메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 66, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 537-566

Albrecht overruled - At last

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0032341203     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (6)

References (150)
  • 1
    • 18944375096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 390 U.S. 145 (1968)
    • 390 U.S. 145 (1968).
  • 2
    • 18944383401 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 118 S. Ct. 275 (1997)
    • 118 S. Ct. 275 (1997).
  • 3
    • 0040130485 scopus 로고
    • Monopoly Power and Market Power in Antitrust Law
    • We use the terms "monopoly power" and "market power" interchangeably in this article. Similarly, we use the term monopolist to denote an entity having market power. See Thomas G. Krattenmaker et al., Monopoly Power and Market Power in Antitrust Law, 76 GEO. L.J. 241 (1987).
    • (1987) Geo. L.J. , vol.76 , pp. 241
    • Krattenmaker, T.G.1
  • 4
    • 18944399108 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977)
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977).
  • 5
    • 18944398854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Adantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990)
    • Adantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990).
  • 6
    • 18944373474 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 278. Khan himself signed the dealership contract with State Oil, and his corporation, Khan & Associates, Inc., operated the station. See Khan v. State Oil Co., 93 F.3d 1358, 1360 (7th Cir. 1996), rev'd, 118 S. Ct. 275 (1997). Both Khan and his corporation sued State Oil, but we refer to them collectively as "Khan."
  • 7
    • 18944375781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 278
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 278.
  • 8
    • 18944386376 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Khan's contract claim was based on State Oil's occasional refusal to lower its suggested retail price on regular grade gasoline and, accordingly, its wholesale price, so that Khan could lower the retail price and maintain his profit margin. State Oil conceded that it had a contractual obligation to suggest competitively realistic retail prices, and Khan argued that State Oil breached its obligation by refusing to lower the suggested retail price when his competitors were charging lower prices. The district court found insufficient evidence in support of the claim and dismissed it; the appellate court affirmed, and the issue did not reach the Supreme Court. See Khan, 93 F.3d at 1366.
  • 9
    • 18944382379 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1360-61
    • Id. at 1360-61.
  • 10
    • 18944363034 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 1363
    • Id. at 1363.
  • 11
    • 18944371779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 12
    • 18944371778 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 429 U.S. 477 (1977)
    • 429 U.S. 477 (1977).
  • 13
    • 18944396461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1363
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1363.
  • 14
    • 18944365961 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 15
    • 18944389448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990)
    • Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990).
  • 16
    • 18944364226 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364.
  • 17
    • 18944394553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 284 ("The Court of Appeals was correct in applying [the] principle [of stare decisis] despite disagreement with Albrecht, for it is this Court's prerogative alone to overrule one of its precedents.").
  • 18
    • 18944407667 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See id. at 280. The majority's reasoning in Albrecht was vigorously disputed at the time in dissents by Justices Harlan (390 U.S. at 156) and Stewart (id. at 168).
  • 19
    • 18944395966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977)
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977).
  • 20
    • 18944406491 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967)
    • United States v. Arnold, Schwinn & Co., 388 U.S. 365 (1967).
  • 21
    • 18944365517 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 281. The Court cited Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982); 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335 (1987); and ARCO
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 281. The Court cited Arizona v. Maricopa County Medical Society, 457 U.S. 332 (1982); 324 Liquor Corp. v. Duffy, 479 U.S. 335 (1987); and ARCO.
  • 22
    • 18944362049 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 282 (citing Business Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 726 (1988))
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 282 (citing Business Elecs. Corp. v. Sharp Elecs. Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 726 (1988)).
  • 23
    • 18944403123 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 281 (quoting ARCO, 495 U.S. at 340)
    • Id. at 281 (quoting ARCO, 495 U.S. at 340).
  • 24
    • 18944400569 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 282 (quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986))
    • Id. at 282 (quoting Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 594 (1986)).
  • 25
    • 18944371377 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 26
    • 18944389545 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 27
    • 18944374307 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 28
    • 18944393022 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 29
    • 18944372966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 283.
    • Id. at 283.
  • 30
    • 18944393125 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 31
    • 18944381993 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 282 (recounting the explanation of the appellate court), 283
    • See id. at 282 (recounting the explanation of the appellate court), 283.
  • 32
    • 18944397896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 284
    • Id. at 284.
  • 33
    • 18944375095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 284-85
    • Id. at 284-85.
  • 34
    • 18944407219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 285
    • Id. at 285.
  • 35
    • 18944370670 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 283
    • Id. at 283.
