메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 24, Issue 1, 1998, Pages 43-58

Policing the system of needs: Hegel, political economy, and the police of the market

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0031624106     PISSN: 01916599     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1016/S0191-6599(98)00009-6     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (16)

References (100)
  • 1
    • 0004260323 scopus 로고
    • trans. T. M. Knox Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • 1. Translators note to G. W. F. Hegel, Philosophy of Right, trans. T. M. Knox (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1942), p. 360. The more recent translation, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, ed. Allen Wood and translated by H. B. Nisbet (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), is truer to the original in this respect. See the editor's note on p. 450.
    • (1942) Philosophy of Right , pp. 360
    • Hegel, G.W.F.1
  • 2
    • 0003516201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • and translated by H. B. Nisbet Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • 1. Translators note to G. W. F. Hegel, Philosophy of Right, trans. T. M. Knox (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1942), p. 360. The more recent translation, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, ed. Allen Wood and translated by H. B. Nisbet (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), is truer to the original in this respect. See the editor's note on p. 450.
    • (1991) Elements of the Philosophy of Right
    • Wood, A.1
  • 4
    • 0004291062 scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Blackwell
    • 3. To give but one example, the Hegel Dictionary by Michael Inwood contains no separate entry for this most important of integrating institutions in Hegel's political philosophy, and only a brief mention in the entry for 'Civil Society'. Michael Inwood, A Hegel Dictionary (Oxford: Blackwell, 1992).
    • (1992) A Hegel Dictionary
    • Inwood, M.1
  • 7
    • 0040246270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Policing and pin-making: Adam Smith, police and the state of prosperity
    • forthcoming
    • 6. The first official use of the concept occurred in December 1714 in Queen Anne's appointment of Commissioners of Police for Scotland, a body of men charged with the task of the general administration of the country. Thereafter the word gradually seeps into the English language and begins to feature in legal and Parliamentary texts in the late-eighteenth century. By 1829 it had become a common enough term to warrant the establishment of an institutionalised force known as the police. For a longer discussion see Mark Neocleous, 'Policing and Pin-making: Adam Smith, Police and the State of Prosperity', Policing and Society, forthcoming 1998.
    • (1998) Policing and Society
    • Neocleous, M.1
  • 8
    • 84925923704 scopus 로고
    • Polizei
    • 7. Franz-Ludwig Knemeyer, 'Polizei', Economy and Society, 9(2) (1980), pp. 173-195. See also David Bayley, 'The Police and Political Development in Europe', in Charles Tilly (Ed.), The Formation of National States in Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975), p. 360; Michel Foucault, 'Omnes et Singulatim: Towards a Criticism of "Political Reason"', in S. McMurrin (Ed.), The Tanner Lectures on Human Values, Vol. II (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 249.
    • (1980) Economy and Society , vol.9 , Issue.2 , pp. 173-195
    • Knemeyer, F.-L.1
  • 9
    • 0003269297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The police and political development in europe
    • Charles Tilly (Ed.)
    • 7. Franz-Ludwig Knemeyer, 'Polizei', Economy and Society, 9(2) (1980), pp. 173-195. See also David Bayley, 'The Police and Political Development in Europe', in Charles Tilly (Ed.), The Formation of National States in Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975), p. 360; Michel Foucault, 'Omnes et Singulatim: Towards a Criticism of "Political Reason"', in S. McMurrin (Ed.), The Tanner Lectures on Human Values, Vol. II (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 249.
    • (1975) The Formation of National States in Europe Princeton: Princeton University Press , pp. 360
    • Bayley, D.1
  • 10
    • 0000707676 scopus 로고
    • Omnes et singulatim: Towards a criticism of "political reason"
    • S. McMurrin (Ed.), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • 7. Franz-Ludwig Knemeyer, 'Polizei', Economy and Society, 9(2) (1980), pp. 173-195. See also David Bayley, 'The Police and Political Development in Europe', in Charles Tilly (Ed.), The Formation of National States in Europe (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975), p. 360; Michel Foucault, 'Omnes et Singulatim: Towards a Criticism of "Political Reason"', in S. McMurrin (Ed.), The Tanner Lectures on Human Values, Vol. II (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 249.
    • (1981) The Tanner Lectures on Human Values , vol.2 , pp. 249
    • Foucault, M.1
  • 11
    • 0010069413 scopus 로고
    • Cameralism and the science of government
    • 8. On this point generally see Keith Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', Journal of Modern History, 56 (1984), pp. 263-284; Keith Tribe, Governing Economy: The Reformation of German Economic Discourse 1750-1840 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988), pp. 35-91.
