-
1
-
-
0004274890
-
-
New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Przeworski, Democracy and the Market (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991), 138.
-
(1991)
Democracy and the Market
, pp. 138
-
-
Przeworski1
-
2
-
-
0000497890
-
The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change
-
Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., Princeton: Princeton University Press
-
Variations on this theme have stressed the virtues of autonomous states (Peter Evans, "The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change," in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992]); powerful executives (Stephan Haggard and Robert Kaufman, The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995]); insulated technocrats (John Williamson, "In Search of a Manual for Technopols," in Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform [Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies, 1994]); and substantial external assistance (Jeffrey Sachs, "Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms," in Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States [New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1993]). Przeworski himself does not support such a view, which he believes will lead to problems in the consolidation of democracy; Przeworski, "Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective," in Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).
-
(1992)
The Politics of Economic Adjustment
-
-
Evans, P.1
-
3
-
-
0004094016
-
-
Princeton: Princeton University Press
-
Variations on this theme have stressed the virtues of autonomous states (Peter Evans, "The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change," in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992]); powerful executives (Stephan Haggard and Robert Kaufman, The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995]); insulated technocrats (John Williamson, "In Search of a Manual for Technopols," in Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform [Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies, 1994]); and substantial external assistance (Jeffrey Sachs, "Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms," in Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States [New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1993]). Przeworski himself does not support such a view, which he believes will lead to problems in the consolidation of democracy; Przeworski, "Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective," in Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).
-
(1995)
The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions
-
-
Haggard, S.1
Kaufman, R.2
-
4
-
-
0002374739
-
In Search of a Manual for Technopols
-
Williamson, ed., Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies
-
Variations on this theme have stressed the virtues of autonomous states (Peter Evans, "The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change," in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992]); powerful executives (Stephan Haggard and Robert Kaufman, The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995]); insulated technocrats (John Williamson, "In Search of a Manual for Technopols," in Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform [Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies, 1994]); and substantial external assistance (Jeffrey Sachs, "Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms," in Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States [New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1993]). Przeworski himself does not support such a view, which he believes will lead to problems in the consolidation of democracy; Przeworski, "Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective," in Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).
-
(1994)
The Political Economy of Policy Reform
-
-
Williamson, J.1
-
5
-
-
0002360925
-
Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms
-
Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., New York: Council on Foreign Relations
-
Variations on this theme have stressed the virtues of autonomous states (Peter Evans, "The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change," in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992]); powerful executives (Stephan Haggard and Robert Kaufman, The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995]); insulated technocrats (John Williamson, "In Search of a Manual for Technopols," in Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform [Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies, 1994]); and substantial external assistance (Jeffrey Sachs, "Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms," in Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States [New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1993]). Przeworski himself does not support such a view, which he believes will lead to problems in the consolidation of democracy; Przeworski, "Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective," in Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).
-
(1993)
Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States
-
-
Sachs, J.1
-
6
-
-
0002003525
-
Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective
-
Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, New York: Cambridge University Press
-
Variations on this theme have stressed the virtues of autonomous states (Peter Evans, "The State as Problem and Solution: Predation, Embedded Autonomy, and Structural Change," in Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman, eds., The Politics of Economic Adjustment [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1992]); powerful executives (Stephan Haggard and Robert Kaufman, The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions [Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995]); insulated technocrats (John Williamson, "In Search of a Manual for Technopols," in Williamson, ed., The Political Economy of Policy Reform [Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Studies, 1994]); and substantial external assistance (Jeffrey Sachs, "Western Financial Assistance and Russia's Reforms," in Shafiq Islam and Michael Mandelbaum, eds., Making Markets: Economic Transformation in Eastern Europe and the Post-Soviet States [New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1993]). Przeworski himself does not support such a view, which he believes will lead to problems in the consolidation of democracy; Przeworski, "Economic Reforms, Public Opinion, and Political Institutions: Poland in the Eastern European Perspective," in Luis C. B. Pereira, Mario M. Maravall, and Adam Przeworski, Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993).
