메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 26, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 363-390

Welfare state limits to globalization

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0032357933     PISSN: 00323292     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1177/0032329298026003004     Document Type: Review
Times cited : (74)

References (137)
  • 1
    • 0003550078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Cambridge University Press
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1998) Partisan Politics in the Global Economy
    • Garrett, G.1
  • 2
    • 0007626522 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1996) A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion
    • Lawrence, R.Z.1    Bressand, A.2    Ito, T.3
  • 3
    • 0040524004 scopus 로고
    • Politische unverträglichkeiten von globalisierung
    • ed. Ulrich Steger Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1995) Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt , pp. 83-114
    • Kohler-Koch, B.1
  • 4
    • 0002082390 scopus 로고
    • Jenseits der staatlichkeit: Über die folgen der ungleichzeitigen denationalisierung
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1992) Leviathan , vol.20 , pp. 490-513
    • Zürn, M.1
  • 5
    • 0039931146 scopus 로고
    • Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1995) Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography
    • Rieger, E.1    Leibfried, S.2
  • 6
    • 85033872620 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Like oil and water: A tale of two economists
    • Sunday, 16 February, sec. 3
    • For a first foray into the literature, see Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics in the Global Economy (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998); Robert Z. Lawrence, Albert Bressand, and Takatoshi Ito. A Vision for the World Economy: Openness, Diversity, and Cohesion (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1996); Beate Kohler-Koch, "Politische Unverträglichkeiten von Globalisierung," in Globalisierung der Wirtschaft - Konsequenzen für Arbeit, Technik und Umwelt, ed. Ulrich Steger (Bonn: J.H.W. Dietz, 1995): 83-114; and Michael Zürn, "Jenseits der Staatlichkeit: Über die Folgen der ungleichzeitigen Denationalisierung," Leviathan 20 (1992): 490-513. For a bibliography on the welfare state and globalization, see Elmar Rieger and Stephan Leibfried, Globalization and the Western Welfare State: An Annotated Bibliography (Bremen: GAAC/SSRC/Wissenschaftskolleg zu Berlin with Centre for Social Policy, Bremen, and Centre for European Social Research, Mannheim, 1995). The pros and cons of globalization discussed among economists are illustrated by a contrast of the work and biography of Lester Thurow and Paul Krugman: "Like Oil and Water: A Tale of Two Economists" (The New York Times, Sunday, 16 February 1997, sec. 3: 1, 10, 11).
    • (1997) The New York Times , pp. 1
    • Thurow, L.1    Krugman, P.2
  • 7
    • 85033878512 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Für eine zukunft in solidarität und gerechtigkeit
    • 1 March 1997
    • The most recent example is the Ecumenical Declaration of the Catholic and Protestant Churches in Germany: Für eine Zukunft in Solidarität und Gerechtigkeit (1997), excerpted in Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung (1 March 1997): 8. This declaration is modeled on the 1986 declaration of the U.S. Catholic bishops, Economic Justice for All.
    • (1997) Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung , pp. 8
  • 8
    • 0005046536 scopus 로고
    • declaration of the U.S. Catholic bishops
    • The most recent example is the Ecumenical Declaration of the Catholic and Protestant Churches in Germany: Für eine Zukunft in Solidarität und Gerechtigkeit (1997), excerpted in Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung (1 March 1997): 8. This declaration is modeled on the 1986 declaration of the U.S. Catholic bishops, Economic Justice for All.
    • (1986) Economic Justice for All
  • 9
    • 85033871510 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • was the National Socialist legal term for such tendencies
    • "Schutz der nationalen Arbeit" was the National Socialist legal term for such tendencies.
    • Schutz der Nationalen Arbeit
  • 10
    • 85033876369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Die bedeutung der sozialpolitik für unternehmerische standortentscheidungen
    • ed. Winfried Schmähl and Herbert Rische Baden-Baden: Nomos
    • For example, Werner Maly, "Die Bedeutung der Sozialpolitik für unternehmerische Standortentscheidungen," in Internationalisierung von Wirtschaft und Politik: Handlungsspielräume der nationalen Sozialpolitik, ed. Winfried Schmähl and Herbert Rische (Baden-Baden: Nomos, 1997): 79-101; and Amity Shlaes, "Germany's Chained Economy," Foreign Affairs 73 (1994): 109-24.
    • (1997) Internationalisierung von Wirtschaft und Politik: Handlungsspielräume der Nationalen Sozialpolitik , pp. 79-101
    • Maly, W.1
  • 11
    • 84937304204 scopus 로고
    • Germany's chained economy
    • For example, Werner Maly, "Die Bedeutung der Sozialpolitik für unternehmerische Standortentscheidungen," in Internationalisierung von Wirtschaft und Politik: Handlungsspielräume der nationalen Sozialpolitik, ed. Winfried Schmähl and Herbert Rische (Baden-Baden: Nomos, 1997): 79-101; and Amity Shlaes, "Germany's Chained Economy," Foreign Affairs 73 (1994): 109-24.
    • (1994) Foreign Affairs , vol.73 , pp. 109-124
    • Shlaes, A.1
  • 12
    • 85033881631 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sozialpartnerschaft, betriebliche sozialpolitik und unternehmenskultur: Eine institutionenökonomische analyse
    • See Josef Wieland, "Sozialpartnerschaft, betriebliche Sozialpolitik und Unternehmenskultur: Eine institutionenökonomische Analyse," Wittener Jahrbuch für ökonomische Literatur (1996): 143-60; and Michael Hüther, "Umbau der Sozialen Sicherungssysteme im Zeichen der Globalisierung," Zeitschrift for Wirtschaftspolitik 46 (1997): 193-214. For a contraposition see Heinz Lampert, "Voraussetzungen einer Sozialstaatsreform-kritische Anmerkungen zur aktuellen Diskussion über den Umbau des Sozialstaats," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonmie und Statistik 214 (1995): 513-31.
    • (1996) Wittener Jahrbuch für Ökonomische Literatur , pp. 143-160
    • Wieland, J.1
  • 13
    • 4243361144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Umbau der sozialen sicherungssysteme im zeichen der globalisierung
    • See Josef Wieland, "Sozialpartnerschaft, betriebliche Sozialpolitik und Unternehmenskultur: Eine institutionenökonomische Analyse," Wittener Jahrbuch für ökonomische Literatur (1996): 143-60; and Michael Hüther, "Umbau der Sozialen Sicherungssysteme im Zeichen der Globalisierung," Zeitschrift for Wirtschaftspolitik 46 (1997): 193-214. For a contraposition see Heinz Lampert, "Voraussetzungen einer Sozialstaatsreform-kritische Anmerkungen zur aktuellen Diskussion über den Umbau des Sozialstaats," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonmie und Statistik 214 (1995): 513-31.
    • (1997) Zeitschrift for Wirtschaftspolitik , vol.46 , pp. 193-214
    • Hüther, M.1
  • 14
    • 0039931129 scopus 로고
    • Voraussetzungen einer sozialstaatsreform-kritische anmerkungen zur aktuellen diskussion über den umbau des sozialstaats
    • See Josef Wieland, "Sozialpartnerschaft, betriebliche Sozialpolitik und Unternehmenskultur: Eine institutionenökonomische Analyse," Wittener Jahrbuch für ökonomische Literatur (1996): 143-60; and Michael Hüther, "Umbau der Sozialen Sicherungssysteme im Zeichen der Globalisierung," Zeitschrift for Wirtschaftspolitik 46 (1997): 193-214. For a contraposition see Heinz Lampert, "Voraussetzungen einer Sozialstaatsreform-kritische Anmerkungen zur aktuellen Diskussion über den Umbau des Sozialstaats," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonmie und Statistik 214 (1995): 513-31.