    • (1984) Journal of Modern History , vol.56 , pp. 263-284
    • Tribe, K.1
  • 12
    • 0003698726 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • 8. On this point generally see Keith Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', Journal of Modern History, 56 (1984), pp. 263-284; Keith Tribe, Governing Economy: The Reformation of German Economic Discourse 1750-1840 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988), pp. 35-91.
    • (1988) Governing Economy: The Reformation of German Economic Discourse 1750-1840 , pp. 35-91
    • Tribe, K.1
  • 13
    • 79956585571 scopus 로고
    • 9. Joseph von Sonnenfels, Grundsätze der Policey, Handlung und Finanz (1765); Johann Heinrich Gottlob von Justi, Staatswirthschaft (1755). Both cited in Small, The Cameralists: The Pioneers of German Social Polity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1909), pp. 327, 490.
    • (1765) Grundsätze der Policey, Handlung und Finanz
    • Von Sonnenfels, J.1
  • 14
    • 0010117141 scopus 로고
    • 9. Joseph von Sonnenfels, Grundsätze der Policey, Handlung und Finanz (1765); Johann Heinrich Gottlob von Justi, Staatswirthschaft (1755). Both cited in Small, The Cameralists: The Pioneers of German Social Polity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1909), pp. 327, 490.
    • (1755) Staatswirthschaft
    • Von Justi, J.H.G.1
  • 15
    • 0010132411 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • 9. Joseph von Sonnenfels, Grundsätze der Policey, Handlung und Finanz (1765); Johann Heinrich Gottlob von Justi, Staatswirthschaft (1755). Both cited in Small, The Cameralists: The Pioneers of German Social Polity (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1909), pp. 327, 490.
    • (1909) The Cameralists: The Pioneers of German Social Polity , pp. 327
    • Small1
  • 16
    • 0010118207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 10. Small, The Cameralists, pp. 16, 18, 414, 421, 431-435, 493. Also see George Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', Bulletin of the History of Medicine, 27 (1953), pp. 21-42, 24.
    • The Cameralists , pp. 16
    • Small1
  • 17
    • 0010118207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cameralism and the concept of medical police
    • 10. Small, The Cameralists, pp. 16, 18, 414, 421, 431-435, 493. Also see George Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', Bulletin of the History of Medicine, 27 (1953), pp. 21-42, 24.
    • (1953) Bulletin of the History of Medicine , vol.27 , pp. 21-42
    • Rosen, G.1
  • 18
    • 0004345217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 11. Small, The Cameralists, pp. 305-307. See also Mack Walker, 'Rights and Functions: The Social Categories of Eighteenth-Century German Jurists and Cameralists', Journal of Modern History, 50 (1978), pp. 234-251; Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 4.
    • The Cameralists , pp. 305-307
    • Small1
  • 19
    • 0010068879 scopus 로고
    • Rights and functions: The social categories of eighteenth-century German jurists and cameralists
    • 11. Small, The Cameralists, pp. 305-307. See also Mack Walker, 'Rights and Functions: The Social Categories of Eighteenth-Century German Jurists and Cameralists', Journal of Modern History, 50 (1978), pp. 234-251; Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 4.
    • (1978) Journal of Modern History , vol.50 , pp. 234-251
    • Walker, M.1
  • 20
    • 0004332004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chap. 4
    • 11. Small, The Cameralists, pp. 305-307. See also Mack Walker, 'Rights and Functions: The Social Categories of Eighteenth-Century German Jurists and Cameralists', Journal of Modern History, 50 (1978), pp. 234-251; Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 4.
    • Governing Economy
    • Tribe1
  • 21
    • 0004345217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 12. Von Justi cited in Small, The Cameralists, pp. 307, 459. Von Justi's recommendations for the policing of prosperity are reproduced in Small, pp. 332-393.
    • The Cameralists , pp. 307
    • Small1
  • 22
    • 8344225746 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • para. 119
    • 13. In the Preface to the Philosophy of Right he criticises Fichte for extending passport regulations to the point where people should have their images painted on their passports. In the earlier lectures of 1817-1819 he insists that 'police supervision must go no further than is necessary', in the process attacking Fichte's state in which people cannot go out without their identity papers: 'such a state becomes a world of galley slaves, where each is supposed to keep his fellow under constant supervision'. Hegel, Lectures on Natural Right and Political Science, para. 119. See J. G. Fichte, The Science of Rights (1796), trans A. E. Kroeger (London: Trubner and Co., 1889), pp. 378-379. Raymond Plant interprets Hegel's reference to 'recent theories, carried partly into effect' (cited in G. Lasson (Ed.), Schriften zur Politik und Rechtsphilosophie (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1923), p. 220), as a reference to cameralism, on the grounds that it refers to those who understand the state through the machine metaphor (discussed below). Plant, Hegel (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1973), p. 115.