  • 36
    • 0003592009 scopus 로고
    • 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978);
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1994) Federal Antitrust Policy , pp. 422
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 37
    • 0041081624 scopus 로고
    • The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1981) U. Fla. L. Rev. , vol.33 , pp. 461
    • Blair, R.D.1    Kaserman, D.L.2
  • 38
    • 0039894683 scopus 로고
    • Maximum Price Fixing
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1981) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 886
    • Easterbrook, F.1
  • 39
    • 0039302531 scopus 로고
    • Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1986) Syracuse L. Rev. , vol.37 , pp. 43
    • Blair, R.D.1    Fesmire, J.M.2
  • 40
    • 11544316721 scopus 로고
    • Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1995) Antitrust Bull. , vol.40 , pp. 1
    • Lopatka, J.E.1
  • 41
    • 0003728403 scopus 로고
    • 3d ed.
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1990) Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance , pp. 558
    • Scherer, F.M.1    Ross, D.2
  • 42
    • 0004148794 scopus 로고
    • For a sampling of critical commentary, see HERBERT HOVENKAMP, FEDERAL ANTITRUST POLICY 422 (1994); 3 PHILLIP AREEDA & DONALD TURNER, ANTITRUST LAW ¶ 734e (1978); Roger D. Blair & David L. Kaserman, The Albrecht Rule and Consumer Welfare; An Economic Analysis, 33 U. FLA. L. REV. 461 (1981); Frank Easterbrook, Maximum Price Fixing, 48 U. CHI. L. REV. 886 (1981); Roger D. Blair & James M. Fesmire, Maximum Price Fixing and the Goals of Antitrust, 37 SYRACUSE L. REV. 43 (1986); John E. Lopatka, Stephen Breyer and Modern Antitrust Law: A Snug Fit, 40 ANTITRUST BULL. 1 (1995); F.M. SCHERER & DAVID ROSS, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 558 (3d ed. 1990); STEPHEN F. ROSS, PRINCIPLES OF ANTITRUST LAW 255 (1993).
    • (1993) Principles of Antitrust Law , pp. 255
    • Ross, S.F.1
  • 43
    • 18944386220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 36
    • HOVENKAMP, supra note 36.
  • 44
    • 18944385978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Albrecht, 390 U.S. 145
    • See Albrecht, 390 U.S. 145.
  • 45
    • 18944395849 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990); Khan
    • See Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328 (1990); Khan.
  • 46
    • 18944385506 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698 (7th Cir. 1984) (Posner, J.)
    • See Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698 (7th Cir. 1984) (Posner, J.).
  • 47
    • 18944371888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Slowiak v. Land O'Lakes, Inc., 987 F.2d 1293 (7th Cir. 1993)
    • See Slowiak v. Land O'Lakes, Inc., 987 F.2d 1293 (7th Cir. 1993).
  • 48
    • 18944398004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994)
    • See Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994).
  • 49
    • 18944405862 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994) (Breyer, C.J.)
    • See Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994) (Breyer, C.J.).
  • 50
    • 0000432057 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy
    • Joseph J. Spengler, Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy, 58 J. POL. ECON. 347 (1950); see also Fritz Machlup & Martha Taber, Bilateral Monopoly, Successive Monopoly, and Vertical Integration, 27 ECONOMICA 101 (1960).
    • (1950) J. Pol. Econ. , vol.58 , pp. 347
    • Spengler, J.J.1
  • 51
    • 0000918817 scopus 로고
    • Bilateral Monopoly, Successive Monopoly, and Vertical Integration
    • Joseph J. Spengler, Vertical Integration and Antitrust Policy, 58 J. POL. ECON. 347 (1950); see also Fritz Machlup & Martha Taber, Bilateral Monopoly, Successive Monopoly, and Vertical Integration, 27 ECONOMICA 101 (1960).
    • (1960) Economica , vol.27 , pp. 101
    • Machlup, F.1    Taber, M.2
  • 52
    • 18944375658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The analysis assumes that demand is sufficient to support a competitive industry, so that no stage is a natural monopoly due to economies of scale relative to the demand for the product. See Spengler, supra note 44, at 347, 351.
  • 53
    • 18944365607 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This result indicates that successive monopoly is inefficient, which provides added incentive for vertical integration. That is, the fact that total profits will be larger with a single, integrated monopolist while prices to consumers will be lower indicates that the unintegrated, successive monopoly structure imposes additional deadweight welfare losses.
  • 56
    • 21444461188 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maximum Resale Price Restraints in Franchising
    • This analysis is presented more formally and more completely in Roger D. Blair & Amanda K. Esquibel, Maximum Resale Price Restraints in Franchising, 65 ANTITRUST L.J. 157 (1996).
