메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 66, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 737-771

Joint ventures: Issues in enforcement policy

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0032348597     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (6)

References (138)
  • 1
    • 84865915892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines for International Operations (1988), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,109 [hereinafter 1988 International Guidelines]
    • U.S. Department of Justice Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines for International Operations (1988), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,109 [hereinafter 1988 International Guidelines].
  • 2
    • 84865909071 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines for International Operations (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,107 [hereinafter 1995 International Guidelines]
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Enforcement Guidelines for International Operations (1995), reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,107 [hereinafter 1995 International Guidelines]; also at 〈http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/ public/guidelines/ipguide.wp5〉.
  • 3
    • 84865916169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995) § 3.4, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132 [hereinafter Intellectual Property Guidelines]
    • See U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995) § 3.4, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132 [hereinafter Intellectual Property Guidelines].
  • 4
    • 0005863296 scopus 로고
    • Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy
    • See Joseph F. Brodley, Joint Ventures and Antitrust Policy, 95 HARV. L. REV. 1521, 1524 (1982).
    • (1982) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.95 , pp. 1521
    • Brodley, J.F.1
  • 6
    • 0042655061 scopus 로고
    • Joint Ventures under the Antitrust Laws: Some Reflections on the Significance of Penn-Olin
    • See Brodley, supra note 4, at 1524-25
    • See Brodley, supra note 4, at 1524-25; Robert Pitofsky, Joint Ventures Under the Antitrust Laws: Some Reflections on the Significance of Penn-Olin, 82 HARV. L. REV. 1007, 1007 (1969); PHILLIP AREEDA & LOUIS KAPLOW, ANTITRUST ANALYSIS 270 (4th ed. 1988).
    • (1969) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 1007
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 7
    • 0004316299 scopus 로고
    • 4th ed.
    • See Brodley, supra note 4, at 1524-25; Robert Pitofsky, Joint Ventures Under the Antitrust Laws: Some Reflections on the Significance of Penn-Olin, 82 HARV. L. REV. 1007, 1007 (1969); PHILLIP AREEDA & LOUIS KAPLOW, ANTITRUST ANALYSIS 270 (4th ed. 1988).
    • (1988) Antitrust Analysis , pp. 270
    • Areeda, P.1    Kaplow, L.2
  • 8
    • 84865908608 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Statement of Joseph Kattan Before FTC 2-3 June 5
    • Even firms in a vertical relationship can be said to have created a joint venture when they work closely in developing specifications for products to be sold by one to the other. See Statement of Joseph Kattan Before FTC 2-3 (June 5, 1997), available at 〈http:// www.ftc.gov/opp/jointvent/june5.htm〉.
    • (1997)
  • 9
    • 18944366315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If the parties take a sufficient equity interest in each other, they would be viewed as having become a single economic actor. See Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752 (1984) (parent and wholly owned subsidiary should be treated as single actor). Even if the participants to a joint venture remain independent companies, some courts treat joint ventures as single actors if they appear to have organized themselves so as to pursue common, rather than divergent, interests. See, e.g., Siegel Transfer, Inc. v. Carrier Express, Inc., 54 F.3d 1125, 1127 (3d Cir. 1995); City of Mt. Pleasant, v. Associated Elec. Coop., 838 F.2d 268, 276-77 (8th Cir. 1988).
  • 10
    • 18944402403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • As some have suggested, it might be more helpful to use the phrase "competitor collaboration policy."
  • 11
    • 18944377114 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Cases with extensive discussions of the relationship between the per se rule and the rule of reason include National Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978); Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979); NCAA v. Board of Regents of the Univ. of Okla., 468 U.S. 85 (1984); and FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447 (1986).
  • 12
    • 18944396058 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Massachusetts Bd. of Registration in Optometry, 110 F.T.C. 549 (1988); 1988 FTC LEXIS 34
    • Massachusetts Bd. of Registration in Optometry, 110 F.T.C. 549 (1988); 1988 FTC LEXIS 34.
  • 13
    • 18944405393 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • FTC v. California Dental Ass'n, 1996 FTC LEXIS 88; aff'd, 129 F.3d 720 (9th Cir. 1997)
    • FTC v. California Dental Ass'n, 1996 FTC LEXIS 88; aff'd, 129 F.3d 720 (9th Cir. 1997).
  • 15
    • 84865908609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 3.41
    • § 3.41.
  • 16
    • 84865909085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • § 3.4
    • § 3.4.
  • 17
    • 84865909081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care (1996) [hereinafter Health Care Statements], reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. ¶ 13,153
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission, Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care (1996) [hereinafter Health Care Statements], reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. ¶ 13,153; also available at 〈http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/guidelines/hcqdln96.wp5〉. The Health Care Statements are intended to treat health care joint ventures no more strictly or more leniently than joint ventures in other industries. Id. at 20,800.
  • 18
    • 84865916183 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress itself mandated a form of rule of reason for certain joint ventures in the National Cooperative Research and Production Act. 15 U.S.C. §§ 4301-4305
    • Congress itself mandated a form of rule of reason for certain joint ventures in the National Cooperative Research and Production Act. 15 U.S.C. §§ 4301-4305.
  • 19
    • 18944383003 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The per se rule on boycotts now appears limited to boycotts of customers or suppliers, intended to drive competitors of the boycotters out of the market. See, e.g., FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458 (1986); Fashion Originators' Guild of Am., Inc. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 447 (1941); Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers' Ass'n v. United States, 234 U.S. 600 (1914)
    • The per se rule on boycotts now appears limited to boycotts of customers or suppliers, intended to drive competitors of the boycotters out of the market. See, e.g., FTC v. Indiana Fed'n of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458 (1986); Fashion Originators' Guild of Am., Inc. v. FTC, 312 U.S. 447 (1941); Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers' Ass'n v. United States, 234 U.S. 600 (1914).
  • 20
    • 18944385498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See National Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978) (agreement among engineers not to engage in competitive bidding); Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643 (1980) (agreement among wholesalers not to offer credit-free sales)
    • See National Soc'y of Prof'l Eng'rs v. United States, 435 U.S. 679 (1978) (agreement among engineers not to engage in competitive bidding); Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643 (1980) (agreement among wholesalers not to offer credit-free sales).