    • Lectures on Natural Right and Political Science
    • Hegel1
  • 23
    • 2942647178 scopus 로고
    • trans A. E. Kroeger London: Trubner and Co.
    • 13. In the Preface to the Philosophy of Right he criticises Fichte for extending passport regulations to the point where people should have their images painted on their passports. In the earlier lectures of 1817-1819 he insists that 'police supervision must go no further than is necessary', in the process attacking Fichte's state in which people cannot go out without their identity papers: 'such a state becomes a world of galley slaves, where each is supposed to keep his fellow under constant supervision'. Hegel, Lectures on Natural Right and Political Science, para. 119. See J. G. Fichte, The Science of Rights (1796), trans A. E. Kroeger (London: Trubner and Co., 1889), pp. 378-379. Raymond Plant interprets Hegel's reference to 'recent theories, carried partly into effect' (cited in G. Lasson (Ed.), Schriften zur Politik und Rechtsphilosophie (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1923), p. 220), as a reference to cameralism, on the grounds that it refers to those who understand the state through the machine metaphor (discussed below). Plant, Hegel (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1973), p. 115.
    • (1796) The Science of Rights , pp. 378-379
    • Fichte, J.G.1
  • 24
    • 84898174904 scopus 로고
    • Leipzig: Felix Meiner
    • 13. In the Preface to the Philosophy of Right he criticises Fichte for extending passport regulations to the point where people should have their images painted on their passports. In the earlier lectures of 1817-1819 he insists that 'police supervision must go no further than is necessary', in the process attacking Fichte's state in which people cannot go out without their identity papers: 'such a state becomes a world of galley slaves, where each is supposed to keep his fellow under constant supervision'. Hegel, Lectures on Natural Right and Political Science, para. 119. See J. G. Fichte, The Science of Rights (1796), trans A. E. Kroeger (London: Trubner and Co., 1889), pp. 378-379. Raymond Plant interprets Hegel's reference to 'recent theories, carried partly into effect' (cited in G. Lasson (Ed.), Schriften zur Politik und Rechtsphilosophie (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1923), p. 220), as a reference to cameralism, on the grounds that it refers to those who understand the state through the machine metaphor (discussed below). Plant, Hegel (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1973), p. 115.
    • (1923) Schriften zur Politik und Rechtsphilosophie , pp. 220
    • Lasson, G.1
  • 25
    • 85016347715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: George Allen & Unwin
    • 13. In the Preface to the Philosophy of Right he criticises Fichte for extending passport regulations to the point where people should have their images painted on their passports. In the earlier lectures of 1817-1819 he insists that 'police supervision must go no further than is necessary', in the process attacking Fichte's state in which people cannot go out without their identity papers: 'such a state becomes a world of galley slaves, where each is supposed to keep his fellow under constant supervision'. Hegel, Lectures on Natural Right and Political Science, para. 119. See J. G. Fichte, The Science of Rights (1796), trans A. E. Kroeger (London: Trubner and Co., 1889), pp. 378-379. Raymond Plant interprets Hegel's reference to 'recent theories, carried partly into effect' (cited in G. Lasson (Ed.), Schriften zur Politik und Rechtsphilosophie (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1923), p. 220), as a reference to cameralism, on the grounds that it refers to those who understand the state through the machine metaphor (discussed below). Plant, Hegel (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1973), p. 115.
    • (1973) Hegel , pp. 115
    • Plant1
  • 26
    • 0003314895 scopus 로고
    • Theatrum politicum: The genealogy of capital - Police and the state of prosperity
    • Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller (Eds), Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf
    • 14. Pasquale Pasquino, 'Theatrum Politicum: The Genealogy of Capital - Police and the State of Prosperity', in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller (Eds), The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality (Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf, 1991), p. 112.
    • (1991) The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality , pp. 112
    • Pasquino, P.1
  • 28
    • 0004203360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: George Allen and Unwin
    • 16. Joseph Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1954), p. 160. Tribe, Governing Economy, p. 71. Tribe writes (p. 60): 'The reader who seeks precision, originality, and theoretical elaboration in the writings of eighteenth-century Cameralism is doomed to disappointment and frustration ... Cameralism is almost, but not quite, like a large stick of rock - wherever one bites into it, one encounters the same terms, definitions, and redefinitions'.