    • (1996) Antitrust L.J. , vol.65 , pp. 157
    • Blair, R.D.1    Esquibel, A.K.2
  • 57
    • 18944405272 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See supra notes 27-30 and accompanying text
    • See supra notes 27-30 and accompanying text.
  • 58
    • 18944386616 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 282-83
    • See Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 282-83.
  • 59
    • 18944371515 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Khan, 93 F.3d at 1361; Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 164-65 (Harlan, J., dissenting). Both jurists offered this theory to explain Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc., 340 U.S. 211 (1951), where the Court held illegal per se an agreement between what it viewed as competing distillers to impose resale price ceilings on their wholesalers.
  • 61
    • 18944394879 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992) (holding that an equipment manufacturer with no market power in die sale of equipment is nevertheless not entitled to summary judgment on an antitrust claim against it alleging that it denied unique repair parts to independent service providers, thereby inducing machine owners to procure repair service from it).
  • 62
  • 64
    • 84963037127 scopus 로고
    • The earliest observation that an "invisible hand" leads individuals pursuing their own self-interest to promote die interests of society generally is contained in ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 477-78 (1776). Of course, in a complex economy, Smith's invisible hand may not operate satisfactorily. See F.M. Bator, The Anatomy of Market Failure, 72 Q.J. ECON. 351 (1958).
    • (1776) The Wealth of Nations , pp. 477-478
    • Smith, A.1
  • 65
    • 84963037127 scopus 로고
    • The Anatomy of Market Failure
    • The earliest observation that an "invisible hand" leads individuals pursuing their own self-interest to promote die interests of society generally is contained in ADAM SMITH, THE WEALTH OF NATIONS 477-78 (1776). Of course, in a complex economy, Smith's invisible hand may not operate satisfactorily. See F.M. Bator, The Anatomy of Market Failure, 72 Q.J. ECON. 351 (1958).
    • (1958) Q.J. Econ. , vol.72 , pp. 351
    • Bator, F.M.1
  • 66
    • 0002401339 scopus 로고
    • Why Is the Common Law Efficient?
    • Paul Rubin, Why Is the Common Law Efficient?, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 51 (1977).
    • (1977) J. Legal Stud. , vol.6 , pp. 51
    • Rubin, P.1
  • 67
    • 0001913043 scopus 로고
    • The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules
    • hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1977) J. Legal Stud. , vol.6 , pp. 65
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 68
    • 0000612582 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1978) J. Legal Stud. , vol.7 , pp. 393
    • Goodman, J.1
  • 69
    • 0011602643 scopus 로고
    • Selective Characteristics of Litigation
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1980) J. Legal Stud. , vol.9 , pp. 399
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 70
    • 0006139605 scopus 로고
    • The Dynamics of the Legal Process
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud. , vol.11 , pp. 405
    • Blume, L.1    Rubinfeld, D.L.2
  • 71
    • 0002254318 scopus 로고
    • The Selection of Disputes for Litigation
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1984) J. Legal Stud. , vol.13 , pp. 1
    • Priest, G.L.1    Klein, B.2
  • 72
    • 0001370489 scopus 로고
    • Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1986) J. Legal Stud. , vol.15 , pp. 227
    • Heiner, R.A.1
  • 73
    • 0043131637 scopus 로고
    • A Positive Theory of Legal Change
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1994) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.14 , pp. 467
    • Bailey, M.J.1    Rubin, P.H.2
  • 74
    • 84925041689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1996) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.109 , pp. 641
    • Roe, M.J.1
  • 75
    • 0013375217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Predictability and Legal Evolution
    • For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614
    • Rubin's article spawned an interesting literature extending his insight. See, e.g., George L. Priest, The Common Law Process and the Selection of Efficient Rules, 6 J. LEGAL STUD. 65 (1977) [hereinafter Priest, Common Law Process]; John Goodman, An Economic Theory of the Evolution of the Common Law, 7 J. LEGAL STUD. 393 (1978); George L. Priest, Selective Characteristics of Litigation, 9 J. LEGAL STUD. 399 (1980); Lawrence Blume & Daniel L. Rubinfeld, The Dynamics of the Legal Process, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 405 (1982); George L. Priest & Benjamin Klein, The Selection of Disputes for Litigation, 13 J. LEGAL STUD. 1 (1984); Ronald A. Heiner, Imperfect Decisions and the Law: On the Evolution of Legal Precedent and Rules, 15 J. LEGAL STUD. 227 (1986); Martin J. Bailey & Paul H. Rubin, A Positive Theory of Legal Change, 14 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 467 (1994); Mark J. Roe, Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics, 109 HARV. L. REV. 641 (1996); Nicholas L. Georgakopoulos, Predictability and Legal Evolution, 17 INT'L REV. L. & ECON. 475 (1997). For a summary of several objections to this theory, see POSNER, supra note 54, at 614.
