-
1
-
-
84971943254
-
The Art of Economic Development: Markets, Politics and Externalities
-
Summer
-
For broad discussions of these measures, see Wing Thye Woo, "The Art of Economic Development: Markets, Politics and Externalities," International Organization 44, no. 3 (Summer 1990): 403-29; and Dwight H. Perkins, "Economic Systems Reform in Developing Countries," in Reforming Economic Systems in Developing Countries, ed. Dwight H. Perkins and Michael Roemer (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for International Development, 1991), pp. 13-53. See also World Bank, World Development Report 1991 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), chaps. 4, 5.
-
(1990)
International Organization
, vol.44
, Issue.3
, pp. 403-429
-
-
Woo, W.T.1
-
2
-
-
11744324534
-
Economic Systems Reform in Developing Countries
-
ed. Dwight H. Perkins and Michael Roemer Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for International Development
-
For broad discussions of these measures, see Wing Thye Woo, "The Art of Economic Development: Markets, Politics and Externalities," International Organization 44, no. 3 (Summer 1990): 403-29; and Dwight H. Perkins, "Economic Systems Reform in Developing Countries," in Reforming Economic Systems in Developing Countries, ed. Dwight H. Perkins and Michael Roemer (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for International Development, 1991), pp. 13-53. See also World Bank, World Development Report 1991 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), chaps. 4, 5.
-
(1991)
Reforming Economic Systems in Developing Countries
, pp. 13-53
-
-
Perkins, D.H.1
-
3
-
-
0003742806
-
-
Oxford: Oxford University Press, chaps. 4, 5
-
For broad discussions of these measures, see Wing Thye Woo, "The Art of Economic Development: Markets, Politics and Externalities," International Organization 44, no. 3 (Summer 1990): 403-29; and Dwight H. Perkins, "Economic Systems Reform in Developing Countries," in Reforming Economic Systems in Developing Countries, ed. Dwight H. Perkins and Michael Roemer (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for International Development, 1991), pp. 13-53. See also World Bank, World Development Report 1991 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991), chaps. 4, 5.
-
(1991)
World Development Report 1991
-
-
-
4
-
-
0004157554
-
-
New York: Harper & Row
-
See, e.g., Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1957), p. 116; Pamela Johnson Conover and Stanley Feldman, "The Origins and Meaning of Liberal/Conservative Self-Identification," American Journal of Political Science 25, no. 4 (November 1981): 617-45, esp. 638.
-
(1957)
An Economic Theory of Democracy
, pp. 116
-
-
Downs, A.1
-
5
-
-
84878989040
-
The Origins and Meaning of Liberal/Conservative Self-Identification
-
November
-
See, e.g., Anthony Downs, An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper & Row, 1957), p. 116; Pamela Johnson Conover and Stanley Feldman, "The Origins and Meaning of Liberal/Conservative Self-Identification," American Journal of Political Science 25, no. 4 (November 1981): 617-45, esp. 638.
-
(1981)
American Journal of Political Science
, vol.25
, Issue.4
, pp. 617-645
-
-
Conover, P.J.1
Feldman, S.2
-
6
-
-
0004051456
-
-
London: Oxford University Press
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1970)
Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries
-
-
Little, I.M.D.1
Scitovsky, T.2
Scott, M.F.G.3
-
7
-
-
0003604168
-
-
New York: National Bureau of Economic Research
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1978)
Liberalization Attempts and Consequences
-
-
Krueger, A.1
-
8
-
-
0003604163
-
-
New York: National Bureau of Economic Research
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1978)
Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes
-
-
Bhagwati, J.1
-
9
-
-
0004056646
-
-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1982)
Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies
-
-
Balassa, B.1
-
10
-
-
0003844130
-
-
World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 World Bank, Washington, D.C.
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1983)
Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries
-
-
Agarwala, R.1
-
11
-
-
0023496617
-
Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study
-
October
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1986)
Economic Development and Cultural Change
, vol.35
, Issue.1
, pp. 35-75
-
-
Landau, D.1
-
12
-
-
0042713007
-
-
World Bank Background Paper World Bank, Washington, D.C.
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1987)
Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?
-
-
Thomas, V.1
Halevi, N.2
Stanton, J.3
-
13
-
-
85040889455
-
-
Washington, D.C.: World Bank
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1990)
Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience
-
-
Papageorgiou, D.1
Choski, A.M.2
Michaely, M.3
-
14
-
-
0026471194
-
Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85
-
April
-
For a number of cross-sectional studies, see Ian M. D. Little, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice F. G. Scott, Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970); Anne Krueger, Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Jagdish Bhagwati, Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978); Bela Balassa et al., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982); Ramgopal Agarwala, "Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries," World Bank Staff Paper no. 575 (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1983); Daniel Landau, "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed Countries: An Empirical Study," Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, no. 1 (October 1986): 35-75; Vinod Thomas, Nadab Halevi, and Julie Stanton, "Does Policy Reform Improve Performance?" World Bank Background Paper (World Bank, Washington, D.C., 1987); Demetrios Papageorgiou, Armeane M. Choski, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1990); and David Dollar, "Outward-Oriented Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-85," Economic Development and Cultural Change 40, no. 3 (April 1992): 520-44.
-
(1992)
Economic Development and Cultural Change
, vol.40
, Issue.3
, pp. 520-544
-
-
Dollar, D.1
-
15
-
-
0010890329
-
Comparative Social Policy: Theories, Methods, Findings
-
ed. Meinolf Dierkes, Hans N. Weiler, and Ariane Berthoin Antal New York: St. Martin's
-
For a survey of some of these tests, see Harold L. Wilensky, Gregory M. Luebbert, Susan Reed Hahn, and Adrienne M. Jamieson, "Comparative Social Policy: Theories, Methods, Findings," in Comparative Policy Research: Learning from Experience, ed. Meinolf Dierkes, Hans N. Weiler, and Ariane Berthoin Antal (New York: St. Martin's, 1987), pp. 381-458, esp. pp. 384-91; and Aaron Wildavsky, "Why Government Grows," in Budgeting: A Comparative Theory of Budgetary Processes, ed. Aaron Wildavsky, 2d ed. (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1986), 12: 360-68.