    • (1954) History of Economic Analysis , pp. 160
    • Schumpeter, J.1
  • 29
    • 0004332004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 16. Joseph Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1954), p. 160. Tribe, Governing Economy, p. 71. Tribe writes (p. 60): 'The reader who seeks precision, originality, and theoretical elaboration in the writings of eighteenth-century Cameralism is doomed to disappointment and frustration ... Cameralism is almost, but not quite, like a large stick of rock - wherever one bites into it, one encounters the same terms, definitions, and redefinitions'.
    • Governing Economy , pp. 71
    • Tribe1
  • 31
    • 85033524641 scopus 로고
    • ed. R. H. Campbell, A. S. Skinner and W. B. Todd Indianapolis: Liberty Fund
    • 18. Adam Smith, Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. R. H. Campbell, A. S. Skinner and W. B. Todd (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1979), pp. 77, 79, 137.
    • (1979) Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations , pp. 77
    • Smith, A.1
  • 33
    • 0041702399 scopus 로고
    • ed. R. L. Meek, D. D. Raphael and P. G. Stein Indianapolis: Liberty Fund
    • 20. Adam Smith, Lectures on Jurisprudence, ed. R. L. Meek, D. D. Raphael and P. G. Stein (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1982); see esp. pp. 5-6, 331-333, 398, 486-487.
    • (1982) Lectures on Jurisprudence , pp. 5-6
    • Smith, A.1
  • 35
    • 84870559790 scopus 로고
    • New York: Academic Press
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • (1980) The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750
    • Wallerstein, I.1
  • 36
    • 0010189082 scopus 로고
    • Cameralism
    • Edwin Seligman (Ed.), London: Macmillan, rev. ed.
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • (1930) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences , pp. 158-161
    • Sommer, L.1
  • 37
    • 0004082296 scopus 로고
    • New Haven: Yale University Press
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • (1983) The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800
    • Raeff, M.1
  • 38
    • 85033519968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police , pp. 23
    • Rosen1
  • 39
    • 17044400417 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • Omnes et Singulatim , pp. 249
    • Foucault1
  • 40
    • 0010070178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The introduction of Adam Smith on the continent
    • John Clarke (Ed.), Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • (1928) Adam Smith, 1776-1926 , pp. 192
    • Palyi, M.1
  • 41
    • 0010070179 scopus 로고
    • Economic theory and policy in Germany 1750-1800
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • (1975) Journal of European Economic History , vol.4 , Issue.2 , pp. 301-322
    • Braun, H.-J.1
  • 42
    • 0004345217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • The Cameralists , pp. 7-15
    • Small1
  • 43
    • 0004332004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • Governing Economy , pp. 66
    • Tribe1
  • 44
    • 0010176948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 22. While it must be recognised that 'mercantilism' is a term which implies far more homogeneity among a group of writers than there really was - the result of Smith's imposition of this category on a very disparate group of writers - it is perhaps still worth registering the fact that for many commentators cameralism is the German form of mercantilism. The index entry for cameralism in Immanuel Wallerstein, The Modern World System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600-1750 (New York: Academic Press, 1980), sums this up perfectly. It reads: 'Cameralism, see Mercantilism'. For other examples see Louise Sommer, 'Cameralism', in Edwin Seligman (Ed.) Encyclopaedia of the Social Sciences (London: Macmillan, 1930, rev. ed. 1937), pp. 158-161: 'Cameralism is properly the German and Austrian variety of mercantilism' (p. 159); Marc Raeff, The Well-Ordered Police State: Social and Institutional Change Through Law in the Germanies and Russia, 1600-1800 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1983): 'It is usually and quite correctly asserted that mercantilism, by whatever definition, inspired the economic theory and practice of cameralism' (p. 92); Rosen, 'Cameralism and the Concept of Medical Police', p. 23, also suggests that cameralism is 'the more politically-oriented, specifically German form' of mercantilism (p. 23); Foucault makes a similar connection in his 'Omnes et Singulatim', p. 249; also see Melchior Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', in John Clarke (Ed.), Adam Smith, 1776-1926 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1928), p. 192. For more subtle accounts see Hans-Joachim Braun, 'Economic Theory and Policy in Germany 1750-1800', Journal of European Economic History, 4(2) (1975), pp. 301-322; Small, The Cameralists, pp. 7-15; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 66, 74, 81; and Tribe, 'Cameralism and the Science of Government', pp. 265, 272.