    • (1997) Int'l Rev. L. & Econ. , vol.17 , pp. 475
    • Georgakopoulos, N.L.1
  • 76
    • 18944383009 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rubin, supra note 57, at 55
    • See Rubin, supra note 57, at 55.
  • 77
    • 18944402998 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Goodman, supra note 58, at 402
    • See Goodman, supra note 58, at 402.
  • 78
    • 18944391127 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Rubin, supra note 57, at 55-56
    • See Rubin, supra note 57, at 55-56.
  • 79
    • 0040904882 scopus 로고
    • Common Law and Statute Law
    • See Paul Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 205, 212 (1982): [D]isputants who are in the market will tend to litigate until they reach a favorable decision. They may achieve such a decision by spending more on litigation; by relitigating cases whenever issues arise until a favorable decision is reached; by waiting to litigate until a particularly apt case for establishing precedent occurs; and by using other techniques aimed at obtaining favorable precedents. See also Galanter, Why the "Haves" Come Out Ahead: Speculation on the Limits of Legal Change, 9 L. & SOC. REV. 95 (1974).
    • (1982) J. Legal Stud. , vol.11 , pp. 205
    • Rubin, P.1
  • 80
    • 79956121151 scopus 로고
    • Why the "Haves" Come Out Ahead: Speculation on the Limits of Legal Change
    • See Paul Rubin, Common Law and Statute Law, 11 J. LEGAL STUD. 205, 212 (1982): [D]isputants who are in the market will tend to litigate until they reach a favorable decision. They may achieve such a decision by spending more on litigation; by relitigating cases whenever issues arise until a favorable decision is reached; by waiting to litigate until a particularly apt case for establishing precedent occurs; and by using other techniques aimed at obtaining favorable precedents. See also Galanter, Why the "Haves" Come Out Ahead: Speculation on the Limits of Legal Change, 9 L. & SOC. REV. 95 (1974).
    • (1974) L. & Soc. Rev. , vol.9 , pp. 95
    • Galanter1
  • 81
    • 18944371629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Priest, Common Law Process, supra note 58. In an addendum to his paper, Rubin offers a critique of Priest's contribution. See Rubin, supra note 57, at 62-63.
  • 82
    • 18944404685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Priest shows that even if the judiciary decides the outcome randomly (e.g., by flipping a coin), efficiency will emerge over time due to the opportunity set of cases that the judiciary considers. Priest, Common Law Process, supra note 58, at 68-69.
  • 83
    • 18944389062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 72
    • Id. at 72.
  • 84
    • 84865913813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1
    • 15 U.S.C. § 1.
  • 87
    • 84875202983 scopus 로고
    • Farewell to the Sea of Doubt: Jettisoning the Constitutional Sherman Act
    • For a criticism of the judicial activism that this engendered, see Thomas Arthur, Farewell to the Sea of Doubt: Jettisoning the Constitutional Sherman Act, 74 CAL. L. REV. 263 (1986).
    • (1986) Cal. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 263
    • Arthur, T.1
  • 89
    • 0004316299 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 5th ed.
    • PHILLIP AREEDA & LOUIS KAPLOW, ANTITRUST ANALYSIS 44 (5th ed. 1997). See also HANS B. THORELLI, THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS 228-29 (1954) ("[I]n adopting the standard of the common law Congress expected the courts not only to apply a set of somewhat vague doctrines but also in doing so to make use of that 'certain technique of judicial reasoning' characteristic of common law courts.").
    • (1997) Antitrust Analysis , pp. 44
    • Areeda, P.1    Kaplow, L.2
  • 90
    • 18944396336 scopus 로고
    • PHILLIP AREEDA & LOUIS KAPLOW, ANTITRUST ANALYSIS 44 (5th ed. 1997). See also HANS B. THORELLI, THE FEDERAL ANTITRUST LAWS 228-29 (1954) ("[I]n adopting the standard of the common law Congress expected the courts not only to apply a set of somewhat vague doctrines but also in doing so to make use of that 'certain technique of judicial reasoning' characteristic of common law courts.").