  • 21
    • 84865908605 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. General Elec. Co., No. CV96-121-M (D. Mont. filed Oct. 28, 1996). Memorandum of the United States in opposition to defendant's motion to dismiss
    • See United States v. General Elec. Co., No. CV96-121-M (D. Mont. filed Oct. 28, 1996). Memorandum of the United States in opposition to defendant's motion to dismiss, available at 〈http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/cases/f1000/1001.htm〉.
  • 22
    • 18944385500 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There might well be differences as to which restraints are appropriate for criminal prosecution, but that issue is outside the scope of this discussion.
  • 23
    • 18944386721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958)
    • Northern Pac. Ry. Co. v. United States, 356 U.S. 1, 5 (1958).
  • 24
    • 18944373078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Court made the point that the literal form of the agreement does not prevent a finding of per se illegality. See United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Corp., 378 U.S. 158, 170 (1964)
    • The Court made the point that the literal form of the agreement does not prevent a finding of per se illegality. See United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Corp., 378 U.S. 158, 170 (1964).
  • 25
    • 84865916179 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The importance of not applying the per se rule based on the "literal" form of the agreement appear was made fifteen years after Timken in Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979)
    • The importance of not applying the per se rule based on the "literal" form of the agreement appear was made fifteen years after Timken in Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979).
  • 26
    • 18944401916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Topco Assocs., 405 U.S. 596 (1972)
    • See United States v. Topco Assocs., 405 U.S. 596 (1972).
  • 27
    • 18944404208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Palmer v. BRG of Ga., 498 U.S. 46, 49 (1990)
    • See Palmer v. BRG of Ga., 498 U.S. 46, 49 (1990).
  • 28
    • 18944395346 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The territorial allocation scheme in Palmer was unrelated to any plausible goal of promoting interbrand competition. Two bar review course providers, which had vigorously competed in Georgia, agreed that one would not operate in the state and the other would not operate outside the state. As a result, bar review prices rose from $150 to over $400. See id. at 46-49.
  • 29
    • 18944365372 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Market allocations schemes are the most obvious example. See United States v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350 (1967). Some might put the price-fixing arrangement struck down in Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982), in this category as well
    • Market allocations schemes are the most obvious example. See United States v. Sealy, Inc., 388 U.S. 350 (1967). Some might put the price-fixing arrangement struck down in Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982), in this category as well.
  • 30
    • 18944403728 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS 34 at 10-13
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS 34 at 10-13.
  • 31
    • 18944406086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 13. The opinion mentioned price fixing and market divisions as examples. Id.
    • Id. at 13. The opinion mentioned price fixing and market divisions as examples. Id.
  • 32
    • 84865909083 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. A "plausible" justification was defined to mean that one that "cannot be rejected without extensive factual inquiry." Id.
    • Id. A "plausible" justification was defined to mean that one that "cannot be rejected without extensive factual inquiry." Id.
  • 33
    • 18944387854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 13-14
    • See id. at 13-14.
  • 34
    • 84865916180 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 26. The Commission read Professional Engineers to say that the per se rule applies to "agreements whose nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their illegality" and that the rule of reason applies to "agreements whose competitive effect can only be evaluated by analyzing the facts peculiar to the business, the history of the restraint, and the reasons why it was imposed." Id. (quoting Professional Engineers, 435 U.S. at 691-92)
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 26. The Commission read Professional Engineers to say that the per se rule applies to "agreements whose nature and necessary effect are so plainly anticompetitive that no elaborate study of the industry is needed to establish their illegality" and that the rule of reason applies to "agreements whose competitive effect can only be evaluated by analyzing the facts peculiar to the business, the history of the restraint, and the reasons why it was imposed." Id. (quoting Professional Engineers, 435 U.S. at 691-92).
  • 35
    • 18944371001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "We use the term 'rule of reason' when speaking about the individualized analysis, in contradistinction to the categorical per se approach." Id.
  • 36
    • 84865916181 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 29 ("We . . . believe it to be well grounded in . . . experience and in precedent to strip CDA's price advertising restrictions of their professional garb and declare them per se unlawful as naked restraints on price competition.")
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 29 ("We . . . believe it to be well grounded in . . . experience and in precedent to strip CDA's price advertising restrictions of their professional garb and declare them per se unlawful as naked restraints on price competition.").
  • 37
    • 18944375652 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 31-32
    • Id. at 31-32.
  • 38
    • 18944391369 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 39
    • 18944361927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 32-33. The Commission, nevertheless, concluded that the association did have market power. Id.
    • Id. at 32-33. The Commission, nevertheless, concluded that the association did have market power. Id.
  • 40
    • 18944401664 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 13
    • See supra note 13.
  • 41
    • 18944381983 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 42
    • 18944363155 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra note 20
    • See supra note 20.
  • 43
    • 18944401663 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klein, supra note 13, at n.6 and accompanying text
    • Klein, supra note 13, at n.6 and accompanying text.
  • 44
    • 18944370022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at n.7 and accompanying text
    • Id. at n.7 and accompanying text.
  • 45
    • 18944379373 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 46
    • 18944401915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS 34 at 13
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS 34 at 13.
  • 47
    • 18944407758 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., id. at 11, where the Commission discussed Blalock v. Ladies Professional Golf Association, 359 F. Supp. 1260 (N.D. Ga. 1973). In that case, a district court found that the suspension of a golfer by a professional association for moving her ball was per se illegal as a group boycott
    • See, e.g., id. at 11, where the Commission discussed Blalock v. Ladies Professional Golf Association, 359 F. Supp. 1260 (N.D. Ga. 1973). In that case, a district court found that the suspension of a golfer by a professional association for moving her ball was per se illegal as a group boycott.
  • 48
    • 18944364817 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS at 13
    • 1988 FTC LEXIS at 13.
  • 49
    • 84865909078 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 30 n.13 ("[W]e have been open to arguments that might carry weight under Broadcast Music, but CDA has simply failed to assert the requisite competitive benefits that might save it from per se condemnation.")
    • See id. at 30 n.13 ("[W]e have been open to arguments that might carry weight under Broadcast Music, but CDA has simply failed to assert the requisite competitive benefits that might save it from per se condemnation.").