-
(1987)
Comparative Policy Research: Learning from Experience
, pp. 381-458
-
-
Wilensky, H.L.1
Luebbert, G.M.2
Hahn, S.R.3
Jamieson, A.M.4
-
16
-
-
11744344179
-
Why Government Grows
-
ed. Aaron Wildavsky, 2d ed. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books
-
For a survey of some of these tests, see Harold L. Wilensky, Gregory M. Luebbert, Susan Reed Hahn, and Adrienne M. Jamieson, "Comparative Social Policy: Theories, Methods, Findings," in Comparative Policy Research: Learning from Experience, ed. Meinolf Dierkes, Hans N. Weiler, and Ariane Berthoin Antal (New York: St. Martin's, 1987), pp. 381-458, esp. pp. 384-91; and Aaron Wildavsky, "Why Government Grows," in Budgeting: A Comparative Theory of Budgetary Processes, ed. Aaron Wildavsky, 2d ed. (New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction Books, 1986), 12: 360-68.
-
(1986)
Budgeting: A Comparative Theory of Budgetary Processes
, vol.12
, pp. 360-368
-
-
Wildavsky, A.1
-
17
-
-
0003324044
-
The Nature of the Fiscal Economy
-
ed. Richard A. Musgrave and Alan R. Peacock London: Macmillan
-
Adolf Wagner, "The Nature of the Fiscal Economy," in Classics in the Theory of Public Finance, ed. Richard A. Musgrave and Alan R. Peacock (London: Macmillan, 1958), pp. 1-8.
-
(1958)
Classics in the Theory of Public Finance
, pp. 1-8
-
-
Wagner, A.1
-
18
-
-
0002263717
-
The Small European States in the International Economy: Economic Dependence and Corporatist Politics
-
ed. John Ruggie New York: Columbia University Press
-
Peter Katzenstein, "The Small European States in the International Economy: Economic Dependence and Corporatist Politics," in The Antinomies of Interdependence, ed. John Ruggie (New York: Columbia University Press, 1983), pp. 91-130, Small States in World Markets (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1985), and Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland and the Politics of Industry (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984).
-
(1983)
The Antinomies of Interdependence
, pp. 91-130
-
-
Katzenstein, P.1
-
19
-
-
0003483114
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Peter Katzenstein, "The Small European States in the International Economy: Economic Dependence and Corporatist Politics," in The Antinomies of Interdependence, ed. John Ruggie (New York: Columbia University Press, 1983), pp. 91-130, Small States in World Markets (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1985), and Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland and the Politics of Industry (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984).
-
(1985)
Small States in World Markets
-
-
-
20
-
-
0003680247
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Peter Katzenstein, "The Small European States in the International Economy: Economic Dependence and Corporatist Politics," in The Antinomies of Interdependence, ed. John Ruggie (New York: Columbia University Press, 1983), pp. 91-130, Small States in World Markets (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1985), and Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland and the Politics of Industry (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984).
-
(1984)
Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland and the Politics of Industry
-
-
-
22
-
-
0004219175
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
See, e.g., the literature on the political business cycle. See Edward Tufte, The Political Control of the Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978). For views on presidential and parliamentarian systems, see Terry M. Moe, "The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy," in Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, ed. Oliver Williamson (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 116-53. See also the discussion in Alexander M. Hicks and Duane Swank, "Politics, Institutions and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1960-82," American Political Science Review 86, no. 3 (September 1992): 658-74. Hicks and Swank also address the differences between majoritarian and proportional voting systems.
-
(1978)
The Political Control of the Economy
-
-
Tufte, E.1
-
23
-
-
0003110110
-
The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy
-
ed. Oliver Williamson New York: Oxford University Press
-
See, e.g., the literature on the political business cycle. See Edward Tufte, The Political Control of the Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978). For views on presidential and parliamentarian systems, see Terry M. Moe, "The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy," in Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, ed. Oliver Williamson (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 116-53. See also the discussion in Alexander M. Hicks and Duane Swank, "Politics, Institutions and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1960-82," American Political Science Review 86, no. 3 (September 1992): 658-74. Hicks and Swank also address the differences between majoritarian and proportional voting systems.
-
(1990)
Organization Theory: from Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond
, pp. 116-153
-
-
Moe, T.M.1
-
24
-
-
84971698875
-
Politics, Institutions and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1960-82
-
September
-
See, e.g., the literature on the political business cycle. See Edward Tufte, The Political Control of the Economy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978). For views on presidential and parliamentarian systems, see Terry M. Moe, "The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy," in Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, ed. Oliver Williamson (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990), pp. 116-53. See also the discussion in Alexander M. Hicks and Duane Swank, "Politics, Institutions and Welfare Spending in Industrialized Democracies, 1960-82," American Political Science Review 86, no. 3 (September 1992): 658-74. Hicks and Swank also address the differences between majoritarian and proportional voting systems.
-
(1992)
American Political Science Review
, vol.86
, Issue.3
, pp. 658-674
-
-
Hicks, A.M.1
Swank, D.2
-
25
-
-
0039487548
-
Centralization and Government Budget Size
-
Winter
-
For fiscal centralization, see J. Fred Giertz, "Centralization and Government Budget Size" Publius 2, no. 1 (Winter 1981): 119-28; John A. C. Conybeare, "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification," World Politics 35, no. 1 (October 1982): 25-42. For indirect taxation, see David R. Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61; and Conybeare. For labor organization, see R. Michael Alvarez, Geoffrey Garrett, and Peter Lange, "The Political Economy of Macroeconomic Performance," American Political Science Review 85 (1991): 539-56.
-
(1981)
Publius
, vol.2
, Issue.1
, pp. 119-128
-
-
Giertz, J.F.1
-
26
-
-
84972054435
-
The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification
-
October
-
For fiscal centralization, see J. Fred Giertz, "Centralization and Government Budget Size" Publius 2, no. 1 (Winter 1981): 119-28; John A. C. Conybeare, "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification," World Politics 35, no. 1 (October 1982): 25-42. For indirect taxation, see David R. Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61; and Conybeare. For labor organization, see R. Michael Alvarez, Geoffrey Garrett, and Peter Lange, "The Political Economy of Macroeconomic Performance," American Political Science Review 85 (1991): 539-56.
-
(1982)
World Politics
, vol.35
, Issue.1
, pp. 25-42
-
-
Conybeare, J.A.C.1
-
27
-
-
84973959798
-
The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis
-
For fiscal centralization, see J. Fred Giertz, "Centralization and Government Budget Size" Publius 2, no. 1 (Winter 1981): 119-28; John A. C. Conybeare, "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification," World Politics 35, no. 1 (October 1982): 25-42. For indirect taxation, see David R. Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61; and Conybeare. For labor organization, see R. Michael Alvarez, Geoffrey Garrett, and Peter Lange, "The Political Economy of Macroeconomic Performance," American Political Science Review 85 (1991): 539-56.
