메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 13, Issue 3, 1998, Pages 295-319

Testing for competitiveness of markets for long distance telephone services: competition finally?

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

COMPETITIVENESS; MARKET CONDITIONS; TELECOMMUNICATIONS;

EID: 0031682295     PISSN: 0889938X     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1023/A:1007748417477     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (45)
  • 1
    • 0004199595 scopus 로고
    • The U.S. Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission Horizontal Merger Guidelines (1992) concur with this conclusion, stating that HHIs above 0.18 represent highly concentrated markets.
    • (1992) Horizontal Merger Guidelines
  • 2
    • 84960612322 scopus 로고
    • The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power
    • June
    • See Abba Lerner, The Concept of Monopoly and the Measurement of Monopoly Power, Review of Economic Studies, 1 (June 1934), pp. 157-175;
    • (1934) Review of Economic Studies , vol.1 , pp. 157-175
    • Lerner, A.1
  • 3
    • 0000748373 scopus 로고
    • Price Cost Margins and Market Structure
    • August
    • Keith Cowling and Michael Waterson, Price Cost Margins and Market Structure, Economica (August 1976), pp. 277-287;
    • (1976) Economica , pp. 277-287
    • Cowling, K.1    Waterson, M.2
  • 4
    • 84875128652 scopus 로고
    • Market Power in Antitrust Cases
    • August
    • William Landes and Richard Posner, Market Power in Antitrust Cases, Harvard Law Review, 95 (August 1982), pp. 1857-1874;
    • (1982) Harvard Law Review , vol.95 , pp. 1857-1874
    • Landes, W.1    Posner, R.2
  • 5
    • 13144283208 scopus 로고
    • New York: Harper Collins College Publishers, 2nd. ed.
    • Dennis Carlton and Jeffrey Perloff (1994), Modern Industrial Organization (New York: Harper Collins College Publishers, 2nd. ed.), pp. 352-354 and 360-366. Carlton and Perloff cite numerous empirical studies that have used the price-cost margin to measure monopoly power, the dual of "competitiveness".
    • (1994) Modern Industrial Organization , pp. 352-354
    • Carlton, D.1    Perloff, J.2
  • 6
    • 13144279840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • A corollary is that: markets with more reduction in concentration should have lower price-cost margins, all else equal, since they should be more competitive than most.
  • 7
    • 0003740586 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, MA: Blackwell Publishers
    • i is the firm's market share. Summing this expression over all firms yields the industry-average price-cost margin as shown in the text.
    • (1993) Advanced Industrial Economics , pp. 167
    • Martin, S.1
  • 8
    • 0003288729 scopus 로고
    • Practices That Credibly Facilitate Collusion
    • Joseph Stiglitz and G. Frank Mathewson, eds., Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press
    • Steven C. Salop (1986), Practices That Credibly Facilitate Collusion, in Joseph Stiglitz and G. Frank Mathewson, eds., New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure, Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
    • (1986) New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure
    • Salop, S.C.1
  • 9
    • 13144261220 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In October 1996, however, the FCC in its Second Report and Order under the Telecom Act of 1996 eliminated tariff filing requirements for all interexchange carriers. This has been stayed by Court proceedings brought by a number of carriers objecting to the non-filing requirement. But the elimination of tariff-filing requirements would be a necessary but not sufficient condition for the breakdown of tacit collusion. It remains to be seen whether or not the FCC=S decision will have an effect on competitiveness.
  • 11
    • 13144276856 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 12
    • 70350155605 scopus 로고
    • Theories of Oligopoly Behavior
    • Richard Schmalensee and Robert Willig (eds.), Amsterdam: North Holland
    • Shapiro, Carl (1989), Theories of Oligopoly Behavior, in Richard Schmalensee and Robert Willig (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 329-414.
    • (1989) Handbook of Industrial Organization , pp. 329-414
    • Shapiro, C.1
  • 13
    • 13144283209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • InterLATA, interstate prices were estimated by the application of software developed with HTL Telemanagement, Ltd. taking the assumed calling patterns and applying them to data files on tariffs that AT&T, MCI, and Sprint maintain at the FCC.
  • 15
    • 13144282243 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • January 23, Dow Jones News Service Wall Street Journal Stories
    • AT&T Long-Distance Traffic Volume Up (January 23, 1997), Dow Jones News Service Wall Street Journal Stories.
    • (1997) AT&T Long-Distance Traffic Volume Up
  • 16
    • 13144266238 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Inside AT&T Corp., TPG Research and Reports
    • At the end of 1995, AT&T reportedly had approximately 30 million enrollees in its True discount plans, leaving approximately 37 million customers not on such plans. See Discount Calling Plans and Promotions (1996), Inside AT&T Corp., TPG Research and Reports, p. 122.
    • (1996) Discount Calling Plans and Promotions , pp. 122
  • 17
    • 13144282244 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Yankee Group (August 1996)
    • Yankee Group (August 1996).
  • 18
    • 13144278118 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id.
    • Id.
  • 20
    • 13144276857 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The effect of the average length of a call on the average price per minute has become less important in recent years as long-distance carriers have lowered their charges for the first minute relative to charges for subsequent minutes.
  • 21
    • 13144263337 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An example of this procedure is the calculation of prices for AT&T's Reach Out America discount calling plan. Customers with monthly bills less than $50 were excluded from the analysis. Weights for the three categories $50, $75, and $100 are 47, 21, and 16 percent respectively. The last three categories were weighted 5 percent apiece.
  • 23
    • 0004148729 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Appendix 2