    • Cameralism and the Science of Government , pp. 265
    • Tribe1
  • 52
    • 0010619892 scopus 로고
    • Economic and philosophical manuscripts
    • Marx, trans. Rodney Livingstone and Gregor Benton Harmondsworth: Penguin
    • 29. There are a variety of reasons why this has happened. The 'history of political ideas' approach has a tendency to oversimplify quite complex relationships between writers and their forebears in general. Marxists have found it convenient to stress a Smith-Hegel nexus. Marx's comment that 'Hegel adopts the standpoint of political economy' (Marx, 'Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts', in Marx, Early Writings trans. Rodney Livingstone and Gregor Benton (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1975), p. 386), is one which Marxists have been too quick to appropriate uncritically, since on an unsophisticated reading it appears to conveniently conflate two of Marxism's opponents into one 'camp'. Conversely, those who wish to appropriate Hegel for liberal thought have likewise tried to suggest that Hegel was really just adopting some of Smith's ideas on the market, which proves that he must have been a good liberal.
    • (1975) Early Writings , pp. 386
    • Marx1
  • 53
    • 85033540789 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 30. Waszek, Scottish Enlightenment and Hegel's Account, p. 77: 'it is no exaggeration to describe the introduction of Smithian doctrines as a main watershed in the development of the teaching of political economy in Germany'. Likewise Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', p. 180. For a general discussion see Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 7.
    • Scottish Enlightenment and Hegel's Account , pp. 77
    • Waszek1
  • 54
    • 0010070178 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 30. Waszek, Scottish Enlightenment and Hegel's Account, p. 77: 'it is no exaggeration to describe the introduction of Smithian doctrines as a main watershed in the development of the teaching of political economy in Germany'. Likewise Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', p. 180. For a general discussion see Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 7.
    • The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent , pp. 180
    • Palyi1
  • 55
    • 0004332004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chap. 7
    • 30. Waszek, Scottish Enlightenment and Hegel's Account, p. 77: 'it is no exaggeration to describe the introduction of Smithian doctrines as a main watershed in the development of the teaching of political economy in Germany'. Likewise Palyi, 'The Introduction of Adam Smith on the Continent', p. 180. For a general discussion see Tribe, Governing Economy, Chap. 7.
    • Governing Economy
    • Tribe1
  • 56
    • 0003900339 scopus 로고
    • London: Heinemann
    • 31. An eminent historian of economic thought such as Mark Blaug sees fit to grant him just two passing references in his 700 page Economic Theory in Retrospect (London: Heinemann, 1964).
    • (1964) Economic Theory in Retrospect
  • 58
    • 84925910423 scopus 로고
    • Hegel and political economy
    • 33. See Raymond Plant, 'Hegel and Political Economy', New Left Review, (1977), pp. 103 and 104, Bernard Cullen, Hegel's Social and Political Thought (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1979), pp. 34-37. Both build very much on Chamley, ibid. 34. Hegel, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, para. 189.
    • (1977) New Left Review , pp. 103
    • Plant, R.1
  • 59
    • 0010069670 scopus 로고
    • Dublin: Gill and Macmillan
    • 33. See Raymond Plant, 'Hegel and Political Economy', New Left Review, (1977), pp. 103 and 104, Bernard Cullen, Hegel's Social and Political Thought (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1979), pp. 34-37. Both build very much on Chamley, ibid. 34. Hegel, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, para. 189.
    • (1979) Hegel's Social and Political Thought , pp. 34-37
    • Cullen, B.1
  • 60
    • 85069288339 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 33. See Raymond Plant, 'Hegel and Political Economy', New Left Review, (1977), pp. 103 and 104, Bernard Cullen, Hegel's Social and Political Thought (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1979), pp. 34-37. Both build very much on Chamley, ibid. 34. Hegel, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, para. 189.
    • Hegel's Social and Political Thought , pp. 34
    • Chamley1
  • 61
    • 0003516201 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • para. 189
    • 33. See Raymond Plant, 'Hegel and Political Economy', New Left Review, (1977), pp. 103 and 104, Bernard Cullen, Hegel's Social and Political Thought (Dublin: Gill and Macmillan, 1979), pp. 34-37. Both build very much on Chamley, ibid. 34. Hegel, Elements of the Philosophy of Right, para. 189.
    • Elements of the Philosophy of Right
    • Hegel1
  • 63
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also pp. 25, 200, 300, 325
    • 36. Steuart, Inquiry, pp. 16, 122. See also pp. 25, 200, 300, 325.
    • Inquiry , pp. 16
    • Steuart1
  • 64
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 37. Steuart, Inquiry, p. 143. He adds: 'were public spirit, instead of private utility, to become the spring of action in the individuals of a well-governed state, I apprehend, it would spoil all'.
    • Inquiry , pp. 143
    • Steuart1
  • 65
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see also p. 300
    • 38. Steuart, Inquiry, p. 80; see also p. 300.