-
(1993)
Economic Reforms in New Democracies: A Social-Democratic Approach
-
-
Przeworski1
-
7
-
-
84984474607
-
The Role of Political Constraints in Transition Economies
-
This is one of the arguments made against the radical or "big bang" approach to economic reform. For a review of the political economy case against such an approach, see Gerard Roland, "The Role of Political Constraints in Transition Economies," Economics of Transition 2, no. 1 (1994).
-
(1994)
Economics of Transition
, vol.2
, Issue.1
-
-
Roland, G.1
-
8
-
-
0007003374
-
-
Manuscript, Cambridge, Mass.
-
In the expected utility function of any given actor, the benefits of reform would be discounted by the probability that the reform will be reversed prior to the receipt of the benefits. For a review of this problem in the politics of economic reform, see Mariano Tommasi and Andres Velasco, "Where Are We in the Political Economy of Reform?" (Manuscript, Cambridge, Mass., 1995).
-
(1995)
Where Are We in the Political Economy of Reform?
-
-
Tommasi, M.1
Velasco, A.2
-
9
-
-
84923746033
-
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2, 1995)
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2, 1995).
-
-
-
-
10
-
-
0003568437
-
-
New Haven: Yale University Press
-
On the earlier literature, see the classic treatment of this issue in Samuel Huntingdon, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968); and the review in Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990). The recent work on the advantages of state autonomy and insulation is voluminous. Some prominent examples are Evans (fn. 2); Haggard and Kaufman, "Economic Adjustment and the Prospects for Democracy," in Haggard and Kaufman (fh. 2, 1992); idem (fn. 2, 1995); and the contributions to Williamson (fn. 2).
-
(1968)
Political Order in Changing Societies
-
-
Huntingdon, S.1
-
11
-
-
0004023051
-
-
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
On the earlier literature, see the classic treatment of this issue in Samuel Huntingdon, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968); and the review in Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990). The recent work on the advantages of state autonomy and insulation is voluminous. Some prominent examples are Evans (fn. 2); Haggard and Kaufman, "Economic Adjustment and the Prospects for Democracy," in Haggard and Kaufman (fh. 2, 1992); idem (fn. 2, 1995); and the contributions to Williamson (fn. 2).
-
(1990)
Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries
-
-
Haggard, S.1
-
12
-
-
0002505405
-
-
Haggard and Kaufman fh. 2, idem fn. 2
-
On the earlier literature, see the classic treatment of this issue in Samuel Huntingdon, Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1968); and the review in Stephan Haggard, Pathways from the Periphery: The Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990). The recent work on the advantages of state autonomy and insulation is voluminous. Some prominent examples are Evans (fn. 2); Haggard and Kaufman, "Economic Adjustment and the Prospects for Democracy," in Haggard and Kaufman (fh. 2, 1992); idem (fn. 2, 1995); and the contributions to Williamson (fn. 2).
-
(1992)
Economic Adjustment and the Prospects for Democracy
-
-
Haggard1
Kaufman2
-
13
-
-
0027455881
-
The Politics of Economic Transformation: Is Third World Experience Relevant in Eastern Europe?
-
April
-
Nelson argues that this approach can be directly applied to the postcommunist transitions; Joan M. Nelson, "The Politics of Economic Transformation: Is Third World Experience Relevant in Eastern Europe?" World Politics 45 (April 1993).
-
(1993)
World Politics
, vol.45
-
-
Nelson, J.M.1
-
14
-
-
0003642227
-
-
London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1994)
Transition Report, 1994
-
-
-
15
-
-
0003642239
-
-
idem, London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1995)
Transition Report, 1995
-
-
-
16
-
-
0003464370
-
-
Washington, D.C.: World Bank
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1996)
World Development Report, 1996
-
-
-
17
-
-
0011287048
-
How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1996)
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
-
-
Aslund, A.1
Boone, P.2
Johnson, S.3
-
18
-
-
0003219686
-
From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1996)
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
, Issue.1564
-
-
De Melo, M.1
Denizer, C.2
Gelb, A.3
-
19
-
-
5844362042
-
-
Manuscript, Washington, D.C.