    • (1995) Jahrbücher für Nationalökonmie und Statistik , vol.214 , pp. 513-531
    • Lampert, H.1
  • 15
    • 0039338917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stanford, CA: Center for Advanced Studies in the Behavioral Sciences
    • Obviously, this assessment is based mainly on the (Western) European experience. In this context one can also note that the predicament of the European Monetary Union seems quite similar: EMU is linked to domestic reforms in fiscal and budgetary affairs, which resulted in mutual hostage-taking and gridlock, rather than functioning as a means of external enforcement of internal reforms, as the heads of state had hoped at Maastricht. See Barry Eichengreen, EMU Up in the Air (Stanford, CA: Center for Advanced Studies in the Behavioral Sciences, 1997).
    • (1997) EMU Up in the Air
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 16
    • 34248987143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National industrialization and the declining share of the international economic sector, 1890-1959
    • See Karl Deutsch and Alexander Eckstein, "National Industrialization and the Declining Share of the International Economic Sector, 1890-1959," World Politics 14 (1960/61): 267-99; and Harold James, International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fond, and New York: Oxford University Press, 1996): 1-26.
    • (1960) World Politics , vol.14 , pp. 267-299
    • Deutsch, K.1    Eckstein, A.2
  • 17
    • 34248987143 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: International Monetary Fond, and New York: Oxford University Press
    • See Karl Deutsch and Alexander Eckstein, "National Industrialization and the Declining Share of the International Economic Sector, 1890-1959," World Politics 14 (1960/61): 267-99; and Harold James, International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fond, and New York: Oxford University Press, 1996): 1-26.
    • (1996) International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods , pp. 1-26
    • James, H.1
  • 18
    • 0004334280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The sheer volume of globalized financial transactions is often advanced as evidence of an unparalleled qualitative change. This is untenable in the historical context -not to mention the equally routine assertion of associated negative consequences for the autonomy of nation-states: Some measurements of the degree of financial integration in the world economy indicate that at the beginning of the twentieth century the world was more interconnected than at any subsequent time (including the 1990s, despite the trillions of dollars of daily currency movements). These measurements examine the behavior of saving and investment levels. Investment and savings were coordinated on a global level, with the result that a surplus of investment in one area or state (that is, a balance of payments current account deficit) could be smoothly financed by the export of surplus savings from another area. Even in the highly integrated 1980s and 1990s, such transfers were much more difficult and raised many more political eyebrows than in the golden era that preceded the First World War. (Harold James, International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods, 12)
    • International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods , pp. 12
    • James, H.1
  • 19
    • 0004062585 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • See Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History: Myth and Paradoxes (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993); Jagdish Bhagwati, Protectionism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); Charles Kindleberger, World Economic Primacy 1500-1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996); and Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1989).
    • (1993) Economics and World History: Myth and Paradoxes
    • Bairoch, P.1
  • 20
    • 0004186070 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: MIT Press
    • See Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History: Myth and Paradoxes (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993); Jagdish Bhagwati, Protectionism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); Charles Kindleberger, World Economic Primacy 1500-1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996); and Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1989).
    • (1989) Protectionism
    • Bhagwati, J.1
  • 21
    • 0003412313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Oxford University Press
    • See Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History: Myth and Paradoxes (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993); Jagdish Bhagwati, Protectionism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); Charles Kindleberger, World Economic Primacy 1500-1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996); and Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1989).
    • (1996) World Economic Primacy 1500-1990
    • Kindleberger, C.1
  • 22
    • 0003912925 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • See Paul Bairoch, Economics and World History: Myth and Paradoxes (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993); Jagdish Bhagwati, Protectionism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); Charles Kindleberger, World Economic Primacy 1500-1990 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1996); and Ronald Rogowski, Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1989).
    • (1989) Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic Political Alignments
    • Rogowski, R.1
  • 23
    • 0004225435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Macmillan, [1945]
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1965) Nationalism and After
    • Carr, E.H.1
  • 24
    • 0041118023 scopus 로고
    • Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1972) Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration
    • Deutsch, K.1
  • 25
    • 0002050812 scopus 로고
    • National self-sufficiency
    • ed. Donald Moggridge London: Macmillan
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1983) The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America , vol.21 , pp. 233-246
    • Keynes, J.M.1
  • 26
    • 0041118007 scopus 로고
    • Economic nationalism and internationalism
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1957) Australian Outlook , vol.11 , pp. 3-50
    • Myrdal, G.1
  • 27
    • 0039918725 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Macmillan
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1937) Economic Planning and International Order
    • Robbins, L.1
  • 28
    • 5944233328 scopus 로고
    • London: William Hodge and Company
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1942) International Economic Disintegration
    • Röpke, W.1
  • 29
    • 0039338877 scopus 로고
    • The future of private enterprise in the face of modern socialist tendencies
    • Edward Hallett Carr, Nationalism and After (London: Macmillan, 1965 [1945]); Karl Deutsch, Nationenbildung - Nationalstaat - Integration (Düsseldorf: Bertelsmann Universitätsverlag, 1972); John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," in The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes: Vol. XXI. Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in Britain and North America, ed. Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1983): 233-46; Gunnar Myrdal, "Economic Nationalism and Internationalism," Australian Outlook 11 (1957): 3-50; Lionel Robbins, Economic Planning and International Order (London: Macmillan, 1937); Wilhelm Röpke, International Economic Disintegration (London: William Hodge and Company, 1942); and Joseph Schumpeter, "The Future of Private Enterprise in the Face of Modern Socialist Tendencies," History of Political Economy 7 (1975): 294-8.
    • (1975) History of Political Economy , vol.7 , pp. 294-298
    • Schumpeter, J.1
  • 30
    • 85033894948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This approach, however, cannot replace the analysis of actual structures and processes of the internationalization of trade, production, and investment. Here we try to argue for a particular view on possible interactions between welfare state structures on one hand and systems of foreign economic policy on the other.
  • 32
    • 0002606027 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The impact of the international economy on national policies: An analytical overview
    • ed. Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • See Jeffrey Frieden and Ronald Rogowski, "The Impact of the International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview," in Internationalization and Domestic Politics, ed. Robert O. Keohane and Helen V. Milner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996): 25-47.
    • (1996) Internationalization and Domestic Politics , pp. 25-47
    • Frieden, J.1    Rogowski, R.2
  • 39
    • 0003970946 scopus 로고
    • Of money
    • Chicago: Liberty Press, [1777]: (emphasis added)
    • David Hume, "Of Money," in Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary (Chicago: Liberty Press, 1987 [1777]): 283-4 (emphasis added).
    • (1987) Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary , pp. 283-284
    • Hume, D.1
  • 40
    • 0347491130 scopus 로고
    • Of the balance of trade
    • Chicago: Liberty Press, [1777]: (emphasis added)
    • David Hume, "Of the Balance of Trade," in Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary (Chicago: Liberty Press, 1987 [1777]): 329-30 (emphasis added). This position is echoed in today's discussion about the resistance to globalization. Paul Krugman notes that it is wrong to blame global markets for those economic and social ills usually brought into a causal relationship with it. He points out that the facts unmistakably indicate domestic and particularly political causes (International Herald Tribune [20 February 1997]: 8). See also his Pop Internationalism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996).
    • (1987) Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary , pp. 329-330
    • Hume, D.1
  • 41
    • 0003657242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 20 February
    • David Hume, "Of the Balance of Trade," in Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary (Chicago: Liberty Press, 1987 [1777]): 329-30 (emphasis added). This position is echoed in today's discussion about the resistance to globalization. Paul Krugman notes that it is wrong to blame global markets for those economic and social ills usually brought into a causal relationship with it. He points out that the facts unmistakably indicate domestic and particularly political causes (International Herald Tribune [20 February 1997]: 8). See also his Pop Internationalism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996).