    • Inquiry , pp. 80
    • Steuart1
  • 69
    • 0010181741 scopus 로고
    • ed. J. Hoffmeister Leipzig: Felix Meiner
    • 42. G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. I, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), pp. 239-240; G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. II, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), p. 323. For a discussion see Plant, Hegel, 111-116.
    • (1932) Jenenser Realphilosophie , vol.1 , pp. 239-240
    • Hegel, G.W.F.1
  • 70
    • 0010176091 scopus 로고
    • ed. J. Hoffmeister Leipzig: Felix Meiner
    • 42. G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. I, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), pp. 239-240; G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. II, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), p. 323. For a discussion see Plant, Hegel, 111-116.
    • (1932) Jenenser Realphilosophie , vol.2 , pp. 323
    • Hegel, G.W.F.1
  • 71
    • 85016347715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 42. G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. I, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), pp. 239-240; G. W. F. Hegel, Jenenser Realphilosophie, Vol. II, ed. J. Hoffmeister (Leipzig: Felix Meiner, 1932), p. 323. For a discussion see Plant, Hegel, 111-116.
    • Hegel , pp. 111-116
    • Plant1
  • 72
    • 85035396645 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • 43. Karl Rosenkranz, Hegel's Leben (Berlin, 1841), cited in George Lukacs, The Young Hegel, trans. Rodney Livingstone (London: Merlin, 1975), p. 170.
    • (1841) Hegel's Leben
    • Rosenkranz, K.1
  • 73
    • 0004209423 scopus 로고
    • trans. Rodney Livingstone London: Merlin
    • 43. Karl Rosenkranz, Hegel's Leben (Berlin, 1841), cited in George Lukacs, The Young Hegel, trans. Rodney Livingstone (London: Merlin, 1975), p. 170.
    • (1975) The Young Hegel , pp. 170
    • Lukacs, G.1
  • 74
    • 84959624794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Leipzig
    • 44. For example, Steuart's image of the economy as a machine is found in von Justi, Gesemalte Politische und Finanzschriften (Leipzig, 1761), p. 86. It is only fair to point out however that the image of government as a machine was far from unusual in the seventeenth century - in The Social Contract, for example, Rousseau describes monarchy as a system in which 'all the springs of the machine are in the same hands'. Jean-Jacques Rousseau, The Social Contract and Discourses (London: Dent & Sons, 1973), p. 221. For discussion of this see Geraint Parry, 'Enlightened Government and its Critics in Eighteenth-Century Germany', The Historical Journal, 6(2), pp. 178-192, 182-183; Leonard Krieger, An Essay on the Theory of Enlightened Despotism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975), p. 40.
    • (1761) Gesemalte Politische und Finanzschriften , pp. 86
    • Von Justi1
  • 75
    • 84959624794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London: Dent & Sons
    • 44. For example, Steuart's image of the economy as a machine is found in von Justi, Gesemalte Politische und Finanzschriften (Leipzig, 1761), p. 86. It is only fair to point out however that the image of government as a machine was far from unusual in the seventeenth century - in The Social Contract, for example, Rousseau describes monarchy as a system in which 'all the springs of the machine are in the same hands'. Jean-Jacques Rousseau, The Social Contract and Discourses (London: Dent & Sons, 1973), p. 221. For discussion of this see Geraint Parry, 'Enlightened Government and its Critics in Eighteenth-Century Germany', The Historical Journal, 6(2), pp. 178-192, 182-183; Leonard Krieger, An Essay on the Theory of Enlightened Despotism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975), p. 40.
    • (1973) The Social Contract and Discourses , pp. 221
    • Rousseau, J.-J.1
  • 76
    • 84959624794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Enlightened government and its critics in eighteenth-century Germany
    • 44. For example, Steuart's image of the economy as a machine is found in von Justi, Gesemalte Politische und Finanzschriften (Leipzig, 1761), p. 86. It is only fair to point out however that the image of government as a machine was far from unusual in the seventeenth century - in The Social Contract, for example, Rousseau describes monarchy as a system in which 'all the springs of the machine are in the same hands'. Jean-Jacques Rousseau, The Social Contract and Discourses (London: Dent & Sons, 1973), p. 221. For discussion of this see Geraint Parry, 'Enlightened Government and its Critics in Eighteenth-Century Germany', The Historical Journal, 6(2), pp. 178-192, 182-183; Leonard Krieger, An Essay on the Theory of Enlightened Despotism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975), p. 40.