    • (1954) The Federal Antitrust Laws , pp. 228-229
    • Thorelli, H.B.1
  • 91
    • 18944387389 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For examples of cases in which lower courts applied Albrecht during the first nine years after that case was decided, see Milsen Co. v. Southland Corp., 454 F.2d 363 (7th Cir. 1971) (holding that a convenience store franchisee was entitled to a preliminary injunction preventing termination of its franchises where the franchisor, inter alia, required franchisees to adhere to the maximum retail prices set by the franchisor on products some of which the franchisor supplied); Blankenship v. Hearst Corp., 519 F.2d 418 (9th Cir. 1975) (holding that a newspaper distributor could sue the publisher for fixing the maximum prices that could be charged by carriers who purchased papers from the distributor); Bowen v. New York News, Inc., 522 F.2d 1242 (2d Cir. 1975) (holding that an otherwise illegal maximum resale price agreement between a newspaper and its dealers was protected under the fair trade laws); Greene v. General Foods Corp., 517 F.2d 635 (5th Cir. 1975) (holding that a food supplier's actions to prevent its distributor from selling its products to national buyers at prices above those set by the supplier constituted illegal vertical maximum price fixing); Knutson v. Daily Rev., Inc., 548 F.2d 795 (9th Cir. 1976) (holding that a newspaper publisher was liable in an action brought by one of its dealers alleging vertical maximum price fixing).
  • 92
    • 18944407762 scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Law and Evolutionary Models of Legal Change
    • The analytical details are provided in Roger D. Blair & Carolyn D. Schafer, Antitrust Law and Evolutionary Models of Legal Change, 40 U. FLA. L. REV. 379 (1988).
    • (1988) U. Fla. L. Rev. , vol.40 , pp. 379
    • Blair, R.D.1    Schafer, C.D.2
  • 93
    • 84865912447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 15 U.S.C. § 15
    • 15 U.S.C. § 15.
  • 94
    • 18944379597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (holding that nonprice vertical restraints imposed by a manufacturer on its dealers are lawful if reasonable)
    • Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (holding that nonprice vertical restraints imposed by a manufacturer on its dealers are lawful if reasonable).
  • 95
    • 18944406096 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Under Sylvania, a manufacturer can agree to grant a distributor an exclusive territory. Some lower courts reasoned that if a manufacturer can confer exclusive territories on its dealers in order to stimulate the provision of point-of-sale services by eliminating the risk of free riding, thereby granting each a monopoly in its brand, the manufacturer can lawfully constrain the prices that the monopolist dealer can charge. See, e.g., Jack Walters & Sons Corp. v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698, 706-07 (7th Cir. 1984) (Posner, J.) (suggesting that "the continued vitality of Albrecht is in doubt after" Sylvania); Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994) (questioning validity of Albrecht in light of Sylvania). Indeed, the Supreme Court later acknowledged that after Sylvania, "the procompetitive potential of a vertical maximum price restraint is more evident . . . than it was when Albrecht was decided, because exclusive territorial arrangements and other nonprice restrictions were unlawful per se in 1968." Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USAPetroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 343 n.13 (1990).
  • 96
    • 18944396066 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977) (articulating the antitrust injury requirement)
    • Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U.S. 477 (1977) (articulating the antitrust injury requirement).
  • 97
    • 0345704132 scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Antitrust Injury
    • Some courts held that the profits lost by competing dealers because of a maximum resale price restraint do not constitute antitrust injury, for they represent losses incurred as a result of stiffer competition from rivals charging lower prices, not as a result of lessened competition. See, e.g., Indiana Grocery, Inc. v. Super Valu Stores, Inc., 864 F.2d 1409 (7th Cir. 1989). See also Roger D. Blair & Jeffrey L. Harrison, Rethinking Antitrust Injury, 42 VAND. L. REV. 1559 (1989). Other courts held that even the dealers subject to the vertical price cap suffer no antitrust injury, for the profits they are prevented from earning are monopoly profits ineligible for antitrust protection. See, e.g., Jack Walters, 737 F.2d at 708-09; Kestenbaum v. Falstaff Brewing Corp., 575 F.2d 564 (5th Cir. 1978).
    • (1989) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 1559
    • Blair, R.D.1    Harrison, J.L.2
  • 98
    • 18944371008 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See cases cited in note 76, supra
    • See cases cited in note 76, supra.
  • 99
    • 18944384290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For example, Khan itself is such a case. See also Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994) (Breyer, C.J.)
    • For example, Khan itself is such a case. See also Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745 (1st Cir. 1994) (Breyer, C.J.).
  • 100
    • 18944368356 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 283
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 283.
  • 101
    • 18944390666 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Various alternatives are examined in depth in Blair & Esquibel, supra note 48
    • Various alternatives are examined in depth in Blair & Esquibel, supra note 48.