-
Broad, cross-national comparisons of the postcommunist transitions include EBRD, Transition Report, 1994 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1994); idem, Transition Report, 1995 (London: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1995); and World Bank, World Development Report, 1996 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1996). Other studies include Anders Aslund, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, "How to Stabilize: Lessons from the Postcommunist Countries," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1996); Martha de Melo, Cevdet Denizer, and Alan Gelb, From Plan to Market: Patterns of Transition, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1564 (1996); and Stanley Fischer, Rajiv Sahay, and Carlos Vegh, "Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience" (Manuscript, Washington, D.C., 1996).
-
(1996)
Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience
-
-
Fischer, S.1
Sahay, R.2
Vegh, C.3
-
20
-
-
84923746032
-
-
World Bank (fn. 8)
-
World Bank (fn. 8).
-
-
-
-
21
-
-
85033299331
-
-
note
-
The groups exclude those countries affected by war: Armenia, Azerbaijan, Croatia, Georgia, Macedonia, and Tajikistan.
-
-
-
-
22
-
-
85033279927
-
-
note
-
Similar results can be obtained by replacing the economic reforms ratings of the World Bank with transition indicators developed by the EBRD that measure progress in six categories of reform; EBRD (fn. 8, 1994). The EBRD measures include more institutional variables in their ratings.
-
-
-
-
23
-
-
84923746029
-
-
De Melo, Denizer, and Gelb (fn. 8)
-
De Melo, Denizer, and Gelb (fn. 8).
-
-
-
-
24
-
-
84923746028
-
-
Åslund, Boone, and Johnson (fn. 8)
-
Åslund, Boone, and Johnson (fn. 8) find no direct statistical correlation between the extent of economic reforms adopted and the magnitude of cumulative output declines once some basic control variables are added to the regression. They do not test for the existence of a nonlinear relationship as Figure 2 would suggest. Nevertheless, they reach the same conclusion through comparative case analysis.
-
-
-
-
25
-
-
85033297000
-
-
note
-
Unemployment data from the postcommunist countries have serious reliability problems and therefore must be used cautiously.
-
-
-
-
26
-
-
84923746026
-
-
Åslund, Boone, and Johnson (fn. 8)
-
Åslund, Boone, and Johnson (fn. 8).
-
-
-
-
27
-
-
84923746025
-
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2, 1995), 156
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2, 1995), 156.
-
-
-
-
28
-
-
85033315096
-
-
note
-
Postcommunist cases affected by war are excluded because executive turnovers are much more likely to be affected by the dynamics of war.
-
-
-
-
29
-
-
85033323501
-
-
note
-
Executive turnovers consist of the number of times the country's lead policy-making executive has been replaced during the time period. In presidential systems, presidential turnovers are counted. In parliamentary and semipresidential systems, prime ministerial turnovers are counted. A count of zero signifies that the same executive governing the country under communist rule was still governing the country through the transition, thus indicating no executive turnovers at all.
-
-
-
-
30
-
-
85033310665
-
-
note
-
Government tenure consists of the number of months in which the leading executive (president in presidential systems and prime minister in parliamentary and semipresidential systems) has remained in office.
-
-
-
-
31
-
-
0010577242
-
Slovenia's Road to Democracy
-
On Slovenia, see Sabena Petra Ramet, "Slovenia's Road to Democracy," Europe-Asia Studies 45, no. 5 (1993); and Boris Pleskovic and Jeffrey D. Sachs, "Political Independence and Economic Reform in Slovenia," in Oliver J. Blanchard, Kenneth A. Froot, and Jeffrey D. Sachs, eds., The Transition in Eastern Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994), 1.