-
(1978)
American Political Science Review
, vol.72
, pp. 1243-1261
-
-
Cameron, D.R.1
-
28
-
-
84971735729
-
The Political Economy of Macroeconomic Performance
-
For fiscal centralization, see J. Fred Giertz, "Centralization and Government Budget Size" Publius 2, no. 1 (Winter 1981): 119-28; John A. C. Conybeare, "The Rent-Seeking State and Revenue Diversification," World Politics 35, no. 1 (October 1982): 25-42. For indirect taxation, see David R. Cameron, "The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis," American Political Science Review 72 (1978): 1243-61; and Conybeare. For labor organization, see R. Michael Alvarez, Geoffrey Garrett, and Peter Lange, "The Political Economy of Macroeconomic Performance," American Political Science Review 85 (1991): 539-56.
-
(1991)
American Political Science Review
, vol.85
, pp. 539-556
-
-
Alvarez, R.M.1
Garrett, G.2
Lange, P.3
-
29
-
-
0001911993
-
Ideology as a Cultural System
-
ed. David E. Apter New York: Free Press of Glencoe
-
Hence this definition is free from the pejorative connotations sometimes attached to discussions of ideology. Ideologies will not be assumed to be necessarily wrong or based on delusion, but simply not proven by the facts available. See discussion in Clifford Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," in Ideology and Discontent, ed. David E. Apter (New York: Free Press of Glencoe, 1964), pp. 47-76. Reprinted in Clifford Geertz, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic, 1973), chap. 8.
-
(1964)
Ideology and Discontent
, pp. 47-76
-
-
Geertz, C.1
-
30
-
-
0004083437
-
-
Reprinted New York: Basic, chap. 8
-
Hence this definition is free from the pejorative connotations sometimes attached to discussions of ideology. Ideologies will not be assumed to be necessarily wrong or based on delusion, but simply not proven by the facts available. See discussion in Clifford Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," in Ideology and Discontent, ed. David E. Apter (New York: Free Press of Glencoe, 1964), pp. 47-76. Reprinted in Clifford Geertz, The Interpretation of Cultures (New York: Basic, 1973), chap. 8.
-
(1973)
The Interpretation of Cultures
-
-
Geertz, C.1
-
34
-
-
0004023051
-
-
Ithaca, N. Y.: Cornell University Press
-
Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery (Ithaca, N. Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990), p. 46.
-
(1990)
Pathways from the Periphery
, pp. 46
-
-
Haggard, S.1
-
35
-
-
0008640214
-
Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions
-
ed. David Colander Cambridge, Mass.: Balinger
-
Douglass North, "Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions," in Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. David Colander (Cambridge, Mass.: Balinger, 1984), pp. 33-40, quote on p. 34.
-
(1984)
Neoclassical Political Economy: The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities
, pp. 33-40
-
-
North, D.1
-
36
-
-
0007029184
-
Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics
-
January
-
Stephen D. Krasner, "Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics," Comparative Politics 16, no. 2 (January 1984): 223-46, quote on 228.
-
(1984)
Comparative Politics
, vol.16
, Issue.2
, pp. 223-246
-
-
Krasner, S.D.1
-
37
-
-
0002503923
-
Corporate Culture and Economic Theory
-
ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle New York: Cambridge University Press
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1990)
Perspectives on Positive Political Economy
, pp. 90-143
-
-
Kreps, D.1
-
38
-
-
11744292531
-
The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses
-
ed. Ernest Gellner Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1985)
Relativism and the Social Sciences
, pp. 68-82
-
-
Gellner, E.1
-
39
-
-
0003542293
-
-
New York: Norton, chap. 5, sec. 2
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1981)
Structure and Change in Economic History
-
-
North, D.1
-
40
-
-
0003540038
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, chap. 3, sec. 3
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1990)
Institutional Change and Economic Performance
-
-
-
41
-
-
0003426656
-
-
Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, chaps. 1-4
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1982)
Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers
-
-
Douglas, M.1
Wildavsky, A.2
-
42
-
-
11744361162
-
When Rationality Fails
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, chap. 1, sec. 3
-
See David Kreps, "Corporate Culture and Economic Theory," in Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), pp. 90-143; Ernest Gellner, "The Gaffe-Avoiding Animal, or a Bundle of Hypotheses," in Relativism and the Social Sciences, ed. Ernest Gellner (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), pp. 68-82; Douglass North, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton, 1981), chap. 5, sec. 2, and Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990), chap. 3, sec. 3; Mary Douglas and Aaron Wildavsky, Risk and Culture: An Essay on the Selection of Technical and Environmental Dangers (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1982), chaps. 1-4; Jon Elster, "When Rationality Fails," in Solomonic Judgements (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989), chap. 1, sec. 3.
-
(1989)
Solomonic Judgements
-
-
Elster, J.1
-
45
-
-
85179185945
-
Structure, Growth and Power: Three Rationalist Accounts
-
ed. Robert Bates Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press
-
For a dissenting note, see Ronald Rogowski, "Structure, Growth and Power: Three Rationalist Accounts," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1988), pp. 300-330, quote on pp. 314-15. This discussion originally appeared in International Organization, vol. 37 (1983).
-
(1988)
Toward a Political Economy of Development
, pp. 300-330
-
-
Rogowski, R.1
-
46
-
-
11744365104
-
-
For a dissenting note, see Ronald Rogowski, "Structure, Growth and Power: Three Rationalist Accounts," in Toward a Political Economy of Development, ed. Robert Bates (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1988), pp. 300-330, quote on pp. 314-15. This discussion originally appeared in International Organization, vol. 37 (1983).
-
(1983)
International Organization
, vol.37
-
-
-
47
-
-
0003988939
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
For collections of such writings, see Peter Hall, ed., The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989); "Special Issue: Knowledge, Power and International Policy Coordination," International Organization 46, no. 1 (Winter 1992); and Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993). The terms "ideas" and "ideology" are generally used interchangeably in this literature.