  • 102
    • 18944376633 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This substitution helps explain why the evolutionary process was stunted
    • This substitution helps explain why the evolutionary process was stunted.
  • 103
    • 18944364572 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Spengler, supra note 44
    • See Spengler, supra note 44.
  • 104
    • 18944364927 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paschall v. Kansas City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692 (8th Cir. 1984)
    • Paschall v. Kansas City Star Co., 727 F.2d 692 (8th Cir. 1984).
  • 107
    • 18944395847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jack Walters & Sons v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698, 706 (7th Cir. 1984)
    • Jack Walters & Sons v. Morton Bldg., Inc., 737 F.2d 698, 706 (7th Cir. 1984).
  • 108
    • 0011913836 scopus 로고
    • Contractual Form, Retail Price, and Asset Characteristics in Gasoline Retailing
    • See Andrea Shephard, Contractual Form, Retail Price, and Asset Characteristics in Gasoline Retailing, 24 RAND J. ECON. 58, 62 (1993).
    • (1993) Rand J. Econ. , vol.24 , pp. 58
    • Shephard, A.1
  • 109
    • 18944366319 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Jack Walters, 737 F.2d at 708. The court's recognition that maximum resale price fixing may be socially beneficial because it is necessary to facilitate price advertising, itself a productive practice, is sound. The publisher in Albrecht, however, also advertised a suggested price in its newspaper, and that did not save its maximum resale price restraint from per se condemnation. See Albrecht, 390 U.S. at 147.
  • 110
    • 18944403733 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Acquaire v. Canada Dry Bottling Co., 24 F.3d 401 (2d Cir. 1994). Canada Dry distributors received the same per-case commission irrespective of whether the supplier was running a promotion or not. The supplier did this by adjusting the effective wholesale price to the distributors.
  • 111
    • 18944405861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. General Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476 (1926)
    • United States v. General Elec. Co., 272 U.S. 476 (1926).
  • 112
    • 18944361933 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 823 F.2d 1215 (8th Cir. 1987)
    • 823 F.2d 1215 (8th Cir. 1987).
  • 113
    • 18944373589 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Simpson v. Union Oil Co., 377 U.S. 13 (1964)
    • See Simpson v. Union Oil Co., 377 U.S. 13 (1964).
  • 114
    • 18944367779 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 517 F.2d 635 (5th Cir. 1975)
    • 517 F.2d 635 (5th Cir. 1975).
  • 115
    • 18944401921 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Morrison v. Murray Biscuit Co., 797 F.2d 1430, 1436 (7th Cir. 1986) (Posner, J.)
    • Morrison v. Murray Biscuit Co., 797 F.2d 1430, 1436 (7th Cir. 1986) (Posner, J.).
  • 116
    • 0003851002 scopus 로고
    • rev. ed.
    • See generally 1 AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 36, ¶¶ 103-113; ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 50-71 (rev. ed. 1993); RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE 8-22 (1976).
    • (1993) The Antitrust Paradox , pp. 50-71
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 117
    • 0003401865 scopus 로고
    • See generally 1 AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 36, ¶¶ 103-113; ROBERT H. BORK, THE ANTITRUST PARADOX 50-71 (rev. ed. 1993); RICHARD A. POSNER, ANTITRUST LAW: AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE 8-22 (1976).
    • (1976) Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective , pp. 8-22
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 118
    • 84865904169 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., 1 AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 36, ¶¶ 103-105; BORK, supra note 97, at ix-xii; POSNER, supra note 97, at 8-22
    • See, e.g., 1 AREEDA & TURNER, supra note 36, ¶¶ 103-105; BORK, supra note 97, at ix-xii; POSNER, supra note 97, at 8-22.
  • 119
    • 0346785473 scopus 로고
    • In Defense of Antitrust
    • See, e.g., Harlan Blake & William Jones, In Defense of Antitrust, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 377, 382-84 (1965); Kenneth Elzinga, The Goals of Antitrust: Other Than Competition and Efficiency, What Else Counts?, 125 U. PA. L. REV. 1191, 1209-13 (1977); DONALD DEWEY, THE ANTITRUST EXPERIMENT IN AMERICA 1-51 (1990); Robert Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 HASTINGS L.J. 65 (1982).
    • (1965) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.65 , pp. 377
    • Blake, H.1    Jones, W.2
  • 120
    • 0344904435 scopus 로고
    • The Goals of Antitrust: Other Than Competition and Efficiency, What Else Counts?
