메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 65, Issue 2, 1997, Pages 449-466

Patents and antitrust: A rethinking in light of patent breadth and sequential innovation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0031511862     PISSN: 00036056     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (45)

References (64)
  • 1
    • 18044395665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Federal Courts Improvement Act of 1982, Pub. L. 97-164, 96 Stat. 37 (Apr. 2, 1982)
    • See Federal Courts Improvement Act of 1982, Pub. L. 97-164, 96 Stat. 37 (Apr. 2, 1982).
  • 2
    • 21344435926 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Running the Gauntlet: Antitrust and Intellectual Property Pitfalls on the Two Sides of the Atlantic
    • See James B. Kobak, Jr., Running the Gauntlet: Antitrust and Intellectual Property Pitfalls on the Two Sides of the Atlantic, 64 ANTITRUST L.J. 341 (1996).
    • (1996) Antitrust L.J. , vol.64 , pp. 341
    • Kobak Jr., J.B.1
  • 3
    • 21844488688 scopus 로고
    • Patent Scope in Biotechnology
    • See John H. Barton, Patent Scope in Biotechnology, 26 INT'L REV. INDUS. PROP. & COPYRIGHT L. 605 (1995). This article includes a description of a survey of a sample of 63 biotechnology patents issued during October 1994. Five of these were extremely broad; another five covered important research tools.
    • (1995) Int'l Rev. Indus. Prop. & Copyright L. , vol.26 , pp. 605
    • Barton, J.H.1
  • 4
    • 18044375311 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S. Patent 5,159,135, Umbeck, Genetic engineering of cotton plants and lines, Oct. 27, 1992, reexamination granted, Dec. 7, 1994
    • U.S. Patent 5,159,135, Umbeck, Genetic engineering of cotton plants and lines, Oct. 27, 1992, reexamination granted, Dec. 7, 1994.
  • 5
    • 18044375097 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., U. S. Patent 5,328,987, Maliszewski, IgA Fc receptors, July 12, 1994
    • E.g., U. S. Patent 5,328,987, Maliszewski, IgA Fc receptors, July 12, 1994.
  • 6
    • 18044362845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • U.S Patent 5,061,620, Tsukamoto et al., Human hematopoietic stem cell, Oct. 29, 1991
    • U.S Patent 5,061,620, Tsukamoto et al., Human hematopoietic stem cell, Oct. 29, 1991.
  • 7
    • 18044383665 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If copyright protection extends to reverse engineering of computer programs or to interfaces, that copyright protection can, effectively, affect a variety of related and follow-on technologies, just as is the case for a patented fundamental research tool in biotechnology. For example, control over a widely accepted user interface, such as that for a spreadsheet, could be a major barrier to entry to the entire spreadsheet market. See Lotus Dev. Corp. v. Borland Int'l, Inc., 49 F.3d 807 (1st Cir. 1995), aff'd by an equally divided Court, 116 S. Ct. 804 (1996). Many of the points of this article can, with appropriate doctrinal adjustments, be applied to the software copyright context as well as to the patent context.
  • 8
    • 0001563414 scopus 로고
    • The Nature and Functions of the Patent System
    • Edmund W. Kitch, The Nature and Functions of the Patent System, 20 J.L. & ECON. 266 (1977).
    • (1977) J.L. & Econ. , vol.20 , pp. 266
    • Kitch, E.W.1
  • 9
    • 0001852331 scopus 로고
    • Market Structure and Technical Advance: The Role of Patent Scope Decisions
    • Thomas M. Jorde & David J. Teece eds.
    • E.g., Robert P. Merges & Richard R. Nelson, Market Structure and Technical Advance: The Role of Patent Scope Decisions, in ANTITRUST, INNOVATION, AND COMPETITIVENESS 185 (Thomas M. Jorde & David J. Teece eds., 1992).
    • (1992) Antitrust, Innovation, and Competitiveness , pp. 185
    • Merges, R.P.1    Nelson, R.R.2
  • 10
    • 0000104811 scopus 로고
    • An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law
    • William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 325 (1989).