-
(1989)
The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations
-
-
Hall, P.1
-
48
-
-
0002348552
-
Special Issue: Knowledge, Power and International Policy Coordination
-
Winter
-
For collections of such writings, see Peter Hall, ed., The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989); "Special Issue: Knowledge, Power and International Policy Coordination," International Organization 46, no. 1 (Winter 1992); and Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993). The terms "ideas" and "ideology" are generally used interchangeably in this literature.
-
(1992)
International Organization
, vol.46
, Issue.1
-
-
-
49
-
-
0003463272
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
For collections of such writings, see Peter Hall, ed., The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1989); "Special Issue: Knowledge, Power and International Policy Coordination," International Organization 46, no. 1 (Winter 1992); and Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993). The terms "ideas" and "ideology" are generally used interchangeably in this literature.
-
(1993)
Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change
-
-
Goldstein, J.1
Keohane, R.O.2
-
51
-
-
0010824985
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, esp. chap. 15
-
Most notably "strain" theories, which associate ideologies with rapid socioeconomic change. See Francis X. Sutton et al., The American Business Creed (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956), esp. chap. 15; Edward Shils, "Ideology," in The International Encyclopedia of Social Science, ed. David Sills (New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan, 1968), 7:66-75. Geertz isolated four ways in which ideologies can address strain: catharsis, morale boosting, solidarity creating, and an explanation of underlying discontents. See Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," (n. 10 above), p. 54. Using a slightly different approach, Lane proposed a paradigm in which ideological change is attributed to exogenous changes in "existential base" (socioeconomic conditions), cultural premises, personal qualities, and social conflicts, each of which is to a limited extent autonomous from the others. See Robert E. Lane, Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does (New York: Free Press, 1962), chap. 25. In a completely different vein, Raymond Boudon focuses on four different cognitive effects, which he labels positional, dispositional, communication, and "e" (epistemological). See his The Analysis of Ideology (Oxford: Polity, 1989), esp. chap. 5.
-
(1956)
The American Business Creed
-
-
Sutton, F.X.1
-
52
-
-
0002007615
-
Ideology
-
ed. David Sills New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan
-
Most notably "strain" theories, which associate ideologies with rapid socioeconomic change. See Francis X. Sutton et al., The American Business Creed (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956), esp. chap. 15; Edward Shils, "Ideology," in The International Encyclopedia of Social Science, ed. David Sills (New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan, 1968), 7:66-75. Geertz isolated four ways in which ideologies can address strain: catharsis, morale boosting, solidarity creating, and an explanation of underlying discontents. See Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," (n. 10 above), p. 54. Using a slightly different approach, Lane proposed a paradigm in which ideological change is attributed to exogenous changes in "existential base" (socioeconomic conditions), cultural premises, personal qualities, and social conflicts, each of which is to a limited extent autonomous from the others. See Robert E. Lane, Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does (New York: Free Press, 1962), chap. 25. In a completely different vein, Raymond Boudon focuses on four different cognitive effects, which he labels positional, dispositional, communication, and "e" (epistemological). See his The Analysis of Ideology (Oxford: Polity, 1989), esp. chap. 5.
-
(1968)
The International Encyclopedia of Social Science
, vol.7
, pp. 66-75
-
-
Shils, E.1
-
53
-
-
0347469788
-
-
n. 10 above
-
Most notably "strain" theories, which associate ideologies with rapid socioeconomic change. See Francis X. Sutton et al., The American Business Creed (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956), esp. chap. 15; Edward Shils, "Ideology," in The International Encyclopedia of Social Science, ed. David Sills (New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan, 1968), 7:66-75. Geertz isolated four ways in which ideologies can address strain: catharsis, morale boosting, solidarity creating, and an explanation of underlying discontents. See Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," (n. 10 above), p. 54. Using a slightly different approach, Lane proposed a paradigm in which ideological change is attributed to exogenous changes in "existential base" (socioeconomic conditions), cultural premises, personal qualities, and social conflicts, each of which is to a limited extent autonomous from the others. See Robert E. Lane, Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does (New York: Free Press, 1962), chap. 25. In a completely different vein, Raymond Boudon focuses on four different cognitive effects, which he labels positional, dispositional, communication, and "e" (epistemological). See his The Analysis of Ideology (Oxford: Polity, 1989), esp. chap. 5.
-
Ideology as a Cultural System
, pp. 54
-
-
Geertz1
-
54
-
-
0003438328
-
-
New York: Free Press, chap. 25
-
Most notably "strain" theories, which associate ideologies with rapid socioeconomic change. See Francis X. Sutton et al., The American Business Creed (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956), esp. chap. 15; Edward Shils, "Ideology," in The International Encyclopedia of Social Science, ed. David Sills (New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan, 1968), 7:66-75. Geertz isolated four ways in which ideologies can address strain: catharsis, morale boosting, solidarity creating, and an explanation of underlying discontents. See Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," (n. 10 above), p. 54. Using a slightly different approach, Lane proposed a paradigm in which ideological change is attributed to exogenous changes in "existential base" (socioeconomic conditions), cultural premises, personal qualities, and social conflicts, each of which is to a limited extent autonomous from the others. See Robert E. Lane, Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does (New York: Free Press, 1962), chap. 25. In a completely different vein, Raymond Boudon focuses on four different cognitive effects, which he labels positional, dispositional, communication, and "e" (epistemological). See his The Analysis of Ideology (Oxford: Polity, 1989), esp. chap. 5.
-
(1962)
Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does
-
-
Lane, R.E.1
-
55
-
-
0008656390
-
-
Oxford: Polity, esp. chap. 5
-
Most notably "strain" theories, which associate ideologies with rapid socioeconomic change. See Francis X. Sutton et al., The American Business Creed (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1956), esp. chap. 15; Edward Shils, "Ideology," in The International Encyclopedia of Social Science, ed. David Sills (New York: Crowell Collier & Macmillan, 1968), 7:66-75. Geertz isolated four ways in which ideologies can address strain: catharsis, morale boosting, solidarity creating, and an explanation of underlying discontents. See Geertz, "Ideology as a Cultural System," (n. 10 above), p. 54. Using a slightly different approach, Lane proposed a paradigm in which ideological change is attributed to exogenous changes in "existential base" (socioeconomic conditions), cultural premises, personal qualities, and social conflicts, each of which is to a limited extent autonomous from the others. See Robert E. Lane, Political Ideology: Why the American Common Man Believes What He Does (New York: Free Press, 1962), chap. 25. In a completely different vein, Raymond Boudon focuses on four different cognitive effects, which he labels positional, dispositional, communication, and "e" (epistemological). See his The Analysis of Ideology (Oxford: Polity, 1989), esp. chap. 5.