  • 50
    • 84865908603 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ("The view that the Commission's reasoning foreshadows summary condemnation for a vast array of future cases . . . overstates our conclusion. Only cases involving equivalent conduct will be accorded similar treatment in the future.")
    • See id. ("The view that the Commission's reasoning foreshadows summary condemnation for a vast array of future cases . . . overstates our conclusion. Only cases involving equivalent conduct will be accorded similar treatment in the future.").
  • 51
    • 84865909079 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. General Elec. Co., No. CV96-121-M (D. Mont. filed Oct. 28, 1996). GE licensed diagnostic software to hospitals that purchased GE's medical equipment and used the software to service the equipment. The hospitals competed with GE in servicing other hospitals' equipment. As a condition of the licensing agreement, GE insisted that the hospitals could not compete with it in servicing any other equipment regardless of brand. The Division took the position that the agreement should be seen as a "naked agreement not to compete in the medical servicing market." Klein, supra note 13, at n.5
    • See United States v. General Elec. Co., No. CV96-121-M (D. Mont. filed Oct. 28, 1996). GE licensed diagnostic software to hospitals that purchased GE's medical equipment and used the software to service the equipment. The hospitals competed with GE in servicing other hospitals' equipment. As a condition of the licensing agreement, GE insisted that the hospitals could not compete with it in servicing any other equipment regardless of brand. The Division took the position that the agreement should be seen as a "naked agreement not to compete in the medical servicing market." Klein, supra note 13, at n.5.
  • 52
    • 18944384041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Klein, supra note 13. Thus, under both agencies' approaches there will continue to be an evolution of the per se rule, expanding to cover certain arrangements (and perhaps contracting as well)
    • Klein, supra note 13. Thus, under both agencies' approaches there will continue to be an evolution of the per se rule, expanding to cover certain arrangements (and perhaps contracting as well).
  • 53
    • 84865916177 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. ("[In] the next step of our analysis, if we conclude that a horizontal agreement that directly limits competition on price or output between or among competitors is not per se illegal, we then inquire whether there's a procompetitive justification for the agreement.")
    • See id. ("[In] the next step of our analysis, if we conclude that a horizontal agreement that directly limits competition on price or output between or among competitors is not per se illegal, we then inquire whether there's a procompetitive justification for the agreement.").
  • 54
    • 84865915905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. ("This [per se] category appears to be reasonably well-defined and usually the sole question we face in deciding if a particular agreement fits within it is whether, despite the effort to make it seem like the agreement is ancillary to some arrangement, it in fact isn't.")
    • Id. ("This [per se] category appears to be reasonably well-defined and usually the sole question we face in deciding if a particular agreement fits within it is whether, despite the effort to make it seem like the agreement is ancillary to some arrangement, it in fact isn't.").
  • 55
    • 18944385245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Supreme Court has sometimes said that procompetitive justifications are irrelevant in the case of per se offenses. See, e.g., Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332, 351 (1982) ("The anticompetitive potential inherent in all price-fixing agreements justifies their facial invalidation even if procompetitive justifications are offered for some." (citing United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150, 226 n.59 (1940)). However, this is the precise proposition that was rejected in Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979).
  • 56
    • 18944368111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Ironically, perhaps, the Antitrust Division has stressed that it wishes to avoid placing too much significance on characterization: [W]e reject the notion that there should be two methods of analysis - per se or full-blown rule of reason market analysis. As a matter of both sound and efficient antitrust analysis, we think this dichotomy is too stark and, frankly, that it leads to far too much of a front-end emphasis on which approach to apply, a choice that can sometimes be outcome determinative. Klein, supra note 13.
  • 57
    • 18944391120 scopus 로고
    • Indiana Federation of Dentists: The Per Se-Rule of Reason Continuum
    • I use the term "limited rule of reason" because the suggested terminology varies widely and there is no consensus about what any of the terms mean. Other descriptions of a limited rule of reason include "presumptive illegality," "strict antitrust scrutiny," "hard-boiled rule of reason," "truncated rule of reason," and "quick look." See, e.g., Richard H. Steuer, Indiana Federation of Dentists: The Per Se-Rule of Reason Continuum, 8 CARDOZO L. REV. 1101 (1987); Donald L. Beschle, "What Never? Well, Hardly Ever": Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Illegality, 38 HASTINGS L.J. 471 (1987); Timothy Muris, The New Rule of Reason, 57 ANTITRUST L.J. 859, 864 (1988); Phillip Areeda, The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 27 (1985).
    • (1987) Cardozo L. Rev. , vol.8 , pp. 1101
    • Steuer, R.H.1
  • 58
    • 18944393921 scopus 로고
    • "What Never? Well, Hardly Ever": Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Illegality
    • I use the term "limited rule of reason" because the suggested terminology varies widely and there is no consensus about what any of the terms mean. Other descriptions of a limited rule of reason include "presumptive illegality," "strict antitrust scrutiny," "hard-boiled rule of reason," "truncated rule of reason," and "quick look." See, e.g., Richard H. Steuer, Indiana Federation of Dentists: The Per Se-Rule of Reason Continuum, 8 CARDOZO L. REV. 1101 (1987); Donald L. Beschle, "What Never? Well, Hardly Ever": Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Illegality, 38 HASTINGS L.J. 471 (1987); Timothy Muris, The New Rule of Reason, 57 ANTITRUST L.J. 859, 864 (1988); Phillip Areeda, The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 27 (1985).
    • (1987) Hastings L.J. , vol.38 , pp. 471
    • Beschle, D.L.1
  • 59
    • 0347519762 scopus 로고
    • The New Rule of Reason
    • I use the term "limited rule of reason" because the suggested terminology varies widely and there is no consensus about what any of the terms mean. Other descriptions of a limited rule of reason include "presumptive illegality," "strict antitrust scrutiny," "hard-boiled rule of reason," "truncated rule of reason," and "quick look." See, e.g., Richard H. Steuer, Indiana Federation of Dentists: The Per Se-Rule of Reason Continuum, 8 CARDOZO L. REV. 1101 (1987); Donald L. Beschle, "What Never? Well, Hardly Ever": Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Illegality, 38 HASTINGS L.J. 471 (1987); Timothy Muris, The New Rule of Reason, 57 ANTITRUST L.J. 859, 864 (1988); Phillip Areeda, The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 27 (1985).