    • (1989) J. Legal Stud. , vol.18 , pp. 325
    • Landes, W.M.1    Posner, R.A.2
  • 11
    • 85077621983 scopus 로고
    • On the Division of Profit in Sequential Innovation
    • E.g., Jerry R. Green & Suzanne Scotchmer, On the Division of Profit in Sequential Innovation, 26 RAND J. ECON. 20 (1995); Howard F. Chang, Patent Scope, Antitrust Policy, and Cumulative Innovation, 26 RAND J. ECON. 34 (1995).
    • (1995) Rand J. Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 20
    • Green, J.R.1    Scotchmer, S.2
  • 12
    • 21844490020 scopus 로고
    • Patent Scope, Antitrust Policy, and Cumulative Innovation
    • E.g., Jerry R. Green & Suzanne Scotchmer, On the Division of Profit in Sequential Innovation, 26 RAND J. ECON. 20 (1995); Howard F. Chang, Patent Scope, Antitrust Policy, and Cumulative Innovation, 26 RAND J. ECON. 34 (1995).
    • (1995) Rand J. Econ. , vol.26 , pp. 34
    • Chang, H.F.1
  • 13
    • 84885632586 scopus 로고
    • Production and Distribution of Knowledge in the New Systems of Innovation: The Role of Intellectual Property Rights
    • Dominique Foray, Production and Distribution of Knowledge in the New Systems of Innovation: The Role of Intellectual Property Rights, 14 SCIENCE TECH. INDUS. DEV. (STI) 119 (1994); Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use, 56 U. CHI. L. REV. 1017 (1989).
    • (1994) Science Tech. Indus. Dev. (STI) , vol.14 , pp. 119
    • Foray, D.1
  • 14
    • 34548610362 scopus 로고
    • Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use
    • Dominique Foray, Production and Distribution of Knowledge in the New Systems of Innovation: The Role of Intellectual Property Rights, 14 SCIENCE TECH. INDUS. DEV. (STI) 119 (1994); Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use, 56 U. CHI. L. REV. 1017 (1989).
    • (1989) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.56 , pp. 1017
    • Eisenberg, R.S.1
  • 15
    • 0006146505 scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents
    • But see Robert Merges, Intellectual Property Rights and Bargaining Breakdown: The Case of Blocking Patents, 62 TENN. L. REV. 75 (1994). Note, moreover, that a university holding a blocking patent usually has little interest in a cross-license with firms holding blocking patents, for it is not directly engaged in commercial research. If two pharmaceutical firms have patented separate receptors involved in the same overall biological phenomenon, they have every incentive to cross-license each other, royalty-free. If one of the receptor patents is held by a university, however, its interest is in royalties rather than a cross-license. Another area of possible exception, suggested in the text, is a venture capital-style startup seeking to control a major area of technology and licensing only as part of that technology control strategy or as necessary to raise capital.
    • (1994) Tenn. L. Rev. , vol.62 , pp. 75
    • Merges, R.1
  • 16
    • 0002730808 scopus 로고
    • Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the Patent Law
    • Suzanne Scotchmer, Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Cumulative Research and the Patent Law, 5 J. ECON. PERSP. 29, 31, 34 (1991).
    • (1991) J. Econ. Persp. , vol.5 , pp. 29
    • Scotchmer, S.1
  • 17
    • 18044370006 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Green & Scotchmer, supra note 11 (emphasizing loss of incentive to initial innovator); Chang, supra note 11 (defining an allocation of monopoly rents to give initial inventor greatest incentive when subsequent inventor is assumed to make an independent cost/ benefit analysis).
  • 18
    • 0039333702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Protecting Early Innovators: Should Second-Generation Products Be Patentable?
    • Suzanne Scotchmer, Protecting Early Innovators: Should Second-Generation Products Be Patentable?, 27 RAND J. ECON. 322 (1996).
    • (1996) Rand J. Econ. , vol.27 , pp. 322
    • Scotchmer, S.1
  • 19
    • 18044390439 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 323
    • See id. at 323.
  • 20
    • 0000075294 scopus 로고
    • Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development
    • E.g., Richard C. Levin et al., Appropriating the Returns from Industrial Research and Development, BROOKINGS PAPERS ON ECON. ACTIVITY NO. 3 at 783 (1987).