-
(1989)
The Analysis of Ideology
-
-
-
56
-
-
0014271630
-
Postdecisional Dissonance at Post Time
-
See, e.g., R. E. Knox and J. A. Inkster, "Postdecisional Dissonance at Post Time," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 8 (1968): 319-23; J. C. Younger, L. Walker, and A. J. Arrowood, "Postdecision Dissonance at the Fair," Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 3 (1977): 284-87.
-
(1968)
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology
, vol.8
, pp. 319-323
-
-
Knox, R.E.1
Inkster, J.A.2
-
57
-
-
0014271630
-
Postdecision Dissonance at the Fair
-
See, e.g., R. E. Knox and J. A. Inkster, "Postdecisional Dissonance at Post Time," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 8 (1968): 319-23; J. C. Younger, L. Walker, and A. J. Arrowood, "Postdecision Dissonance at the Fair," Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 3 (1977): 284-87.
-
(1977)
Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin
, vol.3
, pp. 284-287
-
-
Younger, J.C.1
Walker, L.2
Arrowood, A.J.3
-
58
-
-
0004213688
-
-
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press
-
Originating from work by Leon Festinger; see his A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1957).
-
(1957)
A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance
-
-
Festinger, L.1
-
59
-
-
85055898178
-
Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act
-
July
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1965)
Economic Development and Cultural Change
, vol.13
, Issue.4 PART 1
, pp. 385-393
-
-
Hirschman, A.O.1
-
60
-
-
0003610739
-
-
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, app. E
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1970)
Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States
, pp. 94-96
-
-
-
61
-
-
0003813171
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, chap. 4
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1974)
The Cybernetic Theory of Decision
-
-
Steinbruner, J.D.1
-
62
-
-
0003948199
-
-
New York: Basic, chap. 6
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1982)
Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior
-
-
Maital, S.1
-
63
-
-
0022172301
-
Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy
-
October/November
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1985)
World Development
, vol.13
, Issue.10-11
, pp. 1139-1149
-
-
James, J.1
Gutkind, E.2
-
64
-
-
38249037771
-
Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework
-
March
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1987)
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
, vol.8
, Issue.1
, pp. 61-73
-
-
Gilad, B.1
Kaish, S.2
Loeb, P.D.3
-
65
-
-
78049260738
-
The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance
-
June
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1982)
American Economic Review
, vol.72
, pp. 307-319
-
-
Akerlof, G.A.1
Dickens, W.T.2
-
66
-
-
84984503210
-
The Economics of Illusion
-
Spring
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1989)
Economics and Politics
, vol.1
, Issue.1
, pp. 1-15
-
-
Akerlof, G.A.1
-
67
-
-
0007885733
-
On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology
-
ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young Hants: Edward Elgar
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T.
-
(1992)
New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application
, pp. 49-65
-
-
Earl, P.E.1
-
68
-
-
85034299621
-
-
n. 17 above chap. 1, sec. 4
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
When Rationality Fails
-
-
Elster1
-
69
-
-
0004282536
-
-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, chap. 1
-
Albert O. Hirschman, "Obstacles to Development: A Classification and a Quasi-Vanishing Act," Economic Development and Cultural Change 13, no. 4, pt. 1 (July 1965): 385-93, and Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970), pp. 94-96, 113-14, and app. E; John D. Steinbruner, The Cybernetic Theory of Decision (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1974), chap. 4; Shlomo Maital, Minds, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (New York: Basic, 1982), chap. 6; Jeffrey James and Efraim Gutkind, "Attitude Change Revisited: Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Development Policy," World Development 13, nos. 10/11 (October/November 1985): 1139-49; Benjamin Gilad, Stanley Kaish, and Peter D. Loeb, "Cognitive Dissonance and Utility Maximization: A General Framework," Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 8, no. 1 (March 1987): 61-73; George A. Akerlof and William T. Dickens, "The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance," American Economic Review 72 (June 1982): 307-19; George A. Akerlof, "The Economics of Illusion," Economics and Politics 1, no. 1 (Spring 1989): 1-15; Peter E. Earl, "On the Complementarity of Economic Applications of Cognitive Dissonance Theory and Personal Construct Psychology," in New Directions in Economic Psychology: Theory, Experiment and Application, ed. Stephen E. G. Lea, Paul Webley, and Brian M. Young (Hants: Edward Elgar, 1992), pp. 49-65; Elster, "When Rationality Fails" (n. 17 above), chap. 1, sec. 4, and Jon Elster, Political Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1993), chap. 1.
-
(1993)
Political Psychology
-
-
Elster, J.1
-
71
-
-
85056746757
-
-
New York: Free Press, esp. chap. 5
-
These generalizations are clearly related to some of the propositions explored in Lewis Coser's classic, The Functions of Social Conflict (New York: Free Press, 1956), esp. chap. 5. However, unlike Coser's discussion, which emphasizes efforts on the part of group leaders to enforce intragroup ideological conformity under conditions of outside conflict, this analysis shows why conformist ideologies might in fact be internalized by group members.
-
(1956)
The Functions of Social Conflict
-
-
Coser, L.1
-
72
-
-
84946651784
-
Attitudes and Cognitive Organization
-
Fritz Heider, "Attitudes and Cognitive Organization," Journal of Psychology 21 (1946): 107-12.
-
(1946)
Journal of Psychology
, vol.21
, pp. 107-112
-
-
Heider, F.1
-
75
-
-
85034287065
-
-
note
-
Latin American countries that gained independence in the nineteenth century will not be considered in this category, both because the group with status quo control was not identified with a clear economic ideology and because the countries had gained independence such a long time ago, a point that will be elaborated on below.
-
-
-
-
76
-
-
85034291238
-
-
note
-
Of course, the theory would predict more extreme oppositional ideology formation within ex-Western colonies where conflict with the colonial power was particular long lasting and costly. However, measuring such variations in costliness is beyond the scope of this article and will be put aside in favor of examining the general tendencies toward oppositional ideology formation arising from anticolonial conflicts.
-
-
-
-
77
-
-
11744268572
-
Introduction to the First Edition
-
ed. Paul Sigmund, 2d ed. New York: Praeger
-
For general discussion on this point, see Paul Sigmund, "Introduction to the First Edition," in The Ideologies of the Developing Nations, ed. Paul Sigmund, 2d ed. (New York: Praeger, 1972), pp. 1-40, esp. pp. 13-15.