    • (1988) Antitrust L.J. , vol.57 , pp. 859
    • Muris, T.1
  • 60
    • 0346186236 scopus 로고
    • The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule
    • I use the term "limited rule of reason" because the suggested terminology varies widely and there is no consensus about what any of the terms mean. Other descriptions of a limited rule of reason include "presumptive illegality," "strict antitrust scrutiny," "hard-boiled rule of reason," "truncated rule of reason," and "quick look." See, e.g., Richard H. Steuer, Indiana Federation of Dentists: The Per Se-Rule of Reason Continuum, 8 CARDOZO L. REV. 1101 (1987); Donald L. Beschle, "What Never? Well, Hardly Ever": Strict Antitrust Scrutiny as an Alternative to Per Se Illegality, 38 HASTINGS L.J. 471 (1987); Timothy Muris, The New Rule of Reason, 57 ANTITRUST L.J. 859, 864 (1988); Phillip Areeda, The Changing Contours of the Per Se Rule, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 27 (1985).
    • (1985) Antitrust L.J. , vol.54 , pp. 27
    • Areeda, P.1
  • 61
    • 84865908601 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In both NCAA v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 109 (1984), and FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460 (1986), the Court commented that the absence of market power does not justify a "naked restriction on price or output."
    • In both NCAA v. Board of Regents of the University of Oklahoma, 468 U.S. 85, 109 (1984), and FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 460 (1986), the Court commented that the absence of market power does not justify a "naked restriction on price or output."
  • 62
    • 18944367772 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some commentators advocate dispensing with the market power inquiry for at least cases in Categories II and III. See Muris, supra note 56, at 864; Areeda, supra note 56.
  • 63
    • 18944398209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In both NCAA and Indiana Federation of Dentists, the Court said that "naked" restraints can be found unlawful in a rule of reason case without proof of market power. However, both opinions then went on to discuss marketplace effects. Thus, both statements are dicta.
  • 64
    • 18944371244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Mass. Board distinguished between "plausible" and "valid" efficiency justifications. A "plausible" efficiency justification was simply one that is rational on its face; that is, it "cannot be rejected without extensive factual inquiry." 1988 FTC LEXIS 34 at 12. The meaning of a "valid" justification is less clear. The opinion concluded that there was not a "plausible" procompetitive justification for a restriction on price advertising and that the justifications offered for a ban on certain forms of nonprice advertising were not "legally plausible." Id. at 21-22. Thus, the opinion did not explain how a restraint would be determined to be "valid."
  • 65
    • 18944382226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 9-10
    • Id. at 9-10.
  • 66
    • 18944364819 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 32-33
    • 1996 FTC LEXIS 88 at 32-33.
  • 67
    • 18944388101 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 40
    • Id. at 40.
  • 68
    • 84865915902 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 40. The majority relied on the facts that the association could police and enforce its prohibition and that the market did not force the dentists to advertise even when consumers desired additional information. Id. at 40-42. In addition, the Commission cited evidence of entry barriers to dentistry in California and the fact that, even though some dentists wished to advertise, they preferred to remain in the organization. Id. at 48-49. See also the majority's discussion of how CDA's "quick look" approach would have led to the same results in Mass. Board by focusing on some indicators of marketplace effects. Id. at 61-62
    • See id. at 40. The majority relied on the facts that the association could police and enforce its prohibition and that the market did not force the dentists to advertise even when consumers desired additional information. Id. at 40-42. In addition, the Commission cited evidence of entry barriers to dentistry in California and the fact that, even though some dentists wished to advertise, they preferred to remain in the organization. Id. at 48-49. See also the majority's discussion of how CDA's "quick look" approach would have led to the same results in Mass. Board by focusing on some indicators of marketplace effects. Id. at 61-62.
  • 69
    • 18944364331 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Klein, supra note 13: [I]f we conclude that a horizontal agreement that directly limits competition on price or output is not per se illegal, we then inquire whether there's a procompetitive justification for the agreement . . . [W]e expect a response that doesn't merely speculate about the existence of efficiencies, but rather comes forward with real-world evidence - factual evidence, expert economic evidence, and preferably both. . . . And, if we find that the proffered procompetitive justifications are unsubstantiated, we conclude that the agreement should be struck down. On the other hand, if we find that there are significant procompetitive benefits . . ., we then . . . seek to determine whether its likely anticompetitive effects outweigh its procompetitive benefits
    • See Klein, supra note 13: [I]f we conclude that a horizontal agreement that directly limits competition on price or output is not per se illegal, we then inquire whether there's a procompetitive justification for the agreement . . . [W]e expect a response that doesn't merely speculate about the existence of efficiencies, but rather comes forward with real-world evidence - factual evidence, expert economic evidence, and preferably both. . . . And, if we find that the proffered procompetitive justifications are unsubstantiated, we conclude that the agreement should be struck down. On the other hand, if we find that there are significant procompetitive benefits . . ., we then . . . seek to determine whether its likely anticompetitive effects outweigh its procompetitive benefits.
  • 70
    • 18944403227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An example cited by the Department is a joint selling arrangement between two radio stations, under which one of the stations agreed to pay the other station a fixed price in return for which the second station could sell all of the first station's advertising and keep the revenue. The Department concluded that there might be procompetitive justifications, but the parties were not able to offer any. See id.
  • 71
    • 18944362686 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Intellectual Property Guidelines use different, but perhaps equally ambiguous, language: [The rule of reason] inquiry may be truncated in certain circumstances. If the Agencies conclude that a restraint has no likely anticompetitive effects, they will treat it as reasonable, without an elaborate analysis of market power or the justifications for the restraint Similarly, if a restraint facially appears to be of a kind that would always or almost always tend to reduce output or increase prices and the restraint is not reasonably related to efficiencies, the Agencies will challenge the restraint without an elaborate analysis of particular industry circumstances. §3.4 (emphasis added; footnotes omitted).
  • 72
    • 18944401914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Gellhorn, supra note 58, at 3-4 (arguing against a requirement that there must be financial or operational integration to avoid application of the per se rule because integration may be a response to other legal requirements or exogenous effects, such as tax consequences)
    • See Gellhorn, supra note 58, at 3-4 (arguing against a requirement that there must be financial or operational integration to avoid application of the per se rule because integration may be a response to other legal requirements or exogenous effects, such as tax consequences).