    • (1987) Brookings Papers on Econ. Activity No. 3 , pp. 783
    • Levin, R.C.1
  • 21
    • 18044379481 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • At least four of the ten broad or research tool patents identified in the survey described supra note 3, were supported by the government. The weight to be given to this argument must certainly take into account the possibility of substantial declines in government research support; yet, so far those declines, at least in the United States, have been more in applied research than in basic research. Moreover, academic incentives for basic research remain strong.
  • 22
    • 0001416071 scopus 로고
    • Pre-emptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly
    • It also seems possible that the use of broad and basic patents makes it more plausible for monopolists to maintain their positions by preemption. See Richard J. Gilbert & David Newbery, Pre-emptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly, 72 AM. ECON. REV. 514 (1982). When the later innovator is smaller, it can further be significantly deterred by the fear of intellectual property litigation costs. See Josh Lerner, Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors, 38 J.L. & ECON. 463 (1995).
    • (1982) Am. Econ. Rev. , vol.72 , pp. 514
    • Gilbert, R.J.1    Newbery, D.2
  • 23
    • 84922789072 scopus 로고
    • Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors
    • It also seems possible that the use of broad and basic patents makes it more plausible for monopolists to maintain their positions by preemption. See Richard J. Gilbert & David Newbery, Pre-emptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly, 72 AM. ECON. REV. 514 (1982). When the later innovator is smaller, it can further be significantly deterred by the fear of intellectual property litigation costs. See Josh Lerner, Patenting in the Shadow of Competitors, 38 J.L. & ECON. 463 (1995).
    • (1995) J.L. & Econ. , vol.38 , pp. 463
    • Lerner, J.1
  • 24
    • 18044395664 scopus 로고
    • Microsoft Probe Examines Internet Software
    • Dec. 4
    • Therese Poletti, Microsoft Probe Examines Internet Software, REUTER BUS. REP., Dec. 4, 1995.
    • (1995) Reuter Bus. Rep.
    • Poletti, T.1
  • 25
    • 18044384186 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This also has implications for tying policy in the high-technology area, for tying can be a means of seeking to convert power in one market into power in another. These issues are, not, however, pursued further in this article.
  • 26
    • 18044392195 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Kitch, supra note 8, at 278
    • See, e.g., Kitch, supra note 8, at 278.
  • 27
    • 18044390619 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merges & Nelson, supra note 9
    • Merges & Nelson, supra note 9.
  • 28
    • 18044389645 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Kitch, supra note 8
    • Kitch, supra note 8.
  • 29
    • 84866217423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 U.S.C. § 101
    • 35 U.S.C. § 101.
  • 30
    • 18044382054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 383 U.S. 519, 534 (1966)
    • 383 U.S. 519, 534 (1966).
  • 31
    • 84866219683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 35 U.S.C. § 112
    • 35 U.S.C. § 112.
  • 32
    • 18044386296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Barton, supra note 3, at 615-16
    • See Barton, supra note 3, at 615-16.
  • 33
    • 18044362245 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Merges & Nelson, supra note 9, at 192
    • Merges & Nelson, supra note 9, at 192.
  • 34
    • 0346526728 scopus 로고
    • The Research Exemption: A Proposal
    • See generally Lauren Bruzzone, The Research Exemption: A Proposal, 21 AIPLA O.J. 52 (1993); Rebecca Eisenberg, Technology Transfer and the Genome Project: Problems with Patenting Research Tools, 5 RISK: HEALTH, SAFETY & ENV'T 163 (1994). The doctrine is basically judicially created, although there is a codification for the narrow situation of firms preparing to market drugs when the patents covering those drugs expire. See 35 U.S.C. § 271 (e).
    • (1993) Aipla O.J. , vol.21 , pp. 52
    • Bruzzone, L.1
  • 35
    • 0012338843 scopus 로고
    • Technology Transfer and the Genome Project: Problems with Patenting Research Tools
    • See generally Lauren Bruzzone, The Research Exemption: A Proposal, 21 AIPLA O.J. 52 (1993); Rebecca Eisenberg, Technology Transfer and the Genome Project: Problems with Patenting Research Tools, 5 RISK: HEALTH, SAFETY & ENV'T 163 (1994). The doctrine is basically judicially created, although there is a codification for the narrow situation of firms preparing to market drugs when the patents covering those drugs expire. See 35 U.S.C. § 271 (e).