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 8
  • 42
    • 0004140636 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: MIT Press
    • David Hume, "Of the Balance of Trade," in Essays: Moral, Political, and Literary (Chicago: Liberty Press, 1987 [1777]): 329-30 (emphasis added). This position is echoed in today's discussion about the resistance to globalization. Paul Krugman notes that it is wrong to blame global markets for those economic and social ills usually brought into a causal relationship with it. He points out that the facts unmistakably indicate domestic and particularly political causes (International Herald Tribune [20 February 1997]: 8). See also his Pop Internationalism (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996).
    • (1996) Pop Internationalism
  • 43
    • 0038743847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is especially true for the United States. See Irwin, Against the Tide, 160; and Alfred E. Eckes, Opening Up America's Market: U.S. Foreign Trade Policy Since 1776 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1995).
    • Against the Tide , pp. 160
    • Irwin1
  • 45
    • 0003657242 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • in an article published 25 February
    • For a return of this argument see William Greider in an article published in the International Herald Tribune (25 February 1997: 9). He argues that those people are right who no longer believe in the beneficial logic of comparative advantage and who now think that economic globalization is a zero-sum game producing losses and insecurity. For the counterargument see Paul Krugman: Economic growth in low-wage nations is in principle as likely to raise as to lower per capita income in high-wage countries; the actual effects have been negligible. In theory, there are some reasons for concern about the impact of Third World competition on the distribution (as opposed to the level) of income in the West.... (Pop Internationalism, 51f.) For a more detailed analysis see Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences," in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press): 327-77. For a broadly based comparative analysis of the consequences of global competition for employment and wages, see Adrian Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994); and for an economic evaluation of the relative importance of technological development versus international competition see Jagdish Bhagwati and Marvin H. Kosters, eds., Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down? (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1994).
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 9
    • Greider, W.1
  • 46
    • 0039057287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a return of this argument see William Greider in an article published in the International Herald Tribune (25 February 1997: 9). He argues that those people are right who no longer believe in the beneficial logic of comparative advantage and who now think that economic globalization is a zero-sum game producing losses and insecurity. For the counterargument see Paul Krugman: Economic growth in low-wage nations is in principle as likely to raise as to lower per capita income in high-wage countries; the actual effects have been negligible. In theory, there are some reasons for concern about the impact of Third World competition on the distribution (as opposed to the level) of income in the West.... (Pop Internationalism, 51f.) For a more detailed analysis see Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences," in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press): 327-77. For a broadly based comparative analysis of the consequences of global competition for employment and wages, see Adrian Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994); and for an economic evaluation of the relative importance of technological development versus international competition see Jagdish Bhagwati and Marvin H. Kosters, eds., Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down? (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1994).
    • Pop Internationalism
  • 47
    • 0008147295 scopus 로고
    • Growing world trade: Causes and consequences
    • Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press
    • For a return of this argument see William Greider in an article published in the International Herald Tribune (25 February 1997: 9). He argues that those people are right who no longer believe in the beneficial logic of comparative advantage and who now think that economic globalization is a zero-sum game producing losses and insecurity. For the counterargument see Paul Krugman: Economic growth in low-wage nations is in principle as likely to raise as to lower per capita income in high-wage countries; the actual effects have been negligible. In theory, there are some reasons for concern about the impact of Third World competition on the distribution (as opposed to the level) of income in the West.... (Pop Internationalism, 51f.) For a more detailed analysis see Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences," in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press): 327-77. For a broadly based comparative analysis of the consequences of global competition for employment and wages, see Adrian Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994); and for an economic evaluation of the relative importance of technological development versus international competition see Jagdish Bhagwati and Marvin H. Kosters, eds., Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down? (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1994).
    • (1995) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , pp. 327-377
    • Krugman1
  • 48
    • 0003832351 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • For a return of this argument see William Greider in an article published in the International Herald Tribune (25 February 1997: 9). He argues that those people are right who no longer believe in the beneficial logic of comparative advantage and who now think that economic globalization is a zero-sum game producing losses and insecurity. For the counterargument see Paul Krugman: Economic growth in low-wage nations is in principle as likely to raise as to lower per capita income in high-wage countries; the actual effects have been negligible. In theory, there are some reasons for concern about the impact of Third World competition on the distribution (as opposed to the level) of income in the West.... (Pop Internationalism, 51f.) For a more detailed analysis see Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences," in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press): 327-77. For a broadly based comparative analysis of the consequences of global competition for employment and wages, see Adrian Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994); and for an economic evaluation of the relative importance of technological development versus international competition see Jagdish Bhagwati and Marvin H. Kosters, eds., Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down? (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1994).
    • (1994) North-south Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-driven World
    • Wood, A.1
  • 49
    • 0003404608 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: AEI Press
    • For a return of this argument see William Greider in an article published in the International Herald Tribune (25 February 1997: 9). He argues that those people are right who no longer believe in the beneficial logic of comparative advantage and who now think that economic globalization is a zero-sum game producing losses and insecurity. For the counterargument see Paul Krugman: Economic growth in low-wage nations is in principle as likely to raise as to lower per capita income in high-wage countries; the actual effects have been negligible. In theory, there are some reasons for concern about the impact of Third World competition on the distribution (as opposed to the level) of income in the West.... (Pop Internationalism, 51f.) For a more detailed analysis see Krugman, "Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences," in Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995 (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press): 327-77. For a broadly based comparative analysis of the consequences of global competition for employment and wages, see Adrian Wood, North-South Trade, Employment and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a Skill-Driven World (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994); and for an economic evaluation of the relative importance of technological development versus international competition see Jagdish Bhagwati and Marvin H. Kosters, eds., Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down? (Washington, DC: AEI Press, 1994).
    • (1994) Trade and Wages: Levelling Wages Down?
    • Bhagwati, J.1    Kosters, M.H.2
  • 51
    • 0003505817 scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press
    • In the context of his 1992 presidential campaign against Bill Clinton in the United States, Ross Perot argued against joining NAFTA, coining the slogan of the "great sucking sound" to describe the United States's loss of jobs to Mexico that he predicted would result from ratification of NAFTA; he was able to draw a substantial segment of protectionist voters to his candidacy. On the role of "social dumping" in the European integration context see Stephan Leibfried and Paul Pierson, eds., European Social Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 1995).
    • (1995) European Social Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration
    • Leibfried, S.1    Pierson, P.2
  • 52
    • 0002200948 scopus 로고
    • Berlin: Walter de Gruyter
    • Weber was not alone in this judgment, but clearly within the mainstream of political economical thought of the time. See Hans Rosenberg, Große Depression und Bismarckzeit (Berlin: Walter de Gruyter, 1967): 78-82, 187-91.
    • (1967) Große Depression und Bismarckzeit , pp. 78-82
    • Rosenberg, H.1
  • 54
    • 0004295760 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harper and Row
    • Joseph Schumpeter expressed this best in a speech given in 1949: The best method of satisfying ourselves as to how far this process of disintegration of capitalist society has gone is to observe the extent to which its implications are being taken for granted both by the business class itself and by the large number of economists who feel themselves to be opposed to (one hundred percent) socialism and are in the habit of denying the existence of any tendency toward it. To speak of the latter only, they accept not only unquestioningly but also approvingly : (1) the various stabilization policies which are to prevent recessions or at least depressions, that is, a large amount of public management of business situations even if not the principle of full employment; (2) the "desirability of greater equality of incomes," rarely defining how far short of absolute equality they are prepared to go, and in connection with this the principle of redistributive taxation; (3) a rich assortment of regulative measures, frequently rationalized by antitrust slogans, as regard prices; (4) public control, though within a wide range of variation, over the labor and the money market; (5) indefinite extension of the sphere of wants that are, now or eventually, to be satisfied by public enterprise, either gratis or on some post-office principle; and (6) of course all types of security legislation. (Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy [New York: Harper and Row, 1950]: 418)
    • (1950) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy , pp. 418
    • Schumpeter, J.1
  • 61
    • 0040523902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," 236. The article was published in 1933 in England (The New Statesman) and in the United States (The Yale Review). Keynes began the article as follows: "I was brought up, like most Englishmen, to respect free trade not only as an economic doctrine which a rational and an instructed person could not doubt but almost as a part of the moral law. I regarded departures from it as being at the same time an imbecility and an outrage" (233).