  • 73
    • 18944372835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In that case, however, a court might be able to dismiss the case for failure to show antitrust injury.
  • 74
    • 18944393640 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Supreme Court, of course, has a long tradition of stating overly broad per se rules, which then must be narrowed in subsequent cases. The per se rule against price fixing described in United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.S. 150 (1940); the per se rule against boycotts described in United States v. General Motors Corp., 384 U.S. 127 (1966); and the per se rule against market allocations described in United States v. Topco Associates, 405 U.S. 596 (1972), are good examples.
  • 75
    • 18944379591 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Courts are hesitant to accept new "per se" violations. See, e.g., California Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 128 F.3d 720 (9th Cir. 1997) (rejecting the Commission's conclusion that price-advertising restrictions are per se unlawful).
  • 76
    • 18944406352 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Department's treatment of the licensing restriction discussed above may be an example. See supra note 50.
  • 77
    • 18944374487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The fact that parties are "allowed" to offer a justification does not preclude criminal enforcement where the arguments are spurious. As long as a jury concludes that there was a purpose to restrict competition, the mens rea requirements for criminal conviction are met. See United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. 422 (1978).
  • 78
    • 18944369559 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, a desire to discourage unionization does not change the conclusion that a restriction on hours of operation is per se unlawful. See Detroit Auto Dealers Ass'n, 111 F.T.C. 417 (1989), aff'd in part, 955 F.2d 457 (6th Cir. 1992).
  • 79
    • 18944365166 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One might put in this category, for example, the claimed justifications by the beer wholesalers in Catalano. There, the argument was that an agreement not to provide interest-free credit to customers promoted competition by encouraging entry. The court of appeals was persuaded by this argument, though the Supreme Court was not. See Catalano, Inc. v. Target Sales, Inc., 446 U.S. 643, 648-50 (1980).
  • 80
    • 18944407315 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Detroit Auto Dealers Assoaation, 111 F.T.C. 417 (1989), aff'd in part, 955 F.2d 457 (6th Cir. 1992), the majority was troubled by what it concluded was a "per se" approach by the Commission in finding an agreement to restrict hours of operations to violate the FTC Act. See 955 F.2d at 471. Nevertheless, it affirmed the Commission's finding of an unreasonable restraint of trade, in part because the Commission was able to show harmful competitive effects. Another member of the panel, who would have affirmed the Commission's findings in their entirety, stressed that the Commission was not applying the per se rule. Id. at 475 ("[T]he FTC . . . did not use a per se analysis. Under a per se analysis, the agreement would have been invalid without any consideration of its procompetitive effects. The FTC, however, did consider the efficiency justifications offered by respondents . . . ."). It seems likely all three members of the panel would have been troubled if the Commission had flatly declared procompetitive justifications to be irrelevant. Similarly, the Ninth Circuit affirmed the Commission's decision in CDA only after rejecting the Commission's per se characterization and relying on the Commission's finding of anticompetitive effects. See California Dental Ass'n v. FTC, 128 F.3d 720 (9th Cir. 1997).
  • 81
    • 84865909074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the discussion in the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992) § 0.1, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104
    • See the discussion in the Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992) § 0.1, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,104.
  • 82
    • 18944363156 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This section discusses the power to price over competitive levels obtained through tacit or express collusion, rather than the power obtained by excluding competitors or raising their costs. The issue of exclusionary market power is discussed in the next part of the article.
  • 83
    • 84865909075 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 1988 International Guidelines, supra note 1, § 3.3 ("[A joint venture] may be unlikely to facilitate the exercise of market power in circumstances [where a] complete merger would be likely to do so.")
    • See 1988 International Guidelines, supra note 1, § 3.3 ("[A joint venture] may be unlikely to facilitate the exercise of market power in circumstances [where a] complete merger would be likely to do so.").
  • 84
    • 0346710004 scopus 로고
    • The Antitrust Economics of Joint Ventures
    • There are several possible considerations. For example, special provisions to limit information exchange may reduce the likelihood of spillover effects; the incentive to compete may increase as the number of collaborators increase, see Pitofsky, supra note 6, at 1012; the incentive to compete may decrease if the venture is large compared to individual capacity, see Edmund W. Kitch, The Antitrust Economics of Joint Ventures, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 957, 962 (1985); and the likelihood of competition may decrease to the extent that parents continue to have control over the venture's price and output decision, see Timothy F. Bresnahan & Steven C. Salop, Quantifying the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures, 4 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 155, 156 (1986). These issues are discussed generally in Michael S. McFalls, The Role of Classical Market Power in Joint Venture Analysis, 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 651 (1998).
    • (1985) Antitrust L.J. , vol.54 , pp. 957
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 85
    • 38249040564 scopus 로고
    • Quantifying the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures
    • There are several possible considerations. For example, special provisions to limit information exchange may reduce the likelihood of spillover effects; the incentive to compete may increase as the number of collaborators increase, see Pitofsky, supra note 6, at 1012; the incentive to compete may decrease if the venture is large compared to individual capacity, see Edmund W. Kitch, The Antitrust Economics of Joint Ventures, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 957, 962 (1985); and the likelihood of competition may decrease to the extent that parents continue to have control over the venture's price and output decision, see Timothy F. Bresnahan & Steven C. Salop, Quantifying the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures, 4 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 155, 156 (1986). These issues are discussed generally in Michael S. McFalls, The Role of Classical Market Power in Joint Venture Analysis, 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 651 (1998).
    • (1986) Int'l J. Indus. Org. , vol.4 , pp. 155
    • Bresnahan, T.F.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 86
    • 18944384340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Role of Classical Market Power in Joint Venture Analysis
    • There are several possible considerations. For example, special provisions to limit information exchange may reduce the likelihood of spillover effects; the incentive to compete may increase as the number of collaborators increase, see Pitofsky, supra note 6, at 1012; the incentive to compete may decrease if the venture is large compared to individual capacity, see Edmund W. Kitch, The Antitrust Economics of Joint Ventures, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 957, 962 (1985); and the likelihood of competition may decrease to the extent that parents continue to have control over the venture's price and output decision, see Timothy F. Bresnahan & Steven C. Salop, Quantifying the Competitive Effects of Production Joint Ventures, 4 INT'L J. INDUS. ORG. 155, 156 (1986). These issues are discussed generally in Michael S. McFalls, The Role of Classical Market Power in Joint Venture Analysis, 66 ANTITRUST L.J. 651 (1998).