    • (1994) Risk: Health, Safety & Env't , vol.5 , pp. 163
    • Eisenberg, R.1
  • 36
    • 0013520452 scopus 로고
    • International Compulsory Licensing: The Rationales and the Reality
    • For general discussions, see Merges, supra note 13, at 102-05, and Gianna Julian-Arnold, International Compulsory Licensing: The Rationales and the Reality, 33 IDEA 349 (1993). The use of the dependency license is restricted by art. 31 of the Uruguay Round TRIPS Agreement, Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, Including Trade in Counterfeit Goods, Dec. 15, 1993, GATT Doc. MTN/FA II-A1C, which requires, inter alia, that "the invention claimed in the second patent shall involve an important technical advance of considerable economic significance in relation to the invention claimed in the first patent," and that "the owner of the first patent shall be entitled to a cross-license on reasonable terms to use the invention claimed in the second patent." Moreover, any such compulsory license shall "be authorized predominantly for the supply of the domestic market of the Member authorizing such use," but this condition is not obligatory "where such use is permitted to remedy a practice determined after judicial or administrative process to be anti-competitive."
    • (1993) Idea , vol.33 , pp. 349
    • Julian-Arnold, G.1
  • 37
    • 84866214533 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle, Loi 92-597, art. L. 613-15 (July 1, 1992)
    • Code de la Propriété Intellectuelle, Loi 92-597, art. L. 613-15 (July 1, 1992).
  • 38
    • 18044382658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Code specifically provides: The Tribunal de Grande Instance, having heard the Ministère Public, may, in the public interest, grant, on request, which may not be before the time specified in article L. 613-11 [three years after patent grant or four years after patent application] a non-exclusive license to the holder of the improvement to the extent necessary to the practice of the invention covered by this patent, and to the extent that the invention covered by the improvement patent reflects important technological progress over the prior patent. The holder of the first patent may obtain, upon request to the tribunal, the grant of a license on the improvement patent. Id.
  • 39
    • 18044395088 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Sept. 11
    • See, e.g., Prepared Statement of Jacques J. Gorlin, Director, Intellectual Property Committee, Hearings Subcomm. on Trade of the House Ways and Means Comm. (Sept. 11, 1996); Prepared Statement of Michael K. Kirk, Executive Director, American Intellectual Property Law Association, Hearings Before the Subcomm. on Energy and Environment of the House Comm. on Science (May 2, 1996).
    • (1996) Hearings Subcomm. on Trade of the House Ways and Means Comm.
    • Gorlin, J.J.1
  • 40
    • 18044362657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May 2
    • See, e.g., Prepared Statement of Jacques J. Gorlin, Director, Intellectual Property Committee, Hearings Subcomm. on Trade of the House Ways and Means Comm. (Sept. 11, 1996); Prepared Statement of Michael K. Kirk, Executive Director, American Intellectual Property Law Association, Hearings Before the Subcomm. on Energy and Environment of the House Comm. on Science (May 2, 1996).
    • (1996) Hearings before the Subcomm. on Energy and Environment of the House Comm. on Science
    • Kirk, M.K.1
  • 41
    • 18044381261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 2d ed. 1980 (discussing the concept extensively and presenting 1958-60 congressional studies). Scherer dropped the issue from his more recent edition. For a brief review of the European discussion, see Foray, supra note 12, at 126-27
    • See F.M. SCHERER, INDUSTRIAL MARKET STRUCTURE AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE 456-57 (2d ed. 1980) (discussing the concept extensively and presenting 1958-60 congressional studies). Scherer dropped the issue from his more recent edition. For a brief review of the European discussion, see Foray, supra note 12, at 126-27.
    • Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance , pp. 456-457
    • Scherer, F.M.1
  • 42
    • 18044386295 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Chang notes that under his model of the follow-on invention issue, a compulsory license could be a way to enforce the royalty allocation formula that he concludes would create the best possible incentives for each of the inventors. Chang, supra note 11, at 43.
  • 43
    • 84935498471 scopus 로고
    • The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal
    • See, e.g., the leading article, Louis Kaplow, The Patent-Antitrust Intersection: A Reappraisal, 97 HARV. L. REV. 1813 (1984).