    • The Historical Journal , vol.6 , Issue.2 , pp. 178-192
    • Parry, G.1
  • 77
    • 84959624794 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • 44. For example, Steuart's image of the economy as a machine is found in von Justi, Gesemalte Politische und Finanzschriften (Leipzig, 1761), p. 86. It is only fair to point out however that the image of government as a machine was far from unusual in the seventeenth century - in The Social Contract, for example, Rousseau describes monarchy as a system in which 'all the springs of the machine are in the same hands'. Jean-Jacques Rousseau, The Social Contract and Discourses (London: Dent & Sons, 1973), p. 221. For discussion of this see Geraint Parry, 'Enlightened Government and its Critics in Eighteenth-Century Germany', The Historical Journal, 6(2), pp. 178-192, 182-183; Leonard Krieger, An Essay on the Theory of Enlightened Despotism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975), p. 40.
    • (1975) An Essay on the Theory of Enlightened Despotism , pp. 40
    • Krieger, L.1
  • 78
    • 0004345217 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 45. In a note to paragraph 17 of his Foundations of Police, Commerce and Finance. See Small, The Cameralists, p. 496. On Steuart's links and possible links with cameralism see S. R. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: G. Bell and Sons, 1957), p. 152; Plant, Hegel, 114-115; Laurence Dickey, Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 197; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 134-138.
    • The Cameralists , pp. 496
    • Small1
  • 79
    • 0010128941 scopus 로고
    • London: G. Bell and Sons
    • 45. In a note to paragraph 17 of his Foundations of Police, Commerce and Finance. See Small, The Cameralists, p. 496. On Steuart's links and possible links with cameralism see S. R. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: G. Bell and Sons, 1957), p. 152; Plant, Hegel, 114-115; Laurence Dickey, Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 197; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 134-138.
    • (1957) The Economics of Sir James Steuart , pp. 152
    • Sen, S.R.1
  • 80
    • 85016347715 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 45. In a note to paragraph 17 of his Foundations of Police, Commerce and Finance. See Small, The Cameralists, p. 496. On Steuart's links and possible links with cameralism see S. R. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: G. Bell and Sons, 1957), p. 152; Plant, Hegel, 114-115; Laurence Dickey, Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 197; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 134-138.
    • Hegel , pp. 114-115
    • Plant1
  • 81
    • 0003858068 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • 45. In a note to paragraph 17 of his Foundations of Police, Commerce and Finance. See Small, The Cameralists, p. 496. On Steuart's links and possible links with cameralism see S. R. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: G. Bell and Sons, 1957), p. 152; Plant, Hegel, 114-115; Laurence Dickey, Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 197; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 134-138.
    • (1987) Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 , pp. 197
    • Dickey, L.1
  • 82
    • 0004332004 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 45. In a note to paragraph 17 of his Foundations of Police, Commerce and Finance. See Small, The Cameralists, p. 496. On Steuart's links and possible links with cameralism see S. R. Sen, The Economics of Sir James Steuart (London: G. Bell and Sons, 1957), p. 152; Plant, Hegel, 114-115; Laurence Dickey, Hegel: Religion, Economics, and the Politics of Spirit, 1770-1807 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 197; Tribe, Governing Economy, pp. 134-138.
    • Governing Economy , pp. 134-138
    • Tribe1
  • 84
    • 84874132536 scopus 로고
    • 47. Sir William Mildmay's The Police of France (1763) did a good job of summarising the range of policing institutions which existed in France and the powers possessed by the lieutenant de police for Paris. The range of institutions included 48 commissaires de police with a combination of judicial and executive powers who kept a register of all hotels and lodging houses with detailed information on their residents, 21 inspecteurs de police with an army of spies, exempts de police who were to enforce the regulations for the maintenance of order, soldiers quartered in Paris and a range of archers divided into brigades under the command of a brigadier who marched through Paris virtually all day. See Leon Radzinowicz, A History of English Criminal Law and its Administration from 1750, Vol. 3: Cross-Currents in the Movement for the Reform of the Police (London: Stevens and Sons, 1956), pp. 539-574. See also Bayley, 'Police and Political development in Europe', pp. 343-345. On the eve of the revolution the Registers of the lieutenants contained some 20,000 names of 'suspect and depraved characters'.
    • (1763) The Police of France
    • Mildmay's, W.1
  • 85
    • 0010167962 scopus 로고
    • London: Stevens and Sons
    • 47. Sir William Mildmay's The Police of France (1763) did a good job of summarising the range of policing institutions which existed in France and the powers possessed by the lieutenant de police for Paris. The range of institutions included 48 commissaires de police with a combination of judicial and executive powers who kept a register of all hotels and lodging houses with detailed information on their residents, 21 inspecteurs de police with an army of spies, exempts de police who were to enforce the regulations for the maintenance of order, soldiers quartered in Paris and a range of archers divided into brigades under the command of a brigadier who marched through Paris virtually all day. See Leon Radzinowicz, A History of English Criminal Law and its Administration from 1750, Vol. 3: Cross-Currents in the Movement for the Reform of the Police (London: Stevens and Sons, 1956), pp. 539-574. See also Bayley, 'Police and Political development in Europe', pp. 343-345. On the eve of the revolution the Registers of the lieutenants contained some 20,000 names of 'suspect and depraved characters'.