    • (1998) Antitrust L.J. , vol.66 , pp. 651
    • McFalls, M.S.1
  • 87
    • 0342311504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 4th ed.
    • See ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, ANTITRUST LAW DEVELOPMENTS 395 (4th ed. 1997) ("Ordinarily, the threshold issue with respect to a joint venture involving actual or potential competitors is whether it involves a significant integration of the economic resources of the parties to escape condemnation as a per se unlawful cartel . . . .").
    • (1997) ABA Section of Antitrust Law, Antitrust Law Developments , pp. 395
  • 88
    • 18944395345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Some literature suggests that a monopolist will not underinvest in research. See 1988 International Guidelines, supra note 1, at 53 n.236.
  • 89
    • 18944400682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 53
    • Id. at 53.
  • 90
    • 18944375651 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A five-effort rule, in which all of the ventures are the same size, would lead to an HHI market concentration of 2000, close to the 1800 threshold for highly concentrated markets. See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 77, § 1.51.
  • 91
    • 18944381241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., BOC Int'l Ltd. (British Oxygen) v. FTC, 557 F.2d 24 (2d Cir. 1977) (government must prove that entry is sufficiently probable and imminent); FTC v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 549 F.2d 289 (4th Cir. 1997); United States v. Siemens Corp., 621 F.2d 499 (2d. Cir. 1980)
    • See, e.g., BOC Int'l Ltd. (British Oxygen) v. FTC, 557 F.2d 24 (2d Cir. 1977) (government must prove that entry is sufficiently probable and imminent); FTC v. Atlantic Richfield Co., 549 F.2d 289 (4th Cir. 1997); United States v. Siemens Corp., 621 F.2d 499 (2d. Cir. 1980).
  • 92
    • 84865916174 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Co., 378 U.S. 158 (1964). In Penn-Olin two firms formed a joint venture to establish a new plant. The new venture increased the capacity in a highly concentrated market by about 50%. The district court had found that there would be a violation of § 7 only if the government could show that both firms would have entered the market independently. The Court remanded for a determination whether one of the collaborators would have entered the market on its own, while the other collaborator remained "at the edge of the market," exerting a healthy procompetitive influence on market behavior. Id. at 173
    • See United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Co., 378 U.S. 158 (1964). In Penn-Olin two firms formed a joint venture to establish a new plant. The new venture increased the capacity in a highly concentrated market by about 50%. The district court had found that there would be a violation of § 7 only if the government could show that both firms would have entered the market independently. The Court remanded for a determination whether one of the collaborators would have entered the market on its own, while the other collaborator remained "at the edge of the market," exerting a healthy procompetitive influence on market behavior. Id. at 173.
  • 93
    • 18944394871 scopus 로고
    • A Framework for Antitrust Analysis of Joint Ventures
    • Robert Pitofsky, A Framework for Antitrust Analysis of Joint Ventures, 54 ANTITRUST L.J. 893, 897 (1985).
    • (1985) Antitrust L.J. , vol.54 , pp. 893
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 94
    • 18944388098 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Ivaco, 704 F. Supp. 1409, 1414 (W.D. Mich. 1989)
    • See, e.g., United States v. Ivaco, 704 F. Supp. 1409, 1414 (W.D. Mich. 1989).
  • 95
    • 18944376110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979) (Court viewed package licenses as new products)
    • See Broadcast Music, Inc. v. CBS, Inc., 441 U.S. 1 (1979) (Court viewed package licenses as new products).
  • 96
    • 18944367036 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332 (1982) (Court viewed physician-organized health insurance plan as constituting price fixing)
    • See Arizona v. Maricopa County Med. Soc'y, 457 U.S. 332 (1982) (Court viewed physician-organized health insurance plan as constituting price fixing).
  • 97
    • 18944406600 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Columbia Picture Indus., 507 F. Supp. 412, 430-31 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), aff'd mem., 659 F.2d 1003 (2d Cir. 1981) (court focused on the fact that a joint venture among producers to sell movies involved existing movies not new ones)
    • See, e.g., United States v. Columbia Picture Indus., 507 F. Supp. 412, 430-31 (S.D.N.Y. 1980), aff'd mem., 659 F.2d 1003 (2d Cir. 1981) (court focused on the fact that a joint venture among producers to sell movies involved existing movies not new ones).
  • 98
    • 18944398723 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Penn-Olin involved a clear and substantial addition to capacity. See supra note 86. On remand, the district court found that neither firm was reasonably likely to enter the market, so eventually the right result was reached. See United States v. Penn-Olin Chem. Co., 246 F. Supp. 917, 928 (D. Del. 1965), aff'd per curiam, 389 U.S. 308 (1967). Nevertheless, the prospect that such a significant addition to market capacity could be challenged can give pause to parties planning similar efforts.
  • 99
    • 18944398452 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The finding of a loss of potential competition in Yamaha Motor Co. v. FTC, 657 F.2d 971 (8th Cir. 1981), was more defensible than in Penn-Olin. Brunswick, a domestic manufacturer of outboard motors entered into a joint venture with Yamaha, a Japanese manufacturer of outboard motors. Brunswick contributed capital and technology and the venture created a motor designed especially to compete in the United States. See 1979 FTC LEXIS 107 at 208. However, the venture used primarily existing capacity owned by Yamaha. 657 F.2d at 980. Moreover, there was substantial evidence that the venture precluded independent entry by Yamaha into the United States market. Id.
  • 100
    • 18944387380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See 457 U.S. at 353-53 (rejecting argument that the plan represented a new addition to the market)
    • See 457 U.S. at 353-53 (rejecting argument that the plan represented a new addition to the market).
  • 101
    • 18944389919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Palmer v. BRG of Ga., 498 U.S. 46 (1990) (two bar review course providers agreed that one would no longer compete within the state, while the other agreed that it would not enter other states)
    • See, e.g., Palmer v. BRG of Ga., 498 U.S. 46 (1990) (two bar review course providers agreed that one would no longer compete within the state, while the other agreed that it would not enter other states).