-
(1972)
The Ideologies of the Developing Nations
, pp. 1-40
-
-
Sigmund, P.1
-
79
-
-
0004424761
-
-
New York: Monthly Review
-
Amilcar Cabral, Unity and Struggle (New York: Monthly Review, 1979), p. 127.
-
(1979)
Unity and Struggle
, pp. 127
-
-
Cabral, A.1
-
83
-
-
0004118560
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
For contrasts between different systems of colonial rule, see Tony Smith, The Pattern of Imperialism: The United States, Great Britain and the Late-industrializing World since 1815 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981); and Miles Kahler, Decolonialization in Britain and France: The Domestic Consequences of International Relations (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984).
-
(1984)
Decolonialization in Britain and France: The Domestic Consequences of International Relations
-
-
Kahler, M.1
-
84
-
-
80052855090
-
-
New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press
-
See, e.g., Crawford Young, Ideology and Development in Africa (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1982), p. 189.
-
(1982)
Ideology and Development in Africa
, pp. 189
-
-
Young, C.1
-
85
-
-
5244298926
-
-
See Sigmund, "Introduction to the First Edition." See also Charles F. Andrain, "Democracy and Socialism," in Apter, ed. (n. 10 above), pp. 155-205. In Africa, Young has done a survey of the basic development strategies of 17 African countries, all of which are ex-Western colonies. Eight are classified as "Afro-Marxist," six as "populist socialist," and only three as "African capi-talist." See Young, chap. 1, and table 6.1 on p. 299.
-
Introduction to the First Edition
-
-
Sigmund1
-
86
-
-
85034285059
-
-
Apter, ed. (n. 10 above)
-
See Sigmund, "Introduction to the First Edition." See also Charles F. Andrain, "Democracy and Socialism," in Apter, ed. (n. 10 above), pp. 155-205. In Africa, Young has done a survey of the basic development strategies of 17 African countries, all of which are ex-Western colonies. Eight are classified as "Afro-Marxist," six as "populist socialist," and only three as "African capi-talist." See Young, chap. 1, and table 6.1 on p. 299.
-
Democracy and Socialism
, pp. 155-205
-
-
Andrain, C.F.1
-
87
-
-
11744361573
-
Africa again Betrayed
-
June Briefing Section
-
Wole Soyinka, "Africa again Betrayed," San Francisco Chronicle (June 5, 1991), Briefing Section, p. 2.
-
(1991)
San Francisco Chronicle
, vol.5
, pp. 2
-
-
Soyinka, W.1
-
88
-
-
85034309240
-
-
Young, p. 98
-
Young, p. 98.
-
-
-
-
89
-
-
0000962532
-
Ethnicity and Social Change
-
ed. Nathan Glazer and Daniel P. Moynihan Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press
-
Daniel Bell, "Ethnicity and Social Change," in Ethnicity: Theory and Experience, ed. Nathan Glazer and Daniel P. Moynihan (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1975), pp. 141-74, quote on pp. 150-51.
-
(1975)
Ethnicity: Theory and Experience
, pp. 141-174
-
-
Bell, D.1
-
91
-
-
0005210323
-
-
Dar es Salaam: Oxford University Press
-
Most notably Julius Nyerere, Ujamaa: Essays on Socialism (Dar es Salaam: Oxford University Press, 1968).
-
(1968)
Ujamaa: Essays on Socialism
-
-
Nyerere, J.1
-
95
-
-
11744255881
-
Back to the Future
-
(interview with Yoweri Museveni), July
-
"Back to the Future" (interview with Yoweri Museveni), New African 286 (July 1991): 10.
-
(1991)
New African
, vol.286
, pp. 10
-
-
-
96
-
-
85045733273
-
What Is Negritude?
-
November 4, Reprinted in Sigmund, ed. (n. 34)
-
Leopold Sedar Senghor, "What Is Negritude?" West Africa (November 4, 1961). Reprinted in Sigmund, ed. (n. 34), pp. 250-52. For a discussion of some of the links between African socialism and negritude, see Cynthia Enloe, Ethnic Conflict and Political Development: An Analytic Study (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973), pp. 73-81.
-
(1961)
West Africa
, pp. 250-252
-
-
Senghor, L.S.1
-
97
-
-
0003720338
-
-
Boston: Little, Brown
-
Leopold Sedar Senghor, "What Is Negritude?" West Africa (November 4, 1961). Reprinted in Sigmund, ed. (n. 34), pp. 250-52. For a discussion of some of the links between African socialism and negritude, see Cynthia Enloe, Ethnic Conflict and Political Development: An Analytic Study (Boston: Little, Brown, 1973), pp. 73-81.
-
(1973)
Ethnic Conflict and Political Development: An Analytic Study
, pp. 73-81
-
-
Enloe, C.1
-
98
-
-
85034297148
-
-
Plamenatz (n. 45 above), p. 29
-
Plamenatz (n. 45 above), p. 29.
-
-
-
-
100
-
-
0003601264
-
-
New York: Grove, chap. 4
-
See O. Mannoni, Prospero and Caliban: The Psychology of Colonization (New York: Praeger, 1964), pt. 1. See also the critique in Frantz Fanon, Black Skin, White Masks (New York: Grove, 1967), chap. 4.
-
(1967)
Black Skin, White Masks
-
-
Fanon, F.1
-
101
-
-
85059131052
-
Racism and Culture
-
ed. William Barclay, Krishna Kumar, Ruth Simms New York: AMS Press
-
See Frantz Fanon, "Racism and Culture," in Racial Conflict, Discrimination and Power: Historical and Contemporary Studies, ed. William Barclay, Krishna Kumar, Ruth Simms (New York: AMS Press, 1976), pp. 51-53, quote on p. 51.
-
(1976)
Racial Conflict, Discrimination and Power: Historical and Contemporary Studies
, pp. 51-53
-
-
Fanon, F.1
-
102
-
-
0003656081
-
-
New York: World Bank
-
See Jee-Peng Tan and Alain Mingat, Education in Asia (New York: World Bank, 1992), for a discussion of the adoption of Western-style education. On other Western practices, see David Abernethy, "Bureaucratic Growth and Economic Stagnation in Sub-Saharan Africa," in Africa's Development Challenge and the World Bank, ed. Stephen K. Commins (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1988), pp. 179-214.