    • (1956) A History of English Criminal Law and Its Administration from 1750, Vol. 3: Cross-currents in the Movement for the Reform of the Police , vol.3 , pp. 539-574
    • Radzinowicz, L.1
  • 86
    • 0003269297 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 47. Sir William Mildmay's The Police of France (1763) did a good job of summarising the range of policing institutions which existed in France and the powers possessed by the lieutenant de police for Paris. The range of institutions included 48 commissaires de police with a combination of judicial and executive powers who kept a register of all hotels and lodging houses with detailed information on their residents, 21 inspecteurs de police with an army of spies, exempts de police who were to enforce the regulations for the maintenance of order, soldiers quartered in Paris and a range of archers divided into brigades under the command of a brigadier who marched through Paris virtually all day. See Leon Radzinowicz, A History of English Criminal Law and its Administration from 1750, Vol. 3: Cross-Currents in the Movement for the Reform of the Police (London: Stevens and Sons, 1956), pp. 539-574. See also Bayley, 'Police and Political development in Europe', pp. 343-345. On the eve of the revolution the Registers of the lieutenants contained some 20,000 names of 'suspect and depraved characters'.
    • Police and Political Development in Europe , pp. 343-345
    • Bayley1
  • 87
    • 85033512407 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Circular "to the acting magistrates" Oct 19, 1772
    • Appendix 1 of Radzinowicz
    • 48. John Fielding, 'Circular "To the Acting Magistrates" Oct 19, 1772', Appendix 1 of Radzinowicz, History of English Criminal Law, pp. 482-484; Extracts from Such of the Penal Laws, as Particularly Relate to the Peace and Good Order of this Metropolis (1761, revised ed. 1768),
    • History of English Criminal Law , pp. 482-484
    • Fielding, J.1
  • 89
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 49. See for example Steuart, Inquiry, pp. 79-81.
    • Inquiry , pp. 79-81
    • Steuart1
  • 90
    • 0010067785 scopus 로고
    • 50. Monthly Review, 36, 1767, cited by Steuart, Inquiry, p. 4. See also Andrew Skinner, 'Biographical Sketch' and 'Analytical Introduction' to Steuart, Inquiry, pp. xlvi-xlvii, lxxxii, and his A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1996), p. 285.
    • (1767) Monthly Review , vol.36
  • 91
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 50. Monthly Review, 36, 1767, cited by Steuart, Inquiry, p. 4. See also Andrew Skinner, 'Biographical Sketch' and 'Analytical Introduction' to Steuart, Inquiry, pp. xlvi-xlvii, lxxxii, and his A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1996), p. 285.
    • Inquiry , pp. 4
    • Steuart1
  • 92
    • 85033511629 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Biographical sketch' and 'analytical introduction' to Steuart
    • 50. Monthly Review, 36, 1767, cited by Steuart, Inquiry, p. 4. See also Andrew Skinner, 'Biographical Sketch' and 'Analytical Introduction' to Steuart, Inquiry, pp. xlvi-xlvii, lxxxii, and his A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1996), p. 285.
    • Inquiry
    • Skinner, A.1
  • 93
    • 0010130052 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford: Clarendon Press
    • 50. Monthly Review, 36, 1767, cited by Steuart, Inquiry, p. 4. See also Andrew Skinner, 'Biographical Sketch' and 'Analytical Introduction' to Steuart, Inquiry, pp. xlvi-xlvii, lxxxii, and his A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1996), p. 285.
    • (1996) A System of Social Science: Papers Relating to Adam Smith , pp. 285
  • 94
    • 84940367382 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 51. Steuart, Inquiry, pp. 4-5. As Schumpeter puts it, 'there is something un-English (which is not merely Scottish) about his views and his mode of presentation'; History of Economic Analysis, p. 176.
    • Inquiry , pp. 4-5
    • Steuart1
  • 95
    • 0004203360 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 51. Steuart, Inquiry, pp. 4-5. As Schumpeter puts it, 'there is something un-English (which is not merely Scottish) about his views and his mode of presentation'; History of Economic Analysis, p. 176.
    • History of Economic Analysis , pp. 176


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.