    • National Self-sufficiency , pp. 236
    • Keynes, J.M.1
  • 62
    • 0039931099 scopus 로고
    • in England
    • John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," 236. The article was published in 1933 in England (The New Statesman) and in the United States (The Yale Review). Keynes began the article as follows: "I was brought up, like most Englishmen, to respect free trade not only as an economic doctrine which a rational and an instructed person could not doubt but almost as a part of the moral law. I regarded departures from it as being at the same time an imbecility and an outrage" (233).
    • (1933) The New Statesman
  • 63
    • 84940026628 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • John Maynard Keynes, "National Self-Sufficiency," 236. The article was published in 1933 in England (The New Statesman) and in the United States (The Yale Review). Keynes began the article as follows: "I was brought up, like most Englishmen, to respect free trade not only as an economic doctrine which a rational and an instructed person could not doubt but almost as a part of the moral law. I regarded departures from it as being at the same time an imbecility and an outrage" (233).
    • The Yale Review
  • 65
    • 0041117998 scopus 로고
    • London: George Routledge & Sons
    • For a study of the nationalization of the socialist workers' movement - earlier international in orientation because of its marginalization in national politics - see Franz Borkenau, Socialism, National or International (London: George Routledge & Sons, 1942).
    • (1942) Socialism, National or International
    • Borkenau, F.1
  • 67
    • 0004225435 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carr, Nationalism and After, 22; and Alan Dowty, Closed Borders: The Contemporary Assault on Freedom of Movement (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1987). The political history of U.S. immigration shows that early democratization and parliamentarization led to an early foreign economic policy focused on regulating labor markets by means of immigration control. See Maldwyn Allen Jones, American Immigration (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2d ed., 1982).
    • Nationalism and After , pp. 22
    • Carr1
  • 68
    • 84884111639 scopus 로고
    • New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
    • See Carr, Nationalism and After, 22; and Alan Dowty, Closed Borders: The Contemporary Assault on Freedom of Movement (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1987). The political history of U.S. immigration shows that early democratization and parliamentarization led to an early foreign economic policy focused on regulating labor markets by means of immigration control. See Maldwyn Allen Jones, American Immigration (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2d ed., 1982).
    • (1987) Closed Borders: The Contemporary Assault on Freedom of Movement
    • Dowty, A.1
  • 69
    • 0003774027 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2d ed.
    • See Carr, Nationalism and After, 22; and Alan Dowty, Closed Borders: The Contemporary Assault on Freedom of Movement (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1987). The political history of U.S. immigration shows that early democratization and parliamentarization led to an early foreign economic policy focused on regulating labor markets by means of immigration control. See Maldwyn Allen Jones, American Immigration (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2d ed., 1982).
    • (1982) American Immigration
    • Jones, M.A.1
  • 72
    • 85033885634 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We do not claim that the politics leading to the expansion of the welfare state after World War II can be explained in terms of conscious decisions to provide for an institutional foundation for a closer integration of world markets. We believe that the relationship between social policies and foreign economic policies is much more fruitfully analyzed in terms of unintended consequences.
  • 74
    • 0003710133 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • The same argument of a positive function of institutionally differentiated social policies for a turn toward free trade was advanced by Warner M. Corden in his analysis of the social origins of protectionism: The point is simply that intervention in trade may not be the best way of dealing with the various problems mentioned since they are all essentially caused by "domestic distortions" rather than "trade distortions." The best way may be to deal with them in some direct "first-best" way, and at the same time to allow trade to flow freely. (Trade Policy and Economic Welfare [Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1974]: 4)
    • (1974) Trade Policy and Economic Welfare , pp. 4
    • Corden, W.M.1
  • 75
    • 0039338879 scopus 로고
    • Risiko als produktionsfaktor
    • See Hans-Werner Sinn, "Risiko als Produktionsfaktor," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 201 (1986): 557-71; and idem., Social Insurance, Incentives and Risk Taking (München: Center for Economic Studies, 1996, Working Papers no. 102).
    • (1986) Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik , vol.201 , pp. 557-571
    • Sinn, H.-W.1
  • 76
    • 0039931078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • München: Center for Economic Studies, Working Papers no. 102
    • See Hans-Werner Sinn, "Risiko als Produktionsfaktor," Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 201 (1986): 557-71; and idem., Social Insurance, Incentives and Risk Taking (München: Center for Economic Studies, 1996, Working Papers no. 102).
    • (1996) Social Insurance, Incentives and Risk Taking
    • Sinn, H.-W.1
  • 78
    • 84973959798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 5537
    • A quantitative study of state expenditures in 100 countries showed a general connection between economic openness and the size of the state budget: Contrary to what most economists would expect, the scope of government has been larger, not smaller, in economies taking greater advantage of world markets. Indeed, governments have expanded fastest in the most open economies. The evidence considered here suggests strongly that the reasons have to do with the risks of being exposed to shocks of external origin. Openness exerts the strongest influence on government consumption in economies which are subject to the greatest amounts of terms-of-trade risk. Governments appear to have sought to mitigate the exposure to external risk by increasing the share of domestic output which they consume. Of course, on a priori grounds, it is not altogether clear that a higher share of government consumption can stabilize incomes. But I have provided some evidence that the government sector can indeed be considered as the "safe" sector - in the empirically relevant sense - for the vast majority of countries. (Dani Rodrik, Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments? [Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996, Working Paper 5537]: 26) Also see idem., Has Globalization Gone Too Far? (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997). For similar evidence based on quantitative analysis see David Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61.
    • (1996) Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments? , pp. 26
    • Rodrik, D.1
  • 79
    • 84973959798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics
    • A quantitative study of state expenditures in 100 countries showed a general connection between economic openness and the size of the state budget: Contrary to what most economists would expect, the scope of government has been larger, not smaller, in economies taking greater advantage of world markets. Indeed, governments have expanded fastest in the most open economies. The evidence considered here suggests strongly that the reasons have to do with the risks of being exposed to shocks of external origin. Openness exerts the strongest influence on government consumption in economies which are subject to the greatest amounts of terms-of-trade risk. Governments appear to have sought to mitigate the exposure to external risk by increasing the share of domestic output which they consume. Of course, on a priori grounds, it is not altogether clear that a higher share of government consumption can stabilize incomes. But I have provided some evidence that the government sector can indeed be considered as the "safe" sector - in the empirically relevant sense - for the vast majority of countries. (Dani Rodrik, Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments? [Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996, Working Paper 5537]: 26) Also see idem., Has Globalization Gone Too Far? (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997). For similar evidence based on quantitative analysis see David Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61.
    • (1997) Has Globalization Gone Too Far?
    • Rodrik, D.1
  • 80
    • 84973959798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis
    • A quantitative study of state expenditures in 100 countries showed a general connection between economic openness and the size of the state budget: Contrary to what most economists would expect, the scope of government has been larger, not smaller, in economies taking greater advantage of world markets. Indeed, governments have expanded fastest in the most open economies. The evidence considered here suggests strongly that the reasons have to do with the risks of being exposed to shocks of external origin. Openness exerts the strongest influence on government consumption in economies which are subject to the greatest amounts of terms-of-trade risk. Governments appear to have sought to mitigate the exposure to external risk by increasing the share of domestic output which they consume. Of course, on a priori grounds, it is not altogether clear that a higher share of government consumption can stabilize incomes. But I have provided some evidence that the government sector can indeed be considered as the "safe" sector - in the empirically relevant sense - for the vast majority of countries. (Dani Rodrik, Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments? [Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1996, Working Paper 5537]: 26) Also see idem., Has Globalization Gone Too Far? (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1997). For similar evidence based on quantitative analysis see David Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61.