  • 102
    • 18944371881 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One suggestion is that, after an initial antitrust review at formation, joint ventures should generally be judged as single actors. Gellhorn, supra note 58, at 11-12.
  • 103
    • 84865915896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Statement of Robert Skitol Before the FTC 2-5 June 5
    • See Statement of Robert Skitol Before the FTC 2-5 (June 5, 1997), available at 〈http://www.ftc.gov/opp/jointvent/june5.htm〉.
    • (1997)
  • 104
    • 18944365831 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 105
    • 18944385970 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 207
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 207.
  • 106
    • 18944403475 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are several Supreme Court cases dealing with a claim by excluded outsiders. See, e.g., United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass'n of St. Louis, 224 U.S. 383 (1912); Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945); Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985); Radiant Burners, Inc. v. People's Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961); Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492 (1988). See also Statement of Steven C. Bomse Before the FTC 22 (1997).
  • 107
    • 18944383001 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • hereinafter COMPETITION POLICY
    • 1988 International Guidelines, supra note 1, § 3.42: [T]he Department in general is concerned about the anticompetitive effects of a joint venture when it is overinclusive - that is, when it restricts competition among competitors that account for a large portion of sales (or capacity) in the market, thereby creating, enhancing or facilitating the exercise of market power. A recent FTC Staff Report is somewhat more ambivalent, at least with regard to network joint ventures: [W]e find that a denial of membership in a network joint venture or of access to a standard may enhance the incentives to establish a competing venture or to develop a new standard, while maximizing the reward to incumbents for creating and developing the existing venture or standard. . . . On the other hand, we find that mandating access to membership or to a standard may increase competition within the joint venture or among firms who make use of the established standard. FTC STAFF REPORT, COMPETITION POLICY IN THE NEW HIGH-TECH, GLOBAL MARKETPLACE 9-29 (1996) [hereinafter COMPETITION POLICY].
    • (1996) FTC Staff Report, Competition Policy in the New High-tech, Global Marketplace , pp. 9-29
  • 108
    • 18944369770 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In these cases, the role of the exclusionary policy (e.g., a group's "by-law" or contractual provision) is likely to be facially ambiguous. The purpose and effect of the policy must be determined from its historical use.
  • 109
    • 84865916172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. MCI Communications Corp., 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,730 (D.D.C. 1994) (Antitrust Division challenged a joint venture involving MCI and British Telecommunications)
    • See, e.g., United States v. MCI Communications Corp., 1994-2 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 70,730 (D.D.C. 1994) (Antitrust Division challenged a joint venture involving MCI and British Telecommunications).
  • 110
    • 0040130489 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • You Keep on Knocking but You Can't Come in: Evaluating Restrictions on Access to Joint Ventures
    • See Dennis W. Carlton & Steven C. Salop, You Keep on Knocking But You Can't Come in: Evaluating Restrictions on Access to Joint Ventures, 9 HARV. J. L. & TECH. 319, 330 (1996) ("A joint venture access rule can harm competition by raising the costs or otherwise disadvantaging rivals of its members in the output market. This can reduce competition and lead to higher prices than would otherwise occur.").
    • (1996) Harv. J. L. & Tech. , vol.9 , pp. 319
    • Carlton, D.W.1    Salop, S.C.2
  • 112
    • 22944431922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 101
    • COMPETITION POLICY, supra note 101, at 9-6 to 9-7.
    • Competition Policy , pp. 9-16
  • 113
    • 18944382493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985)
    • Northwest Wholesale Stationers v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985).
  • 114
    • 18944402402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 294
    • See id. at 294.
  • 115
    • 18944385969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Unless the cooperative possesses market power or exclusive access to an element essential to effective competition, the conclusion that expulsion is virtually always likely to have an anticompetitive effect is not warranted. . . . Absent such a showing with respect to a cooperative buying arrangement, courts should apply a rule of reason analysis. Id. at 296.
  • 116
    • 18944367037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 298: A plaintiff seeking application of the "per se" rule must present a threshold case that the challenged activity falls into a category likely to have predominant anticompetitive effect. The mere allegation of a concerted refusal to deal does not suffice because not all concerted refusals to deal are predominately anticompetitive. When the plaintiff challenges expulsion from a joint buying cooperative, some showing must be made that the cooperate possesses market power or unique access to a business element necessary for effective competition. In FTC v. Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 U.S. 447, 458 (1986), the Court characterized the breadth of the per se rule stated in Northwest Stationers as a narrow one. ("As we observed [in Northwest Stationers], the category of restraints classed as group boycotts is not to be expanded indiscriminately, and the per se approach has generally been limited to cases in which firms with market power boycott suppliers or customers in order to discourage them from doing business with a competitor . . . .").
  • 117
    • 18944381737 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Wigod v. Chicago Mercantile Exch., 981 F.2d 1510, 1517 (7th Cir. 1992); Bascom Food Prods. Corp. v. Reese Finer Foods, Inc., 715 F. Supp. 616, 633-34 (D. N.J. 1989)
    • See, e.g., Wigod v. Chicago Mercantile Exch., 981 F.2d 1510, 1517 (7th Cir. 1992); Bascom Food Prods. Corp. v. Reese Finer Foods, Inc., 715 F. Supp. 616, 633-34 (D. N.J. 1989).
  • 118
    • 84865908595 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Hahn v. Oregon Physicians' Serv., 868 F. 2d 1022, 1030 n.9 (9th Cir. 1988); Collins v. Associated Pathologists, 844 F.2d 473 (7th Cir. 1988) ("[B]oycotts are illegal per se only if used to enforce agreements that are themselves illegal per se - for example, price-fixing agreements."); Carleton v. Vermont Dairy Herd Improvement Ass'n, 782 F. Supp. 926, 933 (D. Vt. 1991)
    • See, e.g., Hahn v. Oregon Physicians' Serv., 868 F. 2d 1022, 1030 n.9 (9th Cir. 1988); Collins v. Associated Pathologists, 844 F.2d 473 (7th Cir. 1988) ("[B]oycotts are illegal per se only if used to enforce agreements that are themselves illegal per se - for example, price-fixing agreements."); Carleton v. Vermont Dairy Herd Improvement Ass'n, 782 F. Supp. 926, 933 (D. Vt. 1991).