-
(1992)
Education in Asia
-
-
Tan, J.-P.1
Mingat, A.2
-
103
-
-
0343314531
-
Bureaucratic Growth and Economic Stagnation in Sub-Saharan Africa
-
ed. Stephen K. Commins Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner
-
See Jee-Peng Tan and Alain Mingat, Education in Asia (New York: World Bank, 1992), for a discussion of the adoption of Western-style education. On other Western practices, see David Abernethy, "Bureaucratic Growth and Economic Stagnation in Sub-Saharan Africa," in Africa's Development Challenge and the World Bank, ed. Stephen K. Commins (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1988), pp. 179-214.
-
(1988)
Africa's Development Challenge and the World Bank
, pp. 179-214
-
-
Abernethy, D.1
-
104
-
-
11744282136
-
Schools Brief: Capitalism or Bust
-
February 8
-
"Schools Brief: Capitalism or Bust," Economist 322, no. 7745 (February 8, 1992): 49.
-
(1992)
Economist
, vol.322
, Issue.7745
, pp. 49
-
-
-
105
-
-
85012852926
-
Big Business and Politics in Prewar Japan
-
ed. James William Morley Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
Arthur E. Tiedmann, "Big Business and Politics in Prewar Japan," in Dilemmas of Growth in Prewar Japan, ed. James William Morley (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1971), pp. 267-318, esp. pp. 285-87.
-
(1971)
Dilemmas of Growth in Prewar Japan
, pp. 267-318
-
-
Tiedmann, A.E.1
-
106
-
-
11744358784
-
Class, Tribe and Party in West African Politics
-
ed. Seymour Martin Lipset and Stein Rokkan New York: Free Press
-
Immanuel Wallerstein, "Class, Tribe and Party in West African Politics," in Party Systems and Voter Alignments, ed. Seymour Martin Lipset and Stein Rokkan (New York: Free Press 1967), pp. 497-518, p. 500.
-
(1967)
Party Systems and Voter Alignments
, pp. 497-518
-
-
Wallerstein, I.1
-
107
-
-
85034294519
-
-
For the example of the Congress Party, see Nehru (n. 37 above), pp. 138-39, 350-51
-
For the example of the Congress Party, see Nehru (n. 37 above), pp. 138-39, 350-51. For the United Gold Coast Convention before the Convention People's Party split, see David E. Apter, The Gold Coast in Transition (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1959), pp. 168-72.
-
-
-
-
108
-
-
85050171964
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
For the example of the Congress Party, see Nehru (n. 37 above), pp. 138-39, 350-51. For the United Gold Coast Convention before the Convention People's Party split, see David E. Apter, The Gold Coast in Transition (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1959), pp. 168-72.
-
(1959)
The Gold Coast in Transition
, pp. 168-172
-
-
Apter, D.E.1
-
109
-
-
0007790709
-
-
Paris: OECD, table 2
-
See, e.g., the OECD's Development Cooperation Report (Paris: OECD, 1992), table 2.
-
(1992)
Development Cooperation Report
-
-
-
111
-
-
85034279709
-
-
note
-
Such analysis, of course, requires some fudging of a unitary model of the state. However, it can be retained formally by viewing this generational turnover as a structural attribute of the state rather than as a disaggregation.
-
-
-
-
112
-
-
0007637383
-
-
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press
-
In fact, if there is considerable political conflict between the first generation of anticolonial elites and a group of newer challengers to power, the theory would predict that a "counteroppositional" ideology would form around the challengers and that a kind of "cycling" may occur. For a discussion of this sort of phenomenon see James Smoot Coleman, Education and Political Development (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1965), p. 27.
-
(1965)
Education and Political Development
, pp. 27
-
-
Coleman, J.S.1
-
113
-
-
84984074121
-
International Comparisons of Real Product and Its Composition, 1950-77
-
March
-
For a detailed description of the original version of the data set, see Robert Summers, I. B. Kravis, and Alan Heston, "International Comparisons of Real Product and Its Composition, 1950-77," Review of Income and Wealth 26, no. 1 (March 1980): 19-66. For a description of a more recent version, see Robert Summers and Alan Heston, "The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988," Quarterly Journal of Economics (May 1991), pp. 327-40. The version used here is Mark 5.6, which has data up to 1992. This is available via anonymous ftp from nber.harvard.edu.
-
(1980)
Review of Income and Wealth
, vol.26
, Issue.1
, pp. 19-66
-
-
Summers, R.1
Kravis, I.B.2
Heston, A.3
-
114
-
-
84984074121
-
The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988
-
May
-
For a detailed description of the original version of the data set, see Robert Summers, I. B. Kravis, and Alan Heston, "International Comparisons of Real Product and Its Composition, 1950-77," Review of Income and Wealth 26, no. 1 (March 1980): 19-66. For a description of a more recent version, see Robert Summers and Alan Heston, "The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988," Quarterly Journal of Economics (May 1991), pp. 327-40. The version used here is Mark 5.6, which has data up to 1992. This is available via anonymous ftp from nber.harvard.edu.
-
(1991)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, pp. 327-340
-
-
Summers, R.1
Heston, A.2
-
115
-
-
85034305391
-
-
The 1992 version, with data from 1948-91, which is available from the Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR)
-
The 1992 version, with data from 1948-91, which is available from the Interuniversity Consortium for Political and Social Research (ICPSR).
-
-
-
-
116
-
-
85034302562
-
-
The 1995 version, with data from 1971-94, which is available from ICPSR
-
The 1995 version, with data from 1971-94, which is available from ICPSR.
-
-
-
-
117
-
-
85034292565
-
-
World Bank (see n. 1 above), p. 279
-
World Bank (see n. 1 above), p. 279.
-
-
-
-
118
-
-
85034285596
-
-
note
-
Overall spending levels were obtained from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) data set, while economic services spending levels were obtained from the Government Finance Statistics. They were divided by measures of GDP, obtained from the same data sets. Price-corrected goods and services as a share of GDP were obtained from the Penn World Tables.
-
-
-
-
119
-
-
84870967262
-
-
chaps. 4 and 5
-
This statistic was obtained from the Penn World Tables. It has been used as a measure of government intervention in Dollar (n. 3 above) and also was adopted in the 1991 issue of the World Bank's World Development Report, chaps. 4 and 5. A discussion of the justification for using aggregate relative prices as a measure of government-induced distortion can be found in Dollar, pp. 525-27.