-
(1993)
Europe-Asia Studies
, vol.45
, Issue.5
-
-
Ramet, S.P.1
-
32
-
-
0010121110
-
Political Independence and Economic Reform in Slovenia
-
Oliver J. Blanchard, Kenneth A. Froot, and Jeffrey D. Sachs, eds., Chicago: University of Chicago Press
-
On Slovenia, see Sabena Petra Ramet, "Slovenia's Road to Democracy," Europe-Asia Studies 45, no. 5 (1993); and Boris Pleskovic and Jeffrey D. Sachs, "Political Independence and Economic Reform in Slovenia," in Oliver J. Blanchard, Kenneth A. Froot, and Jeffrey D. Sachs, eds., The Transition in Eastern Europe (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994), 1.
-
(1994)
The Transition in Eastern Europe
, pp. 1
-
-
Pleskovic, B.1
Sachs, J.D.2
-
33
-
-
5844312117
-
-
Manuscript
-
On Hungary, see David L. Bartlett, "Stabilization, Adjustment, and Reform: The Political Economy of Transition in Hungary" (Manuscript, 1995); Laszlo Bruszt and David Stark, "Remaking the Political Field in Hungary: From the Politics of Confrontation to the Politics of Competition," in Ivo Banac, ed., Eastern Europe in Revolution (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992); and Valerie Bunce and Mario Csanadi, "Uncertainty in the Transition: Post-Communism in Hungary," East European Politics and Society 7, no. 2 (1993).
-
(1995)
Stabilization, Adjustment, and Reform: The Political Economy of Transition in Hungary
-
-
Bartlett, D.L.1
-
34
-
-
0006795940
-
Remaking the Political Field in Hungary: From the Politics of Confrontation to the Politics of Competition
-
Ivo Banac, ed., Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press
-
On Hungary, see David L. Bartlett, "Stabilization, Adjustment, and Reform: The Political Economy of Transition in Hungary" (Manuscript, 1995); Laszlo Bruszt and David Stark, "Remaking the Political Field in Hungary: From the Politics of Confrontation to the Politics of Competition," in Ivo Banac, ed., Eastern Europe in Revolution (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992); and Valerie Bunce and Mario Csanadi, "Uncertainty in the Transition: Post-Communism in Hungary," East European Politics and Society 7, no. 2 (1993).
-
(1992)
Eastern Europe in Revolution
-
-
Bruszt, L.1
Stark, D.2
-
35
-
-
0000239593
-
Uncertainty in the Transition: Post-Communism in Hungary
-
On Hungary, see David L. Bartlett, "Stabilization, Adjustment, and Reform: The Political Economy of Transition in Hungary" (Manuscript, 1995); Laszlo Bruszt and David Stark, "Remaking the Political Field in Hungary: From the Politics of Confrontation to the Politics of Competition," in Ivo Banac, ed., Eastern Europe in Revolution (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992); and Valerie Bunce and Mario Csanadi, "Uncertainty in the Transition: Post-Communism in Hungary," East European Politics and Society 7, no. 2 (1993).
-
(1993)
East European Politics and Society
, vol.7
, Issue.2
-
-
Bunce, V.1
Csanadi, M.2
-
36
-
-
0003530745
-
-
Ph.D. diss., Yale University
-
Even Vaclav Klaus has faced strong electoral pressures, as evidenced by his poor performance in the 1996 parliamentary elections. Klaus's three-party coalition government lost its majority share and has been governing as a minority coalition. On the Czech Republic, see Mitchell Orenstein, "Out of the Red: Building Capitalism and Democracy in Post-Communist Europe" (Ph.D. diss., Yale University, 1996).
-
(1996)
Out of the Red: Building Capitalism and Democracy in Post-Communist Europe
-
-
Orenstein, M.1
-
37
-
-
85033318043
-
-
note
-
This should not be taken as a proxy measure for the continued dominance of former communist rulers in the postcommunist era. Not all of the slow reformers have faced continuous rule by former communist leaders. Kazakhstan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan did continue to be governed by chief executives who were former first secretaries of their respective communist parties prior to the transition. The first leader of Ukraine, Leonid Kravchuk, was formerly second secretary of the Ukranian Communist Party. In Belarus, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, and Russia, new chief executives were elected, most of whom held previous positions - though not the leading positions - in the communist parties of their respective republics prior to the transition.
