메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 73, Issue 2, 1998, Pages 511-515

Toward Contractual Choice in Marriage

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0032372754     PISSN: 00196665     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (2)

References (14)
  • 1
    • 0032377821 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Lifting the Veil of Ignorance: Personalizing the Marriage Contract
    • See Eric Rasmusen & Jeffrey Evans Stake, Lifting the Veil of Ignorance: Personalizing the Marriage Contract, 73 IND. L.J. 453 (1998).
    • (1998) Ind. L.J. , vol.73 , pp. 453
    • Rasmusen, E.1    Stake, J.E.2
  • 2
    • 0004106624 scopus 로고
    • rev. & enlarged ed.
    • On the gains to specialization within marriage, see GARY S. BECKER, A TREATISE ON THE FAMILY 30-53 (rev. & enlarged ed. 1991).
    • (1991) A Treatise on the Family , pp. 30-53
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 3
    • 84909769712 scopus 로고
    • Economics of Alimony
    • see also BECKER, supra note 2, at 14
    • See Elisabeth M. Landes, Economics of Alimony, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 35, 38-39 (1978); see also BECKER, supra note 2, at 14.
    • (1978) J. Legal Stud. , vol.7 , pp. 35
    • Landes, E.M.1
  • 4
    • 0000062085 scopus 로고
    • Unilateral Divorce and the Labor-Force Participation Rates of Married Women, Revisited
    • On the effect of no-fault divorce on the labor-force participation of women, compare Allen M. Parkman, Unilateral Divorce and the Labor-Force Participation Rates of Married Women, Revisited, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 671 (1992), with H. Elizabeth Peters, Marriage and Divorce: Informational Constraints and Private Contracting, 76 AM. ECON. REV. 437 (1986).
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 671
    • Parkman, A.M.1
  • 5
    • 0000620362 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and Divorce: Informational Constraints and Private Contracting
    • On the effect of no-fault divorce on the labor-force participation of women, compare Allen M. Parkman, Unilateral Divorce and the Labor-Force Participation Rates of Married Women, Revisited, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 671 (1992), with H. Elizabeth Peters, Marriage and Divorce: Informational Constraints and Private Contracting, 76 AM. ECON. REV. 437 (1986).
    • (1986) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 437
    • Peters, H.E.1
  • 6
    • 77952080005 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and Opportunism
    • See Margaret F. Brinig & Steven M. Crafton, Marriage and Opportunism, 23 J. LEGAL STUD. 869 (1994).
    • (1994) J. Legal Stud. , vol.23 , pp. 869
    • Brinig, M.F.1    Crafton, S.M.2
  • 7
    • 0000818384 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability
    • See generally BECKER, supra note 2; Gary S. Becker et al., An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability, 85 J. POL. ECON. 1141 (1977).
    • (1977) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.85 , pp. 1141
    • Becker, G.S.1
  • 8
    • 0000376358 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and Divorce: Reply
    • same
    • The theoretical point here is not disputed, at least within the law-and-economics community. There has been empirical debate, however, over how large the transaction costs (and any other potential impediments to negotiation) are, and whether they are large enough to have a noticeable effect on divorce rates. See generally BECKER, supra note 2, at 333-35 (arguing that no-fault divorce has only temporary effect on divorce rate); Peters, supra note 4 (stating that no-fault does not affect divorce rates); H. Elizabeth Peters, Marriage and Divorce: Reply, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 686 (1992) (same). But see Douglas W. Allen, Marriage and Divorce: Comment, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 679 (1992) (arguing that no-fault does increase divorce rates); Martin Zelder, Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of No-Fault Divorce, 22 J. LEGAL STUD. 503 (1993) (same).
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 686
    • Peters, H.E.1
  • 9
    • 0001068513 scopus 로고
    • Marriage and Divorce: Comment
    • The theoretical point here is not disputed, at least within the law-and-economics community. There has been empirical debate, however, over how large the transaction costs (and any other potential impediments to negotiation) are, and whether they are large enough to have a noticeable effect on divorce rates. See generally BECKER, supra note 2, at 333-35 (arguing that no-fault divorce has only temporary effect on divorce rate); Peters, supra note 4 (stating that no-fault does not affect divorce rates); H. Elizabeth Peters, Marriage and Divorce: Reply, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 686 (1992) (same). But see Douglas W. Allen, Marriage and Divorce: Comment, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 679 (1992) (arguing that no-fault does increase divorce rates); Martin Zelder, Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of No-Fault Divorce, 22 J. LEGAL STUD. 503 (1993) (same).
    • (1992) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 679
    • Allen, D.W.1
  • 10
    • 0013158894 scopus 로고
    • Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of No-Fault Divorce
    • same
    • The theoretical point here is not disputed, at least within the law-and-economics community. There has been empirical debate, however, over how large the transaction costs (and any other potential impediments to negotiation) are, and whether they are large enough to have a noticeable effect on divorce rates. See generally BECKER, supra note 2, at 333-35 (arguing that no-fault divorce has only temporary effect on divorce rate); Peters, supra note 4 (stating that no-fault does not affect divorce rates); H. Elizabeth Peters, Marriage and Divorce: Reply, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 686 (1992) (same). But see Douglas W. Allen, Marriage and Divorce: Comment, 82 AM. ECON. REV. 679 (1992) (arguing that no-fault does increase divorce rates); Martin Zelder, Inefficient Dissolutions as a Consequence of Public Goods: The Case of No-Fault Divorce, 22 J. LEGAL STUD. 503 (1993) (same).
    • (1993) J. Legal Stud. , vol.22 , pp. 503
    • Zelder, M.1
  • 11
    • 1542657078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peters, supra note 7, at 690 (emphasis in original)
    • Peters, supra note 7, at 690 (emphasis in original).
  • 12
    • 1542762189 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Peters, supra note 4, at 452-53
    • Peters, supra note 4, at 452-53.
  • 13
    • 84934182015 scopus 로고
    • The Family and the State
    • Critics object that he can also leave by abusing her so badly that she finds marriage intolerable - indeed, this is a point Becker himself made. See Gary S. Becker & Kevin M. Murphy, The Family and the State, 31 J.L. & ECON. 1, 14 (1988). While the danger of abuse is a problem to be sure, it is one the law can substantially mitigate by making abuse itself grounds for which she can demand high levels of alimony.
    • (1988) J.L. & Econ. , vol.31 , pp. 1
    • Becker, G.S.1    Murphy, K.M.2
  • 14
    • 0001757334 scopus 로고
    • A Transaction Cost Approach to Families and Households
    • See Robert A. Pollak, A Transaction Cost Approach to Families and Households, 23 J. ECON. LITERATURE 581, 601 (1985). Compare Parkman, supra note 4 (recognizing that no-fault divorce has increased the number of married women in the workforce, but arguing that the increase is due to a lack of compensation at divorce for a married woman's reduced earning capacity), with Peters, supra note 4 (arguing that no-fault divorce causes an increase in the number of married women in the workforce because married women are not compensated at divorce for marriage-specific investments).
    • (1985) J. Econ. Literature , vol.23 , pp. 581
    • Pollak, R.A.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.