  • 120
    • 0006608377 scopus 로고
    • Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles
    • In the context of denial of a facility by a monopolist, an influential formulation of the doctrine stated that it applies only if: (1) there is control of the facility by the monopolist; (2) the competitor is unable to reasonably duplicate the facility; (3) the competitor is denied use of the facility; and (4) it is feasible to provide access to the facility. See MCI Communications Corp. v. AT&T, 708 F.2d 1081, 1132-33 (7th Cir. 1983). The doctrine has been frequently criticized. See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 273 ("The so-called 'essential facility doctrine' is one of the most troublesome, incoherent and unmanageable of bases for Sherman section 2 liability. The antitrust world would almost certainly be a better place if it were jettisoned . . . ."); Phillip Areeda, Essential Facilities: An Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles, 58 ANTITRUST L.J. 841 (1990).
    • (1990) Antitrust L.J. , vol.58 , pp. 841
    • Areeda, P.1
  • 121
    • 18944398453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In that case, the particular facility controlled by one group is essential to the plaintiff, but not to others.
  • 122
    • 18944399461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carlton & Salop, supra note 104, at 328-29. This discussion borrows from Carlton and Salop but the framework and terminology suggested here are somewhat different
    • See Carlton & Salop, supra note 104, at 328-29. This discussion borrows from Carlton and Salop but the framework and terminology suggested here are somewhat different.
  • 123
    • 18944383528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass'n of St. Louis, 224 U.S. 383 (1912)
    • United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass'n of St. Louis, 224 U.S. 383 (1912).
  • 124
    • 18944406085 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945)
    • Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1 (1945).
  • 125
    • 18944371000 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Radiant Burners, Inc. v. People's Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961)
    • Radiant Burners, Inc. v. People's Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961).
  • 126
    • 18944363599 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 274
    • See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 274.
  • 127
    • 18944372834 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • However, market power in the output market may be based on the fact that individual members have market power by virtue of their participation in the collaboration in the input market. In Associated Press the market power in the output market - sale of newspapers - was held by individual newspapers. 326 U.S. at 17-18.
  • 128
    • 18944394401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There may be special cases in markets for differentiated products, where the outsider offers close substitute for the products produced by the group. Even though the excluding group does not have large market share, preventing the outsider from competing may allow the group to raise prices to some extent. See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 77, § 2.21; HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 212-13.
  • 129
    • 18944372833 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, excluding the outsider may simply mean that the outsider must enter the input market on its own or collaborate with other outsiders to enter.
  • 130
    • 18944386210 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In both Terminal Railroad and Associated Press, the Court assumed that admitting outsiders would promote competition. In Terminal Railroad the Court required that the joint venture of railroads, which owned a terminal and transfer facilities, make them available to any other railroads on non-discriminatory terms, even if these new users did not elect to become owners. The Court assumed that the large number of railroads that could use the facility, including non-owners of the terminal, would result in competition. In Associated Press the Court required a joint venture of newspapers, which gathered news and distributed it to all members, to admit outsiders. By preventing a member newspaper from excluding a competitor in its own city, the Court assumed that competition would be promoted in cities with more than one newspaper. See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 208-09.
  • 131
    • 18944404915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under some circumstances, the "disruptiveness" of the outsider will be relevant. For example, excluding a discount broker from a listing service suggests that the broker, if admitted, will promote competition within the group. Under these circumstances, there may be particular concerns about excluding these maverick firms from the market, just as there are particular concerns about their being acquired. See 1992 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, supra note 77, § 2.12.
  • 132
    • 18944389050 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In Associated Press the efficiencies of the joint news-gathering activities could still be achieved if a newspaper was not allowed to bar another newspaper in its city from participating. In particular, the participants in the venture did not appear to be concerned that latecomers would take a free ride on earlier risk taking. See HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 209.
  • 133
    • 22944431922 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 101
    • Demand side economies can occur, for example, if the product becomes more desirable the larger the number of collaborators. See COMPETITION POLICY, supra note 101, at 9-1.
    • Competition Policy , pp. 9-11
  • 134
    • 18944375888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., United States v. Realty Multi-List, Inc., 629 F.2d 1351, 1372-74 (5th Cir. 1980) (a group of real estate brokers, who would ordinarily benefit from sharing the listings of additional brokers, attempted to exclude brokers who could promote competition by charging discount fees)
    • See, e.g., United States v. Realty Multi-List, Inc., 629 F.2d 1351, 1372-74 (5th Cir. 1980) (a group of real estate brokers, who would ordinarily benefit from sharing the listings of additional brokers, attempted to exclude brokers who could promote competition by charging discount fees).
  • 135
    • 18944380582 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Carlton & Salop, supra note 104, at 330
    • See, e.g., Carlton & Salop, supra note 104, at 330.
  • 136
    • 18944405392 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The possibility that the outsider would be particularly disruptive played a role in Radiant Burners, Inc. v. People's Gas Light & Coke Co., 364 U.S. 656 (1961) (plaintiff stated a cause of action by alleging that the standards applied by the standard-setting organization were arbitrary and capricious); and Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492 (1988) (plaintiff proposed new product standard, which was rejected by established competitors).
  • 137
    • 18944402637 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This is not to say that the fairness of the procedures should become an important aspect of determining whether the outsider is "arbitrarily excluded." The Court rejected a general requirement of procedural fairness in Northwest Stationers, 472 U.S. at 293. In Allied Tube the unfair procedures used by the association ("packing" the meeting to vote against a proposed new standard) amounted to a discriminatory application of a standard by economically interested competitors. 486 U.S. at 509. In addition, the control over standard setting effectively excluded the outsider because the group's standards were routinely adopted by public and private building codes. Id. at 495-96.
  • 138
    • 18944362425 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There still remains the problem of determining whether exclusion is "arbitrary," without involving courts in the analysis of the objective validity of a certification standard. To this extent, it may be necessary to examine the motive of the organization despite the difficulties of doing so. The alternative - a court's attempting to assess the legitimacy of a professional or technical standard - is even less workable. See, e.g., Wilk v. AMA, 719 F.2d 207, 213 (7th Cir. 1983) (placing burden on association to show good faith in denying a chiropractor access to medical facilities); see also HOVENKAMP, supra note 5, at 213.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.