    • See, e.g., Harlan Blake & William Jones, In Defense of Antitrust, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 377, 382-84 (1965); Kenneth Elzinga, The Goals of Antitrust: Other Than Competition and Efficiency, What Else Counts?, 125 U. PA. L. REV. 1191, 1209-13 (1977); DONALD DEWEY, THE ANTITRUST EXPERIMENT IN AMERICA 1-51 (1990); Robert Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 HASTINGS L.J. 65 (1982).
    • (1977) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.125 , pp. 1191
    • Elzinga, K.1
  • 121
    • 0346841975 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Harlan Blake & William Jones, In Defense of Antitrust, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 377, 382-84 (1965); Kenneth Elzinga, The Goals of Antitrust: Other Than Competition and Efficiency, What Else Counts?, 125 U. PA. L. REV. 1191, 1209-13 (1977); DONALD DEWEY, THE ANTITRUST EXPERIMENT IN AMERICA 1-51 (1990); Robert Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 HASTINGS L.J. 65 (1982).
    • (1990) The Antitrust Experiment in America , pp. 1-51
    • Dewey, D.1
  • 122
    • 0012041643 scopus 로고
    • Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged
    • See, e.g., Harlan Blake & William Jones, In Defense of Antitrust, 65 COLUM. L. REV. 377, 382-84 (1965); Kenneth Elzinga, The Goals of Antitrust: Other Than Competition and Efficiency, What Else Counts?, 125 U. PA. L. REV. 1191, 1209-13 (1977); DONALD DEWEY, THE ANTITRUST EXPERIMENT IN AMERICA 1-51 (1990); Robert Lande, Wealth Transfers as the Original and Primary Concern of Antitrust: The Efficiency Interpretation Challenged, 34 HASTINGS L.J. 65 (1982).
    • (1982) Hastings L.J. , vol.34 , pp. 65
    • Lande, R.1
  • 123
    • 18944370033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See generally SCHERER & ROSS, supra note 36, at 15-56
    • See generally SCHERER & ROSS, supra note 36, at 15-56.
  • 124
    • 0005121542 scopus 로고
    • Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act
    • Bork's position is certainly unequivocal: "[T]He only legitimate goal of antitrust is the maximization of consumer welfare." BORK, supra note 97, at 7. In addition to his provocative book, see Robert H. Bork, Legislative Intent and the Policy of the Sherman Act, 9 J.L. & ECON. 7 (1966).
    • (1966) J.L. & Econ. , vol.9 , pp. 7
    • Bork, R.H.1
  • 125
    • 18944395848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Lande, supra note 99. In addition, Elzinga notes that the conventional wisdom holds that there is a tradeoff between equity and efficiency: In light of this well-known tradeoff, it is notable that antitrust enforcement generally served to help those at the low end of the income distribution range without decreasing efficiency. Antitrust achieves this double benefit when it promotes efficiency in resource allocation by preventing the cartelization or monopolization of a market shopped in by low-income buyers. The reason is straightforward: prices will be made lower in this market so that for any given income, however low, a larger basket of goods and services can be purchased . . . . In sum, the pursuit of efficiency goals through antitrust enforcement is consistent with the objective of an equitable distribution of income. Elzinga, supra note 99, at 1194-96. In fact, in most cases economists will take the distribution of income as given or will "hold income constant" when dealing with matters of efficiency. This does not deny the fact that some distributions of income are more conducive to economic efficiency than others. Regrettably perhaps, it is often true that the more equal distributions of income are those that provide incentives that to some extent discourage economic efficiency.
  • 126
    • 18944401673 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Lande, supra note 99, at 72-74, 80-82
    • See Lande, supra note 99, at 72-74, 80-82.
  • 127
    • 18944389328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 83-85
    • See id. at 83-85.
  • 128
    • 18944381023 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 87-88
    • See id. at 87-88.
  • 129
    • 0039747489 scopus 로고
    • The Modernization of Antitrust: A New Equilibrium
    • Eleanor M. Fox, The Modernization of Antitrust: A New Equilibrium, 66 CORNELL L. REV. 1140, 1152-54 (1981).
    • (1981) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.66 , pp. 1140
    • Fox, E.M.1
  • 130
    • 0002349749 scopus 로고
    • The Political Content of Antitrust
    • Robert Pitofsky, The Political Content of Antitrust, 127 U. PA. L. REV. 1051, 1054 (1979).
    • (1979) U. Pa. L. Rev. , vol.127 , pp. 1051
    • Pitofsky, R.1
  • 131
    • 18944389924 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F. 2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945)
    • United States v. Aluminum Co. of Am., 148 F. 2d 416 (2d Cir. 1945).