-
-
-
-
38
-
-
0040556194
-
-
Banac (fn. 21)
-
Romania is a semipresidential system in which the popularly elected president shares considerable powers with a parliamentary government. Since 1990 Romania has had three prime ministers with an average tenure of twenty-one months each. On Romania, see Katherine Verdery and Gail Kligman, "Romania after Ceausescu: Postcommunist Communism?" in Banac (fn. 21).
-
Romania after Ceausescu: Postcommunist Communism?
-
-
Verdery, K.1
Kligman, G.2
-
39
-
-
5844313978
-
-
Manuscript
-
In a recent paper on the politics of stabilization in postcommunist systems, I show that stabilization programs are as likely to be introduced just before elections - the moment of greatest insecurity in a politician's tenure - as immediately after electoral victories; see Joel S. Hellman, "Competitive Advantage: Political Competition and Economic Reform in Post-Communist Transitions" (Manuscript, 1996).
-
(1996)
Competitive Advantage: Political Competition and Economic Reform in Post-Communist Transitions
-
-
Hellman, J.S.1
-
40
-
-
84923746020
-
-
Przeworski (fn. 1), 179
-
Przeworski (fn. 1), 179.
-
-
-
-
41
-
-
85033304122
-
-
note
-
Similarly, the EBRD's transition indicators measuring progress in economic reform in six categories in 1994 and nine categories in 1995 do not reflect any backtracking on reform scores in any of the postcommunist countries; EBRD (fn. 8, 1994, 1995).
-
-
-
-
42
-
-
0004019885
-
-
2 vols. Budapest: Central European University
-
For detailed accounts of the privatization process in Central Europe and the Baltic states, see Roman Frydman and Andrzej Rapaczynski, The Privatization Process in Central Europe, 2 vols. (Budapest: Central European University, 1993).
-
(1993)
The Privatization Process in Central Europe
-
-
Frydman, R.1
Rapaczynski, A.2
-
44
-
-
85033295054
-
-
note
-
For assessments of macroeconomic policy in Hungary and Lithuania, see the country sections in EBRD (fn. 8, 1995).
-
-
-
-
45
-
-
85033311712
-
-
note
-
Of course, this does not preclude such reform reversals in the future, nor is it necessarily advantageous for the creation of a stable democracy. Przeworski (fn. 2) expresses the concern that electoral backlashes against reformers that do not lead to backtracking on economic reform can be politically destabilizing in emerging democracies. If voters continue to find that their votes are not reflected in policy changes, then they could lose confidence in the democratic process and be more attracted to authoritarian solutions.
-
-
-
-
46
-
-
0006742209
-
Political Economy of Sequencing Tactics in the Transition Period
-
Laszlo Csaba, ed., Aldershot, U.K.: Dartmouth Press, and idem (fn. 3)
-
This assumption is especially important in political economy models that are designed to high-light the advantages of gradual reforms. Roland argues that the best political strategy of reform is to start with measures that produce winners in the short term who gain a stake in the reform process that they will continue to defend once more costly measures need to be adopted down the road. See Gerard Roland, "Political Economy of Sequencing Tactics in the Transition Period," in Laszlo Csaba, ed., Systemic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe (Aldershot, U.K.: Dartmouth Press, 1991); and idem (fn. 3). This is also the spirit of Murrell's critique of the shock therapy reform program; Peter Murrell, "Conservative Political Philosophy and the Strategy of the Economic Transition," East European Politics and Societies 6, no. 1 (1993); and idem, "Evolution in Economics and in the Economic Reform of the Centrally Planned Economies," in Christopher Clague and Gordon C. Rausser, eds., The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell, 1992).