-
World Development Report
-
-
-
120
-
-
0004296667
-
-
One way of testing this is to check exchange rate premiums (the gap between official and black market exchange rates). An official exchange rate that assigns a positive premium to local currency indicates distortions that inflate aggregate local prices relative to international prices, while a negative premium indicates distortions that deflate local prices. A premium of zero indicates non-distortive policies (see World Bank, World Development Report 1991, p. 82, for a discussion). Examination of 1990 estimates in the International Currency Yearbook (New York: International Currency Analysis, 1991), shows no cases where a negative premium occurs.
-
World Development Report 1991
, pp. 82
-
-
-
121
-
-
84909930687
-
-
New York: International Currency Analysis
-
One way of testing this is to check exchange rate premiums (the gap between official and black market exchange rates). An official exchange rate that assigns a positive premium to local currency indicates distortions that inflate aggregate local prices relative to international prices, while a negative premium indicates distortions that deflate local prices. A premium of zero indicates non-distortive policies (see World Bank, World Development Report 1991, p. 82, for a discussion). Examination of 1990 estimates in the International Currency Yearbook (New York: International Currency Analysis, 1991), shows no cases where a negative premium occurs.
-
(1991)
International Currency Yearbook
-
-
-
122
-
-
85034288103
-
-
note
-
A total of 74 countries in the three data sets were classified as ex-Western colonies. They were (with year of independence and colonial power in parentheses, B = British, F = French, O = other): Algeria (1962, F), Angola (1975, O), Bahamas (1972, B), Bangladesh (1947, B), Barbados (1966, B), Belize (1981, B), Benin (1960, F), Bhutan (1949, B), Botswana (1966, B), Burkina Faso (1960, F), Burundi (1962, B), Cameroon (1960, O), Cape Verde (1975, O), Central African Republic (1960, F), Chad (1960, F), Comoros (1975, F), Congo-Brazzaville (1960, F), Djibouti (1978, F), Fiji (1970, B), Gabon (1960, F), Gambia (1965, B), Ghana (1957, B), Grenada (1974, B), Guinea (1958, F), GuineaBissau (1974, O), Guyana (1966, B), India (1947, B), Indonesia (1949, O), Ivory Coast (1960, F), Jamaica (1962, B), Kenya (1963, B), Laos (1953, F), Lesotho (1966, B), Madagascar (1960, F), Malawi (1964, B), Malaysia (1957, B), Mali (1960, F), Malta (1964, B), Mauritania (1960, F), Mauritius (1968, B), Morocco (1956, F), Mozambique (1975, O), Myanmar (1948, B), Niger (1960, F), Nigeria (1960, B), Pakistan (1947, B), Papua New Guinea (1973, B), Philippines (1946, O), Reunion (1990, F), Rwanda (1961, O), Saint Lucia (1979, B), Saint Vincent and Grenadines (1979, B), Senegal (1960, F), Seychelles (1976, B), Sierra Leone (1961, B), Singapore (1959, B), Solomon Islands (1978, B), Somalia (1960, O), Sri Lanka (1948, B), Sudan (1956, B), Surinam (1975, O), Swaziland (1968, B), Syria (1946, F), Tanzania (1961, B), Togo (1960, F), Tonga (1970, B), Trinidad and Tobago (1962, B), Tunisia (1956, F), Uganda (1962, B), Vanuatu (1980, O), Western Samoa (1962, O), Zaire (1960, O), Zambia (1964, B), Zimbabwe (1980, O). Former British protectorates where indigenous rulers retained a measure of formal political control for long periods of time (e.g., Egypt, Iraq, Jordan, Nepal, and the gulf states) were not considered as former colonies, although their inclusion did not significantly change the results of regressions. Among the former colonies not covered in any of the data sets are Cambodia, Equatorial Guinea, Lebanon, Libya, and Vietnam.
-
-
-
-
123
-
-
85034290947
-
-
note
-
The Latin America category included Antigua Barbuda, Argentina, the Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Dominica, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Grenada, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Puerto Rico, Saint Kitts and Nevis, Saint Lucia, Saint Vincent and the Grenadines, Surinam, Trinidad and Tobago, Uruguay, and Venezuela. The African category included Angola, Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, the Central African Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo-Brazzaville, Equatorial Guinea, Ethiopia, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, the Ivory Coast, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Madagascar, Malawi, the Maldives, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mozambique, Namibia, Niger, Nigeria, Reunion, Rwanda, Sao Tome Principe, Senegal, the Seychelles, Sierra Leone, Somalia, South Africa, Sudan, Swaziland, Tanzania, Togo, Uganda, Zaire, Zambia, and Zimbabwe. The East Asian category included Cambodia, China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, North Korea, South Korea, Laos, Malaysia, Mongolia, Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam.
-
-
-
-
124
-
-
85034287617
-
-
note
-
The achievement of independence can be likened to the boundary change or other disruptive events that Olson (n. 7 above) uses to mark the beginning of the formation of distributive coalitions.
-
-
-
-
125
-
-
0004296667
-
-
Among other authors who have used aggregate prices as a measure of intervention, Dollar (pp. 526-28) purges for labor and land costs by including independent variables for per capita GDP and population density. The World Bank uses a slightly different methodology, with variables for urbanization, land area and population. See World Bank, World Development Report 1991, p. 163.
-
World Development Report 1991
, pp. 163
-
-
-
126
-
-
85034297456
-
-
note
-
Data for GDP and populations variables were obtained from the same data sets as the dependent variables against which they were regressed. The IMF GDP data were in local currency, so figures in constant dollars were obtained by dividing each by the current local currency unit per dollar exchange rate, then by the current GDP deflator for the United States (1985 dollars = 1 for IFS; 1990 dollars = 1 for GFS). Data for land area were obtained primarily from the World Bank's World Development Report 1991.
-
-
-
-
127
-
-
85034293044
-
-
note
-
When each data set was reduced to those observations that included complete data for these models, they consisted of time series with varying starting points and lengths for different countries. In order to provide reasonably stable estimates of cross-sectional heteroscedacity, observations for countries whose times series were shorter than 10 years were deleted. However, no attempt was made to convert the data sets into panels, because this would have resulted in deletion of most of the data for the IMF data sets and an unrepresentative sample biased toward industrialized countries.
-
-
-
|