    • (1978) American Political Science Review , vol.72 , pp. 1243-1261
    • Cameron, D.1
  • 83
    • 84906461350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • Against the Tide , pp. 183
  • 84
    • 0000310992 scopus 로고
    • Welfare propositions of economics and interpersonal comparisons of utility
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1939) Economic Journal , vol.49 , pp. 549-552
    • Kaldor, N.1
  • 85
    • 0000954276 scopus 로고
    • A note on tariffs and terms of trade
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1940) Economica , vol.1 , pp. 377-380
    • Kaldor, N.1
  • 86
    • 0000082519 scopus 로고
    • The foundations of welfare economics
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1939) Economic Journal , vol.49 , pp. 696-712
    • Hicks, J.R.1
  • 87
    • 0000176110 scopus 로고
    • The valuation of social income
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1940) Economica , vol.7 , pp. 105-124
    • Kaldor, N.1
  • 88
    • 84963090940 scopus 로고
    • A note on welfare propositions in economics
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1941) Review of Economic Studies , vol.9 , pp. 77-88
    • De Scitovsky, T.1
  • 89
    • 0038743847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • Against the Tide , pp. 180-188
    • Irwin1
  • 90
    • 0039931049 scopus 로고
    • Compensation principle
    • London: Macmillan
    • Ibid., 183. This attempt at a Pareto-optimal solution to the distribution problems, which resulted from repealing the tariffs, was refined and formalized in welfare economics by Nicholas Kaldor, "Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 549-52; idem., "A Note on Tariffs and Terms of Trade," Economica 1 (1940): 377-80; and John R. Hicks, "The Foundations of Welfare Economics," Economic Journal 49 (1939): 696-712 and idem., "The Valuation of Social Income," Economica 7 (1940): 105-24. Tibor de Scitovsky criticized these works, since he saw Pareto-optimal solutions via the compensation of losers by the winners as a two-edged sword. After all, why shouldn't the beneficiaries of tariffs compensate the potential beneficiaries of free trade (the "losers" of tariff protection)? See "A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics," Review of Economic Studies 9 (1941): 77-88. For an overview see Irwin, Against the Tide: 180-8; and on compensation strategies in economic theory see John S. Chipman, "Compensation Principle," in The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics (London: Macmillan, 1988): 524-31.
    • (1988) The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics , pp. 524-531
    • Chipman, J.S.1
  • 91
    • 0002973932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Institutions and economic growth after World War II
    • eds. Nicholas Crafts and Gianni Toniolo Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • On the economic-historical context of this "Golden Age" and on the labor and social policy components of the social compact formulated in the 1950s, see Barry Eichengreen, "Institutions and Economic Growth after World War II," in Economic Growth Since 1945, eds. Nicholas Crafts and Gianni Toniolo (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996): 38-72.
    • (1996) Economic Growth Since 1945 , pp. 38-72
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 94
    • 0003717058 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • For a corresponding study of U.K. and U.S. social policy developments in the 1980s, see Paul Pierson, Dismantling the Welfare State ? Reagan, Thatcher and the Politics of Retrenchment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994). For an extension of this analysis to additional countries see idem., "The New Politics of the Welfare State," World Politics 48 (1996): 147-79.
    • (1994) Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan, Thatcher and the Politics of Retrenchment
    • Pierson, P.1
  • 95
    • 0029753187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The new politics of the welfare state
    • For a corresponding study of U.K. and U.S. social policy developments in the 1980s, see Paul Pierson, Dismantling the Welfare State ? Reagan, Thatcher and the Politics of Retrenchment (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994). For an extension of this analysis to additional countries see idem., "The New Politics of the Welfare State," World Politics 48 (1996): 147-79.
    • (1996) World Politics , vol.48 , pp. 147-179
    • Pierson, P.1
  • 96
    • 0007391039 scopus 로고
    • Frankfurt: Campus
    • See Jens Alber, Der Sozialstaat in der Bundesrepublik 1950-1983 (Frankfurt: Campus, 1989); Morris Janowitz, Social Control of the Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976); and M. Rainer Lepsius, "Soziale Ungleichheit und Klassenstrukturen in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland," in Klassen in der europäischen Sozialgeschichte, ed. Hans-Ulrich Wehler (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1979): 166-209.
    • (1989) Der Sozialstaat in der Bundesrepublik 1950-1983
    • Alber, J.1
  • 97
    • 0004082768 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • See Jens Alber, Der Sozialstaat in der Bundesrepublik 1950-1983 (Frankfurt: Campus, 1989); Morris Janowitz, Social Control of the Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976); and M. Rainer Lepsius, "Soziale Ungleichheit und Klassenstrukturen in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland," in Klassen in der europäischen Sozialgeschichte, ed. Hans-Ulrich Wehler (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1979): 166-209.
    • (1976) Social Control of the Welfare State
    • Janowitz, M.1
  • 98
    • 0009139082 scopus 로고
    • Soziale ungleichheit und klassenstrukturen in der bundesrepublik Deutschland
    • ed. Hans-Ulrich Wehler Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht
    • See Jens Alber, Der Sozialstaat in der Bundesrepublik 1950-1983 (Frankfurt: Campus, 1989); Morris Janowitz, Social Control of the Welfare State (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1976); and M. Rainer Lepsius, "Soziale Ungleichheit und Klassenstrukturen in der Bundesrepublik Deutschland," in Klassen in der europäischen Sozialgeschichte, ed. Hans-Ulrich Wehler (Göttingen: Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, 1979): 166-209.
    • (1979) Klassen in der Europäischen Sozialgeschichte , pp. 166-209
    • Lepsius, M.R.1
  • 99
    • 26444507727 scopus 로고
    • From industrial to postindustrial welfare state?
    • Tokyo: University of Tokyo, Institute of Social Science [Special Issue of the Annals of the Institute of Social Science]
    • For empirical evidence see Peter Flora, "From Industrial to Postindustrial Welfare State?" in The Advanced Industrial Societies in Disarray: What Are the Available Choices? (Tokyo: University of Tokyo, Institute of Social Science [Special Issue of the Annals of the Institute of Social Science], 1989): 149-62.
    • (1989) The Advanced Industrial Societies in Disarray: What are the Available Choices? , pp. 149-162
    • Flora, P.1
  • 100
    • 0041117920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Beschäftigungswunder Niederlande? Ein vergleich der beschäftigungssysteme in den Niederlanden und in Deutschland
    • See Günther Schmid, "Beschäftigungswunder Niederlande? Ein Vergleich der Beschäftigungssysteme in den Niederlanden und in Deutschland," Leviathan 25 (1997): 302-37;
    • (1997) Leviathan , vol.25 , pp. 302-337
    • Schmid, G.1
  • 102
    • 0040523817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fiskalische disziplin und institutionelle budgetkoordinierung: Internationale erfahrungen und ihre bedeutung für die Europäische union
    • eds. Thomas König, Elmar Rieger, and Hermann Schmitt Frankfurt: Campus
    • Between 1981 and 1996, the average quotient of government outlays on all levels to the nominal domestic product rose from 47 to 49 percent, while state debt - the quotient of gross obligations of all levels of government to gross domestic product - climbed from 44 to 76 percent. See Paul Bernd Spahn and Wolfgang Föttinger, "Fiskalische Disziplin und institutionelle Budgetkoordinierung: Internationale Erfahrungen und ihre Bedeutung für die Europäische Union," in Europäische Institutionenpolitik, eds. Thomas König, Elmar Rieger, and Hermann Schmitt (Frankfurt: Campus, 1997): 140-59.