-
(1991)
Systemic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe
-
-
Roland, G.1
-
47
-
-
84977014137
-
Conservative Political Philosophy and the Strategy of the Economic Transition
-
This assumption is especially important in political economy models that are designed to high-light the advantages of gradual reforms. Roland argues that the best political strategy of reform is to start with measures that produce winners in the short term who gain a stake in the reform process that they will continue to defend once more costly measures need to be adopted down the road. See Gerard Roland, "Political Economy of Sequencing Tactics in the Transition Period," in Laszlo Csaba, ed., Systemic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe (Aldershot, U.K.: Dartmouth Press, 1991); and idem (fn. 3). This is also the spirit of Murrell's critique of the shock therapy reform program; Peter Murrell, "Conservative Political Philosophy and the Strategy of the Economic Transition," East European Politics and Societies 6, no. 1 (1993); and idem, "Evolution in Economics and in the Economic Reform of the Centrally Planned Economies," in Christopher Clague and Gordon C. Rausser, eds., The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell, 1992).
-
(1993)
East European Politics and Societies
, vol.6
, Issue.1
-
-
Murrell, P.1
-
48
-
-
0001898001
-
Evolution in Economics and in the Economic Reform of the Centrally Planned Economies
-
Christopher Clague and Gordon C. Rausser, eds., Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell
-
This assumption is especially important in political economy models that are designed to high-light the advantages of gradual reforms. Roland argues that the best political strategy of reform is to start with measures that produce winners in the short term who gain a stake in the reform process that they will continue to defend once more costly measures need to be adopted down the road. See Gerard Roland, "Political Economy of Sequencing Tactics in the Transition Period," in Laszlo Csaba, ed., Systemic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe (Aldershot, U.K.: Dartmouth Press, 1991); and idem (fn. 3). This is also the spirit of Murrell's critique of the shock therapy reform program; Peter Murrell, "Conservative Political Philosophy and the Strategy of the Economic Transition," East European Politics and Societies 6, no. 1 (1993); and idem, "Evolution in Economics and in the Economic Reform of the Centrally Planned Economies," in Christopher Clague and Gordon C. Rausser, eds., The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe (Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell, 1992).
-
(1992)
The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe
-
-
Murrell, P.1
-
49
-
-
84923746016
-
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2,1995), chap. 1
-
Haggard and Kaufman (fn. 2,1995), chap. 1, emphasize this collective action dilemma in the political economy of reform.
-
-
-
-
50
-
-
84960583830
-
The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform
-
The only work that explicitly examines the dynamics of partial reform is Kevin M. Murphy, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, "The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform," Quarterly Journal of Economics 57, no. 3 (1992). Ronald I. McKinnon touches on this issue in his analysis of different sequences of economic reform; see McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991). Richard E. Ericson discusses the social costs of partial reforms in the specific context of the transition from centrally planned economies, though he does not explore the distribution of gains from such reforms; see Ericson, "The Classical Soviet-Type Economy: Nature of the System and Implications for Reform," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 4 (1991).
-
(1992)
Quarterly Journal of Economics
, vol.57
, Issue.3
-
-
Murphy, K.M.1
Shleifer, A.2
Vishny, R.3
-
51
-
-
84960583830
-
-
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press
-
The only work that explicitly examines the dynamics of partial reform is Kevin M. Murphy, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, "The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform," Quarterly Journal of Economics 57, no. 3 (1992). Ronald I. McKinnon touches on this issue in his analysis of different sequences of economic reform; see McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991). Richard E. Ericson discusses the social costs of partial reforms in the specific context of the transition from centrally planned economies, though he does not explore the distribution of gains from such reforms; see Ericson, "The Classical Soviet-Type Economy: Nature of the System and Implications for Reform," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 4 (1991).
