847561042
-
-
the total number of various kinds of development zones in China dropped from 3,000 to 500 and over 90% of those established by sub-provincial authorities were closed down. Zliongguo gaige kaifang shhru nian dashiji (Fifteen-Year Chronology of China's Reform and Opening) (Beijing: Xinhua chubanshe, 1994), pp. 225, 238, 240.
-
By November 1993, the total number of various kinds of development zones in China dropped from 3,000 to 500 and over 90% of those established by sub-provincial authorities were closed down. Zliongguo gaige kaifang shhru nian dashiji (Fifteen-Year Chronology of China's Reform and Opening) (Beijing: Xinhua chubanshe, 1994), pp. 225, 238, 240.
-
-
-
November, B.1
|