    • (1997) Europäische Institutionenpolitik , pp. 140-159
    • Spahn, P.B.1    Föttinger, W.2
  • 103
    • 0040523814 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Occupational careers under different welfare regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden
    • eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker Bristol: Policy Press
    • Jutta Allmendinger and Thomas Hinz, "Occupational Careers Under Different Welfare Regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden," in The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare, eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker (Bristol: Policy Press, 1998): 61-82; Karl-Ulrich Mayer and Walter Müller, "The State and the Structure of the Life Course," in Human Development and the life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives, eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod (Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1986): 217-45; idem., "Lebensverläufe im Wohlfahrtsstaat," in Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne, ed. Ansgar Weymann (Stuttgart: Enke, 1989): 41-60; Assar Lindbeck, "Consequences of the Advanced Welfare State," World Economy 11 (1988): 19-37; and idem., "Welfare State Disincentives with Endogenous Habits and Norms," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (1995): 477-94.
    • (1998) The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare , pp. 61-82
    • Allmendinger, J.1    Hinz, T.2
  • 104
    • 0002036642 scopus 로고
    • The state and the structure of the life course
    • eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe
    • Jutta Allmendinger and Thomas Hinz, "Occupational Careers Under Different Welfare Regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden," in The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare, eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker (Bristol: Policy Press, 1998): 61-82; Karl-Ulrich Mayer and Walter Müller, "The State and the Structure of the Life Course," in Human Development and the life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives, eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod (Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1986): 217-45; idem., "Lebensverläufe im Wohlfahrtsstaat," in Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne, ed. Ansgar Weymann (Stuttgart: Enke, 1989): 41-60; Assar Lindbeck, "Consequences of the Advanced Welfare State," World Economy 11 (1988): 19-37; and idem., "Welfare State Disincentives with Endogenous Habits and Norms," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (1995): 477-94.
    • (1986) Human Development and the Life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives , pp. 217-245
    • Mayer, K.-U.1    Müller, W.2
  • 105
    • 11744276264 scopus 로고
    • Lebensverläufe im wohlfahrtsstaat
    • ed. Ansgar Weymann Stuttgart: Enke
    • Jutta Allmendinger and Thomas Hinz, "Occupational Careers Under Different Welfare Regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden," in The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare, eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker (Bristol: Policy Press, 1998): 61-82; Karl-Ulrich Mayer and Walter Müller, "The State and the Structure of the Life Course," in Human Development and the life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives, eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod (Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1986): 217-45; idem., "Lebensverläufe im Wohlfahrtsstaat," in Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne, ed. Ansgar Weymann (Stuttgart: Enke, 1989): 41-60; Assar Lindbeck, "Consequences of the Advanced Welfare State," World Economy 11 (1988): 19-37; and idem., "Welfare State Disincentives with Endogenous Habits and Norms," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (1995): 477-94.
    • (1989) Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne , pp. 41-60
    • Mayer, K.-U.1    Müller, W.2
  • 106
    • 84982732300 scopus 로고
    • Consequences of the advanced welfare state
    • Jutta Allmendinger and Thomas Hinz, "Occupational Careers Under Different Welfare Regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden," in The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare, eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker (Bristol: Policy Press, 1998): 61-82; Karl-Ulrich Mayer and Walter Müller, "The State and the Structure of the Life Course," in Human Development and the life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives, eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod (Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1986): 217-45; idem., "Lebensverläufe im Wohlfahrtsstaat," in Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne, ed. Ansgar Weymann (Stuttgart: Enke, 1989): 41-60; Assar Lindbeck, "Consequences of the Advanced Welfare State," World Economy 11 (1988): 19-37; and idem., "Welfare State Disincentives with Endogenous Habits and Norms," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (1995): 477-94.
    • (1988) World Economy , vol.11 , pp. 19-37
    • Lindbeck, A.1
  • 107
    • 21844491146 scopus 로고
    • Welfare state disincentives with endogenous habits and norms
    • Jutta Allmendinger and Thomas Hinz, "Occupational Careers Under Different Welfare Regimes: West Germany, Great Britain and Sweden," in The Dynamics of Modern Society: Poverty, Policy and Welfare, eds. Lutz Leisering and Robert Walker (Bristol: Policy Press, 1998): 61-82; Karl-Ulrich Mayer and Walter Müller, "The State and the Structure of the Life Course," in Human Development and the life Course: Multidisciplinary Perspectives, eds. Aage B. Sorensen, Franz L. Weinert, and L. R. Sherrod (Hillsdale, NJ: M. E. Sharpe, 1986): 217-45; idem., "Lebensverläufe im Wohlfahrtsstaat," in Handlungsspielräume: Untersuchungen zur Individualisierung und Institutionalisierung von Lebensverläufen in der Moderne, ed. Ansgar Weymann (Stuttgart: Enke, 1989): 41-60; Assar Lindbeck, "Consequences of the Advanced Welfare State," World Economy 11 (1988): 19-37; and idem., "Welfare State Disincentives with Endogenous Habits and Norms," Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97 (1995): 477-94.
    • (1995) Scandinavian Journal of Economics , vol.97 , pp. 477-494
    • Lindbeck, A.1
  • 108
    • 0038837156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik
    • On the United States see Thomas Gebhardt, Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996 (Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997); Martin Seeleib-Kaiser, "Sozialpolitik nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts," in Das amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts, eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg (Paderborn: Schöningh, 1996): 239-68; and Michael Wiseman, "Welfare Reform in the United States: A Background Paper," Housing Policy Debate 7 (1996): 1-54. On the contrasting German case, see Herbert Jacobs, Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993 (Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997). In Germany, a "leaning" of the welfare state is discernible with means-and income-tested benefits. Germany's 1996 introduction of old-age nursing-care insurance, however, indicates how well entrenched the welfare state is, since this policy did not consider the imperatives of integration in the global market for German industry. On the failure of the United States's 1995 health insurance reform, proposed as a strategy to expand the welfare state, see Jacob Hacker, The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1997) Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996
    • Gebhardt, T.1
  • 109
    • 0040022097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sozialpolitik nach dem ende des ost-west-konflikts
    • eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg Paderborn: Schöningh
    • On the United States see Thomas Gebhardt, Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996 (Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997); Martin Seeleib-Kaiser, "Sozialpolitik nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts," in Das amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts, eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg (Paderborn: Schöningh, 1996): 239-68; and Michael Wiseman, "Welfare Reform in the United States: A Background Paper," Housing Policy Debate 7 (1996): 1-54. On the contrasting German case, see Herbert Jacobs, Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993 (Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997). In Germany, a "leaning" of the welfare state is discernible with means-and income-tested benefits. Germany's 1996 introduction of old-age nursing-care insurance, however, indicates how well entrenched the welfare state is, since this policy did not consider the imperatives of integration in the global market for German industry. On the failure of the United States's 1995 health insurance reform, proposed as a strategy to expand the welfare state, see Jacob Hacker, The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1996) Das Amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten Nach dem Ende des Ost-west-konflikts , pp. 239-268
    • Seeleib-Kaiser, M.1
  • 110
    • 0040523815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Welfare reform in the United States: A background paper
    • On the United States see Thomas Gebhardt, Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996 (Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997); Martin Seeleib-Kaiser, "Sozialpolitik nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts," in Das amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts, eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg (Paderborn: Schöningh, 1996): 239-68; and Michael Wiseman, "Welfare Reform in the United States: A Background Paper," Housing Policy Debate 7 (1996): 1-54. On the contrasting German case, see Herbert Jacobs, Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993 (Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997). In Germany, a "leaning" of the welfare state is discernible with means-and income-tested benefits. Germany's 1996 introduction of old-age nursing-care insurance, however, indicates how well entrenched the welfare state is, since this policy did not consider the imperatives of integration in the global market for German industry. On the failure of the United States's 1995 health insurance reform, proposed as a strategy to expand the welfare state, see Jacob Hacker, The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1996) Housing Policy Debate , vol.7 , pp. 1-54
    • Wiseman, M.1
  • 111
    • 85033901815 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik
    • On the United States see Thomas Gebhardt, Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996 (Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997); Martin Seeleib-Kaiser, "Sozialpolitik nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts," in Das amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts, eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg (Paderborn: Schöningh, 1996): 239-68; and Michael Wiseman, "Welfare Reform in the United States: A Background Paper," Housing Policy Debate 7 (1996): 1-54. On the contrasting German case, see Herbert Jacobs, Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993 (Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997). In Germany, a "leaning" of the welfare state is discernible with means-and income-tested benefits. Germany's 1996 introduction of old-age nursing-care insurance, however, indicates how well entrenched the welfare state is, since this policy did not consider the imperatives of integration in the global market for German industry. On the failure of the United States's 1995 health insurance reform, proposed as a strategy to expand the welfare state, see Jacob Hacker, The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1997) Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993
    • Jacobs, H.1
  • 112
    • 0004001504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • On the United States see Thomas Gebhardt, Ending Welfare as We Know It: Die US-amerikanische Sozialhilfereform 1993-1996 (Bremen: Universität Bremen, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997); Martin Seeleib-Kaiser, "Sozialpolitik nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts," in Das amerikanische Dilemma: Die Vereinigten Staaten nach dem Ende des Ost-West-Konflikts, eds. Herbert Dittgen and Michael Minkenberg (Paderborn: Schöningh, 1996): 239-68; and Michael Wiseman, "Welfare Reform in the United States: A Background Paper," Housing Policy Debate 7 (1996): 1-54. On the contrasting German case, see Herbert Jacobs, Zwischen Mißbrauch und Arbeitspflicht - Die Diskussion um die Sozialhilfe und die Novellierungen des BSHG 1993 (Bremen: Universität, Zentrum für Sozialpolitik, 1997). In Germany, a "leaning" of the welfare state is discernible with means-and income-tested benefits. Germany's 1996 introduction of old-age nursing-care insurance, however, indicates how well entrenched the welfare state is, since this policy did not consider the imperatives of integration in the global market for German industry. On the failure of the United States's 1995 health insurance reform, proposed as a strategy to expand the welfare state, see Jacob Hacker, The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1997).