-
(1991)
The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy
-
-
McKinnon1
-
52
-
-
84960583830
-
The Classical Soviet-Type Economy: Nature of the System and Implications for Reform
-
The only work that explicitly examines the dynamics of partial reform is Kevin M. Murphy, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, "The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform," Quarterly Journal of Economics 57, no. 3 (1992). Ronald I. McKinnon touches on this issue in his analysis of different sequences of economic reform; see McKinnon, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1991). Richard E. Ericson discusses the social costs of partial reforms in the specific context of the transition from centrally planned economies, though he does not explore the distribution of gains from such reforms; see Ericson, "The Classical Soviet-Type Economy: Nature of the System and Implications for Reform," Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 4 (1991).
-
(1991)
Journal of Economic Perspectives
, vol.5
, Issue.4
-
-
Ericson1
-
53
-
-
84923746015
-
-
Ericson (fn. 34)
-
Ericson (fn. 34).
-
-
-
-
54
-
-
85033287864
-
-
note
-
The fact that such market distortions exist does not guarantee that actors will be able to take advantage of them in these partially reformed economies. It is possible that a highly restrictive state could build walls between the liberalized and more highly controlled spheres of the economy, preventing actors from gaining access to these rent-seeking opportunities. This is often the explanation for the success of China's partially reformed economy, though press reports of high levels of corruption within China's state sector suggest that there are limits to the state's capacity to enforce such restrictions; Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishnay (fn. 34).
-
-
-
-
55
-
-
85033322847
-
-
note
-
Of course, these are not the only components of comprehensive reform, but they do encompass what are generally considered to be the key elements of reform. See EBRD (fh. 8, 1995).
-
-
-
-
56
-
-
85033311368
-
-
note
-
Such a measure assumes that the distance separating the thresholds of the 1-4 scale within each dimension are directly comparable across all the dimensions, which may not necessarily be the case. As a result, this measure of partial reform should be interpreted with considerable caution. Given the potential measurement error in gauging partial reform, it would not be appropriate to use these data in any sophisticated statistical tests. Rather, at this stage the data are more suggestive of trends that are worthy of further empirical investigation.
-
-
-
-
57
-
-
0004095709
-
Poverty, Inequality and Social Policy in Transition Economies
-
The World Bank has collected the only detailed data on inequality and the concentration of incomes in the transition economies based on household surveys. Unfortunately, because data are not available on the entire set of transition economies, it is impossible to make any statistical tests on this small sample of countries. Branko Milanovic presents the data and provides an interesting analysis of the relationship between inequality and poverty. See Milanovic, Poverty, Inequality and Social Policy in Transition Economies," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1530 (1995); and idem, Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition, Transition Economies Division Research Paper Series 11 (1996). Data on inequality among postcommunist countries require more than the standard caveats in this field, given the strong incentives to hide income from taxation at all levels. Gini coefficients from the prereform period should be biased downward, given the ideological constraints on revealing inequalities in socialist systems and the numerous forms of perquisites in kind available to the nomenklatura. In the transition period Gini coefficients are likely to be biased downward, as higher income groups have greater access to outlets for hiding income than do those in lower income groups.
-
(1995)
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
, Issue.1530
-
-
Milanovic1
-
58
-
-
0003938177
-
Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition
-
The World Bank has collected the only detailed data on inequality and the concentration of incomes in the transition economies based on household surveys. Unfortunately, because data are not available on the entire set of transition economies, it is impossible to make any statistical tests on this small sample of countries. Branko Milanovic presents the data and provides an interesting analysis of the relationship between inequality and poverty. See Milanovic, Poverty, Inequality and Social Policy in Transition Economies," World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, no. 1530 (1995); and idem, Income, Inequality and Poverty during the Transition, Transition Economies Division Research Paper Series 11 (1996). Data on inequality among postcommunist countries require more than the standard caveats in this field, given the strong incentives to hide income from taxation at all levels. Gini coefficients from the prereform period should be biased downward, given the ideological constraints on revealing inequalities in socialist systems and the numerous forms of perquisites in kind available to the nomenklatura. In the transition period Gini coefficients are likely to be biased downward, as higher income groups have greater access to outlets for hiding income than do those in lower income groups.