  • 132
    • 18944402409 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 428
    • Id. at 428.
  • 133
    • 0040380193 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis after Kodak
    • See, e.g., Benjamin Klein, Market Power in Antitrust: Economic Analysis After Kodak, 3 SUP. CT. ECON. Rev. 43, 72 (1993).
    • (1993) Sup. Ct. Econ. Rev. , vol.3 , pp. 43
    • Klein, B.1
  • 134
    • 18944385977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Blake & Jones, supra note 99, at 383
    • Blake & Jones, supra note 99, at 383.
  • 135
    • 18944368597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 136
    • 18944389544 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 384
    • Id. at 384.
  • 137
    • 18944370777 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 340 U.S. 211, 213 (1951)
    • Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 340 U.S. 211, 213 (1951).
  • 138
    • 18944364095 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Paschall v. Kansas City Star Co., 695 F. 2d 322, 325 (8th Cir. 1982); reh'g en banc, 727 F. 2d 692, 695 (8th Cir. 1984) (noting that, in spite of the Kansas City Star's policy of not recognizing a carrier's propietary right in its assigned route, some routes were sold to third parties for hundreds of thousands of dollars).
  • 139
    • 18944371007 scopus 로고
    • Vertical Integration by the Newspaper Monopolist
    • For an insightful analysis that predates the en banc rehearing in Paschall, see Herbert Hovenkamp, Vertical Integration by the Newspaper Monopolist, 69 IOWA L. REV. 451 (1984).
    • (1984) Iowa L. Rev. , vol.69 , pp. 451
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 140
    • 18944380110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 752 F.2d 473 (9th Cir. 1985)
    • 752 F.2d 473 (9th Cir. 1985).
  • 141
    • 18944373332 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 475, 477
    • See id. at 475, 477.
  • 142
    • 18944396852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1362-63
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1362-63.
  • 143
    • 0347308724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Antitrust Injury, Merger Policy, and the Competitor Plaintiff
    • See, e.g., ARCO, 495 U.S. at 339 (observing that a private party cannot recover unless it is "adversely affected by an anticompetitive aspect of the defendant's conduct"). For detailed analyses of the antitrust injury doctrine, see William H. Page & John E. Lopatka, Antitrust Injury, Merger Policy, and the Competitor Plaintiff, 82 IOWA L. REV. 127 (1996); William H. Page, The Scope of Liability for Antitrust Violations, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1445 (1985).
    • (1996) Iowa L. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 127
    • Page, W.H.1    Lopatka, J.E.2
  • 144
    • 0347308724 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Scope of Liability for Antitrust Violations
    • See, e.g., ARCO, 495 U.S. at 339 (observing that a private party cannot recover unless it is "adversely affected by an anticompetitive aspect of the defendant's conduct"). For detailed analyses of the antitrust injury doctrine, see William H. Page & John E. Lopatka, Antitrust Injury, Merger Policy, and the Competitor Plaintiff, 82 IOWA L. REV. 127 (1996); William H. Page, The Scope of Liability for Antitrust Violations, 37 STAN. L. REV. 1445 (1985).
    • (1985) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.37 , pp. 1445
    • Page, W.H.1
  • 145
    • 18944399962 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ARCO, 495 U.S. at 345
    • ARCO, 495 U.S. at 345.
  • 146
    • 18944365171 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Caribe BMW, Inc. v. Bayerische Motoren Werke Aktiengesellschaft, 19 F.3d 745, 752-54 (1st Cir. 1994) (Breyer, C.J.). To be precise, the court held that profits lost by the dealer due to an inefficient aspect of the practice are antitrust injury, whereas if the profits the plaintiff lost because of the price cap were supracompetitive profits, "it is at least arguable that no 'antitrust injury' occurred." Id. at 753-54.
  • 147
    • 18944399233 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364
    • Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364.
  • 148
    • 18944406611 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 285
    • Khan, 118 S. Ct. at 285.
  • 149
    • 18944391621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364
    • See Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364.
  • 150
    • 18944396335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The appellate court suggested that, if a practice causes no antitrust injury, then even public enforcers are unable to bring suit. Khan, 93 F.3d at 1364. Though the assertion has analytical appeal, the Court has explained the antitrust injury doctrine as a limitation solely on private enforcement. See, e.g., ARCO, 495 U.S. at 339 (commenting that antitrust injury does not arise "until a private party is adversely affected by an anticompetitive aspect of the defendant's conduct"). The idea of a substantive antitrust offense, subject to public enforcement, that causes no one anticompetitive harm is troubling, but it is not impossible.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.