    • In Appendix 2 (p. 227) of The Failure of Antitrust and Regulation to Establish Competition in Long-Distance Telephone Services (P.W. MacAvoy) results are reported under the assumption that a customer switches plans immediately whenever a carrier offers a lower price plan, yielding an always minimum price index for each carrier. Minimum prices for AT&T and MCI were approximately $0.03 to $0.04 per minute lower for 1994 than those estimated for the MTS discount plans. Sprint's minimum prices were identical to the prices of its well-known discount plans until mid-1994.
    • The Failure of Antitrust and Regulation to Establish Competition in Long-Distance Telephone Services , pp. 227
    • MacAvoy, P.W.1
  • 24
    • 13144270111 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Marginal costs are to be distinguished from long-run incremental costs, measured as the change in a firm's long-run total costs when an individual service is added (or removed) from a set of existing services. Long-run incremental costs do not include access charges.
  • 25
    • 13144302362 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Access charges could be measured in two ways: tariffed prices or average access charges per minute of service. I use tariffed access charges to be consistent with the use of tariffed prices for long-distance service.
  • 28
    • 13144266239 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • LRIC per minute has likely decreased over the past decade as a result of productivity and technological gains. The one cent per minute estimate used here embodies the likelihood that technology and system productivity advances have been offset by inflationary increases. In any event, if LRIC per minute has declined over this time frame then the price-cost margins evaluated below would have an even greater increasing trend.
  • 29
    • 13144252653 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Direct Testimony of John Sumpter on Behalf of AT&T Communications of California, Inc., Application of AT&T Communications of California, Inc. (U 5002 C) for Authority to Provide Intrastate AT&T 800 READYLINE Service, June 18, 1990.
  • 31
    • 13144251704 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Price War Looms for Long-Distance Calls
    • June 25
    • Price War Looms for Long-Distance Calls (June 25, 1996), Contra Costa Times, p. C-1.
    • (1996) Contra Costa Times
  • 32
    • 13144305596 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Sprint's margin on its Residential Promo plan subsequently increased to 0.58 in late 1996.
  • 33
    • 13144278117 scopus 로고
    • Voice Networks Pricing Update
    • February
    • See Hills, Michael T., (February 1994), Voice Networks Pricing Update, Business Communications Review, pp. 12-18.
    • (1994) Business Communications Review , pp. 12-18
    • Hills, M.T.1
  • 34
    • 13144306632 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In the Midwest, the use of outbound switched WATS service declined by a factor often during the period 1991-1995. This occurred because business customers substituted from switched WATS services to dedicated outbound services. Because of the small volume of minutes that remain in the outbound switched WATS category, no HHI was estimated.
  • 35
    • 13144279839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • HHI data are not available for Combined Services, preventing the comparison of changes in HHI with changes in margins.
  • 36
    • 13144270110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When making comparisons between price-cost margins for switched and dedicated services, it should be recalled that the usage levels differ, being lower for switched than for dedicated. Since the fixed costs of dedicated service are higher than the fixed costs of switched service, a higher monthly usage level must be maintained by dedicated users to make the dedicated service economic relative to switched.
  • 37
    • 13144295532 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These margins are unambiguously above those previously obtained under 36 month contracts for outbound dedicated WATS services (which are not shown in Figure 8).
  • 38
    • 13144249730 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • These margins are unambiguously above those previously obtained under 36 month contracts for outbound dedicated WATS services (which are not shown in Figure 8).
  • 39
    • 0000187348 scopus 로고
    • Market Conduct in the Airline Industry: An Empirical Investigation
    • This equation formulation is presented in J. Brander and A. Zhang, Market Conduct in the Airline Industry: An Empirical Investigation, 21 Rand Journal of Economics 56 (1990). Demand elasticity is assumed to equal -0.70.
    • (1990) Rand Journal of Economics , vol.21 , pp. 56
    • Brander, J.1    Zhang, A.2
  • 40
    • 0003889424 scopus 로고
    • Kluwer Academic Publishers
    • See Lester D. Taylor, Telecommunications Demand in Theory and Practice ch. 6 (Kluwer Academic Publishers 1994). Equivalently, the conjectural variation for a firm equals the partial derivative of all other firms' output with respect to a change in that firm's output.
    • (1994) Telecommunications Demand in Theory and Practice Ch. 6
    • Taylor, L.D.1
  • 42
    • 13144278826 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • One variable indicates the conjectural variation for switched and dedicated outbound WATS while the other dummy is associated with switched and dedicated inbound WATS plans. An alternative specification using four dummy variables separating switched and dedicated did not significantly affect the results of the regression model.
  • 45
    • 13144263311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The price-cost margins shown in Figures One through Eight have been constructed with prices based on stipulated calling patterns intended to be representative of customers in the Midwest (see Table I). These calling pattern assumptions have three dimensions: (1) time-of-day usage, (2) mileage distribution, and (3) monthly calling volume. One could ask whether the observed pattern of rising margins is specific to this calling pattern only. The sensitivity of prices can be tested by examining prices based on alternative time-of-day, mileage and calling pattern distributions. Each alternative scenario tested, results in price-cost margins that do not differ from those derived from the original set of assumptions. Price-cost margins under eight alternative scenarios increase over time and move in concert across the three interLATA providers. For an appendix demonstrating this pattern, please contact the author.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.