-
(1996)
Transition Economies Division Research Paper Series 11
-
-
Milanovic1
-
59
-
-
84923746011
-
-
Milanovic (fn. 39, 1996), chap. 4
-
Milanovic (fn. 39, 1996), chap. 4.
-
-
-
-
60
-
-
85033303635
-
-
note
-
Countries that adopt radical economic reforms from the very start are not necessarily immune from this problem. Even the most radical reform programs are composed of multiple elements each with a different time horizon giving rise to temporary market distortions and arbitrage opportunities that produce concentrated gains in the short term. Since the reform process does not consist of a single choice of reform programs, but rather is a sequence of numerous choices on separate dimensions of reform over time, there are still many opportunities for the short-term winners to scale back the intentions of radical reformers.
-
-
-
-
61
-
-
0344492607
-
-
St. Petersburg: Norma
-
Dmitriev et al. provide a detailed analysis of the rents to newly created commercial banks directly related to the lack of macroeconomic stabilization in the context of a highly liberalized financial system and how quickly those rents declined as the economy began to stabilize. See Mikhail E. Dmitriev et al., Rossiiskie Banki Nakanune Finansovoi Stabiliaztsii (Russian banks on the eve of financial stabilization) (St. Petersburg: Norma, 1996).
-
(1996)
Rossiiskie Banki Nakanune Finansovoi Stabiliaztsii (Russian Banks on the Eve of Financial Stabilization)
-
-
Dmitriev, M.E.1
-
62
-
-
84923746009
-
-
EBRD (fn. 8, 1994)
-
EBRD (fn. 8, 1994).
-
-
-
-
64
-
-
84976104285
-
Decision-Making in Political Systems: Veto in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism
-
Tsebelis argues that increasing the number of parties in a coalition government increases the number of veto points in the policy-making process; see George Tsebelis, "Decision-Making in Political Systems: Veto in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism," British Journal of Political Science 25 (1995).
-
(1995)
British Journal of Political Science
, vol.25
-
-
Tsebelis, G.1
-
65
-
-
0024484766
-
Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries
-
The scale is slightly modified for the postcommunist countries to include a category for single-parry governments that explicitly restrict party competition. The scale is as follows: 1 = one-party authoritarian government (competition restricted); 2 = one-party majority parliamentary government or united presidential government; 3 = two-party coalition government or divided presidential government; 4 = three- or more party government; and 5 = minority government. Monthly coalition government scores were coded for each postcommunist country beginning with the first free election or the formal declaration of independence. A weighted average of the monthly scores is used in the scatterplot graph. See Nouriel Roubini and Jeffrey Sachs, "Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries," Economic Policy 8 (1989); and idem "Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies," European Economic Review 33 (1989).
-
(1989)
Economic Policy
, vol.8
-
-
Roubini, N.1
Sachs, J.2
-
66
-
-
0010543423
-
Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies
-
The scale is slightly modified for the postcommunist countries to include a category for single-parry governments that explicitly restrict party competition. The scale is as follows: 1 = one-party authoritarian government (competition restricted); 2 = one-party majority parliamentary government or united presidential government; 3 = two-party coalition government or divided presidential government; 4 = three- or more party government; and 5 = minority government. Monthly coalition government scores were coded for each postcommunist country beginning with the first free election or the formal declaration of independence. A weighted average of the monthly scores is used in the scatterplot graph. See Nouriel Roubini and Jeffrey Sachs, "Government Spending and Budget Deficits in the Industrial Countries," Economic Policy 8 (1989); and idem "Political and Economic Determinants of Budget Deficits in the Industrial Democracies," European Economic Review 33 (1989).
-
(1989)
European Economic Review
, vol.33
-
-
Roubini, N.1
Sachs, J.2
|