    • (1997) The Road to Nowhere: The Genesis of President Clinton's Plan for Health Security
    • Hacker, J.1
  • 113
    • 0039931033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Clinton offers workers aid in bid to win trade battle
    • 7 November
    • See John M. Broder, "Clinton Offers Workers Aid in Bid to Win Trade Battle," International Herald Tribune (7 November 1997): 3; William Pfaff, "Don't Forget That Globalization Creates Losers, Too," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 8; Jill Abramson and Steven Greenhouse, 'Trade Bill's Fate Underlines Labor's Muscle," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 3; and Thomas L. Friedman, "Plotting Politics on the New Globalization Graph," International Herald Tribune (14 November 1997): 8.
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 3
    • Broder, J.M.1
  • 114
    • 85033879025 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Don't forget that globalization creates losers, too
    • 13 November
    • See John M. Broder, "Clinton Offers Workers Aid in Bid to Win Trade Battle," International Herald Tribune (7 November 1997): 3; William Pfaff, "Don't Forget That Globalization Creates Losers, Too," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 8; Jill Abramson and Steven Greenhouse, 'Trade Bill's Fate Underlines Labor's Muscle," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 3; and Thomas L. Friedman, "Plotting Politics on the New Globalization Graph," International Herald Tribune (14 November 1997): 8.
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 8
    • Pfaff, W.1
  • 115
    • 85033881591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Trade bill's fate underlines labor's muscle
    • 13 November
    • See John M. Broder, "Clinton Offers Workers Aid in Bid to Win Trade Battle," International Herald Tribune (7 November 1997): 3; William Pfaff, "Don't Forget That Globalization Creates Losers, Too," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 8; Jill Abramson and Steven Greenhouse, 'Trade Bill's Fate Underlines Labor's Muscle," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 3; and Thomas L. Friedman, "Plotting Politics on the New Globalization Graph," International Herald Tribune (14 November 1997): 8.
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 3
    • Abramson, J.1    Greenhouse, S.2
  • 116
    • 85033878979 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Plotting politics on the new globalization graph
    • 14 November
    • See John M. Broder, "Clinton Offers Workers Aid in Bid to Win Trade Battle," International Herald Tribune (7 November 1997): 3; William Pfaff, "Don't Forget That Globalization Creates Losers, Too," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 8; Jill Abramson and Steven Greenhouse, 'Trade Bill's Fate Underlines Labor's Muscle," International Herald Tribune (13 November 1997): 3; and Thomas L. Friedman, "Plotting Politics on the New Globalization Graph," International Herald Tribune (14 November 1997): 8.
    • (1997) International Herald Tribune , pp. 8
    • Friedman, T.L.1
  • 117
    • 0038743847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nassau Senior in 1828, quoted in Irwin, Against the Tide, 93.
    • (1828) Against the Tide , pp. 93
    • Irwin1
  • 118
    • 0003996012 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
    • On the relevant changes in the world currency system as a result of the development of welfare states after World War II, see Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996): 188-91. For a perspective on the linkages between the welfare statism of the post-World War II period and the governance of international economic relations see John Gerard Ruggie, "International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-war Economic Order," International Organization 36 (1982): 379-415; and idem., "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11.
    • (1996) Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System , pp. 188-191
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 119
    • 84971845190 scopus 로고
    • International regimes, transactions and change: Embedded liberalism in the post-war economic order
    • On the relevant changes in the world currency system as a result of the development of welfare states after World War II, see Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996): 188-91. For a perspective on the linkages between the welfare statism of the post-World War II period and the governance of international economic relations see John Gerard Ruggie, "International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-war Economic Order," International Organization 36 (1982): 379-415; and idem., "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11.
    • (1982) International Organization , vol.36 , pp. 379-415
    • Ruggie, J.G.1
  • 120
    • 0006789571 scopus 로고
    • Trade, protectionism and the future of welfare capitalism
    • On the relevant changes in the world currency system as a result of the development of welfare states after World War II, see Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1996): 188-91. For a perspective on the linkages between the welfare statism of the post-World War II period and the governance of international economic relations see John Gerard Ruggie, "International Regimes, Transactions and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Post-war Economic Order," International Organization 36 (1982): 379-415; and idem., "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11.
    • (1994) Journal of International Affairs , vol.48 , pp. 1-11
    • Ruggie, J.G.1
  • 121
    • 0000472188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the problems of fair trade and social clauses in trade policy, see Drusilla K. Brown, Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern, "International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis"; Brian Alexander Langille, "General Reflections on the Relationship of Trade and Labor (Or: Fair Trade Is Free Trade's Destiny)"; and Virginia A. Leary, "Workers' Rights and International Trade: The Social Clause (GATT, ILO; NAFTA, U.S. Laws)" the two last mentioned in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. II. Legal Analysis (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996 Brown et al. is in Vol. I). For a review of this work see Paul Krugman, "What Should Trade Negotiators Negotiate About?," Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1997): 113-20
    • International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis
    • Brown, D.K.1    Deardorff, A.V.2    Stern, R.M.3
  • 122
    • 85033893434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For an overview of the problems of fair trade and social clauses in trade policy, see Drusilla K. Brown, Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern, "International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis"; Brian Alexander Langille, "General Reflections on the Relationship of Trade and Labor (Or: Fair Trade Is Free Trade's Destiny)"; and Virginia A. Leary, "Workers' Rights and International Trade: The Social Clause (GATT, ILO; NAFTA, U.S. Laws)" the two last mentioned in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. II. Legal Analysis (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996 Brown et al. is in Vol. I). For a review of this work see Paul Krugman, "What Should Trade Negotiators Negotiate About?," Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1997): 113-20
    • General Reflections on the Relationship of Trade and Labor (Or: Fair Trade Is Free Trade's Destiny)
    • Langille, B.A.1
  • 123
    • 0345509044 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Workers' rights and international trade: The social clause (GATT, ILO; NAFTA, U.S. Laws)
    • the two last mentioned in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Cambridge: MIT Press, Brown et al. is in Vol. I
    • For an overview of the problems of fair trade and social clauses in trade policy, see Drusilla K. Brown, Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern, "International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis"; Brian Alexander Langille, "General Reflections on the Relationship of Trade and Labor (Or: Fair Trade Is Free Trade's Destiny)"; and Virginia A. Leary, "Workers' Rights and International Trade: The Social Clause (GATT, ILO; NAFTA, U.S. Laws)" the two last mentioned in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. II. Legal Analysis (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996 Brown et al. is in Vol. I). For a review of this work see Paul Krugman, "What Should Trade Negotiators Negotiate About?," Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1997): 113-20
    • (1996) Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. II. Legal Analysis , vol.2
    • Leary, V.A.1
  • 124
    • 0000213344 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What should trade negotiators negotiate about?
    • For an overview of the problems of fair trade and social clauses in trade policy, see Drusilla K. Brown, Alan V. Deardorff, and Robert M. Stern, "International Labor Standards and Trade: A Theoretical Analysis"; Brian Alexander Langille, "General Reflections on the Relationship of Trade and Labor (Or: Fair Trade Is Free Trade's Destiny)"; and Virginia A. Leary, "Workers' Rights and International Trade: The Social Clause (GATT, ILO; NAFTA, U.S. Laws)" the two last mentioned in Jagdish Bhagwati and Robert E. Hudec, eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization: Prerequisites for Free Trade? Vol. II. Legal Analysis (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996 Brown et al. is in Vol. I). For a review of this work see Paul Krugman, "What Should Trade Negotiators Negotiate About?," Journal of Economic Literature 35 (1997): 113-20
    • (1997) Journal of Economic Literature , vol.35 , pp. 113-120
    • Krugman, P.1
  • 125
    • 0041377358 scopus 로고
    • Safeguard policy and the conservative social welfare function
    • ed. Henry Kierzkowski London: Blackwell
    • On the role of safeguard clauses, see Alan V. Deardorff, "Safeguard Policy and the Conservative Social Welfare Function," in Protection and Competition in International Trade: Essays in Honor of W. M. Corden, ed. Henry Kierzkowski (London: Blackwell, 1987): 22-40.
    • (1987) Protection and Competition in International Trade: Essays in Honor of W. M. Corden , pp. 22-40
    • Deardorff, A.V.1
  • 126
    • 0003519168 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: MIT Press
    • On the instruments and general tendency of neoprotectionism, see John Jackson, The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); John Gerard Ruggie, "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11; and Dominick Salvatore, ed., Protectionism and World Welfare (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1993). Max Corden's analysis Trade Policy and Economic Welfare has become a classic in this field.
    • (1989) The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations
    • Jackson, J.1
  • 127
    • 0006789571 scopus 로고
    • Trade, protectionism and the future of welfare capitalism
    • On the instruments and general tendency of neoprotectionism, see John Jackson, The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); John Gerard Ruggie, "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11; and Dominick Salvatore, ed., Protectionism and World Welfare (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1993). Max Corden's analysis Trade Policy and Economic Welfare has become a classic in this field.
    • (1994) Journal of International Affairs , vol.48 , pp. 1-11
    • Ruggie, J.G.1
  • 128
    • 0004228765 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press
    • On the instruments and general tendency of neoprotectionism, see John Jackson, The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); John Gerard Ruggie, "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11; and Dominick Salvatore, ed., Protectionism and World Welfare (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1993). Max Corden's analysis Trade Policy and Economic Welfare has become a classic in this field.
    • (1993) Protectionism and World Welfare
    • Salvatore, D.1
  • 129
    • 84972042851 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • has become a classic in this field
    • On the instruments and general tendency of neoprotectionism, see John Jackson, The World Trading System: Law and Policy of International Economic Relations (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1989); John Gerard Ruggie, "Trade, Protectionism and the Future of Welfare Capitalism," Journal of International Affairs 48 (1994): 1-11; and Dominick Salvatore, ed., Protectionism and World Welfare (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1993). Max Corden's analysis Trade Policy and Economic Welfare has become a classic in this field.
    • Trade Policy and Economic Welfare
    • Corden, M.1
  • 130
    • 0004322011 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For research, the additional problem posed is to contrast the (historical) genesis of the functions of the welfare state for economic openness with their (present-day) role in guaranteeing that openness. The search for substitutive mechanisms has to consider that many instruments of national control over foreign economic policy that were still prevalent in the 1950s and 1960s, such as control of capital mobility and exchange rates, would be much harder to reestablish today. Also, they would be much less effective and politically more risky in their consequences for the investment behavior of enterprises. See Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital; and idem., "Institutions and Economic Growth after World War II."
    • Globalizing Capital
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 131
    • 0002973932 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For research, the additional problem posed is to contrast the (historical) genesis of the functions of the welfare state for economic openness with their (present-day) role in guaranteeing that openness. The search for substitutive mechanisms has to consider that many instruments of national control over foreign economic policy that were still prevalent in the 1950s and 1960s, such as control of capital mobility and exchange rates, would be much harder to reestablish today. Also, they would be much less effective and politically more risky in their consequences for the investment behavior of enterprises. See Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital; and idem., "Institutions and Economic Growth after World War II."
    • Institutions and Economic Growth after World War II
    • Eichengreen, B.1
  • 134
    • 85033897249 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • These characteristics seem to obtain in the United States, the NICs, and Japan
    • These characteristics seem to obtain in the United States, the NICs, and Japan.
  • 135
    • 0002813673 scopus 로고
    • Reinterpreting corporatism and explaining unemployment: Co-ordinated and non-co-ordinated market economies
    • eds. Renato Brunetta and Carlo Dell'Aringa London: Macmillan and International Economic Association
    • This characteristic is especially pronounced in Germany. For a view on the microfoundations of the German socioeconomic system see David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Co-ordinated and Non-co-ordinated Market Economies," in Labour Relations and Economic Performance, eds. Renato Brunetta and Carlo Dell'Aringa (London: Macmillan and International Economic Association, 1990): 170-211. For a skeptical view on the integrative function of the German welfare state see Franz-Xaver Kaufmann, "Schwindet die integrative Funktion des Sozialstaats?" Berliner Journal für Soziologie 7 (1997): 5-19; and his Herausforderungen des Sozialstaates.
    • (1990) Labour Relations and Economic Performance , pp. 170-211
    • Soskice, D.1
  • 136
    • 0038264694 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Schwindet die integrative funktion des sozialstaats?
    • and his Herausforderungen des Sozialstaates
    • This characteristic is especially pronounced in Germany. For a view on the microfoundations of the German socioeconomic system see David Soskice, "Reinterpreting Corporatism and Explaining Unemployment: Co-ordinated and Non-co-ordinated Market Economies," in Labour Relations and Economic Performance, eds. Renato Brunetta and Carlo Dell'Aringa (London: Macmillan and International Economic Association, 1990): 170-211. For a skeptical view on the integrative function of the German welfare state see Franz-Xaver Kaufmann, "Schwindet die integrative Funktion des Sozialstaats?" Berliner Journal für Soziologie 7 (1997): 5-19; and his Herausforderungen des Sozialstaates.
    • (1997) Berliner Journal für Soziologie , vol.7 , pp. 5-19
    • Kaufmann, F.-X.1
  • 137
    • 0031508256 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Economic integration, democracy and the welfare state
    • In the European Union, Germany (contribution-oriented) and Denmark (taxoriented) are usually contrasted. See Fritz J. Scharpf, "Economic Integration, Democracy and the Welfare State," Journal of European Public Policy 4 (1997): 18-36.
    • (1997) Journal of European Public Policy , vol.4 , pp. 18-36
    • Scharpf, F.J.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.