    • (1984) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.97 , pp. 1813
    • Kaplow, L.1
  • 44
    • 21344488355 scopus 로고
    • Intellectual Property and the Antitrust Pendulum: Recent Developments at the Interface between the Antitrust and Intellectual Property Laws
    • See, e.g., Data Gen. Corp. v. Grumman Sys. Support Corp., 36 F.3d 1147 (1st Cir. 1994); Miller Insituform, Inc. v. Insituform of N. Am., Inc., 830 F.2d 606 (1987); SCM Corp. v. Xerox Corp., 463 F. Supp. 983 (D. Conn. 1978), aff'd, 645 F.2d 1195 (2d Cir. 1981), cert. denied, 455 U.S. 1016 (1982); see generally Norman Rosen, Intellectual Property and the Antitrust Pendulum: Recent Developments at the Interface Between the Antitrust and Intellectual Property Laws, 62 ANTITRUST L.J. 669 (1994).
    • (1994) Antitrust L.J. , vol.62 , pp. 669
    • Rosen, N.1
  • 45
    • 18044389053 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 36 F.3d at 1187
    • 36 F.3d at 1187.
  • 46
    • 18044365541 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 463 F. Supp. at 1013
    • 463 F. Supp. at 1013.
  • 47
    • 18044386914 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Admittedly, the new products would not be possible without the initial invention; they would not be possible without the subsequent invention either.
  • 48
    • 18044373827 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The standard would be very similar to that of Radio Telefis Eireann v. Commission, 4 C.M.L.R. 718 (E.C.J. 1995), in which a copyright holder was required to grant a license to permit creation of an all-channel TV guide. In thus overriding an intellectual property right on competition grounds, the court stated: The appellants' refusal to provide basic information by relying on national copyright provisions thus prevented the appearance of a new product, a comprehensive weekly guide to television programmes, which the appellants did not offer and for which there was a potential consumer demand. Such refusal constitutes an abuse under . . . Article 86 . . . . Id. at 791. As in the discussion in the text, the logic is that the intellectual property right is being stretched to cover markets beyond that for which it reasonably confers a monopoly.
  • 49
    • 18044381073 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Supra note 4
    • Supra note 4.
  • 50
    • 18044383865 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Moreover, action under antitrust law avoids the limitations imposed on the dependency license under art. 31 of TRIPS, supra note 32.
  • 51
    • 18044381658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Commission Reg. 240/96 of 31 Jan. 1996 on the Application of Article 85(3) of the Treaty to Certain Categories of Technology Transfer Agreements, O.J. (L 31) 2 (Feb. 9, 1996). Article 2(1)(4) states that certain grantback license requirements are acceptable provided that, in certain circumstances, they are nonexclusive and reciprocal; art. 3(6) states that an assignment requirement is not acceptable.
  • 52
    • 18044384037 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • U.S. Department of Justice and Federal Trade Commission Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of Intellectual Property (1995) § 5.6, reprinted in 4 Trade Reg. Rep. (CCH) ¶ 13,132 [hereinafter IP Guidelines]; see United States v. Pilkington, Civ. Action No. 94-345, Competitive Impact Statement (D. Ariz. filed May 25, 1994), 59 Fed. Reg. 30,604 (June 14, 1994).
  • 53
    • 0040991454 scopus 로고
    • E.g., Intel Corp. v. ULSI Sys. Technology, Inc., 995 F.2d 1566 (Fed. Cir. 1993); Intel Corp. v. U.S. Int'l Trade Comm'n, 946 F.2d 821 (Fed. Cir. 1991); Cyrix Corp. v. Intel Corp., 879 F. Supp. 672 (E.D. Tex. 1995); see generally FRED WARSHOFSKY, THE PATENT WARS (1994).
    • (1994) The Patent Wars
    • Warshofsky, F.1
  • 54
    • 18044369417 scopus 로고
    • Dec. 19
    • For example, Agracetus licensed its cotton technology to Monsanto and Calgene, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, Dec. 19, 1994, at 5; but more recently, Monsanto purchased Agracetus, John A. Jones, Monsanto Using Biotech to Develop New Farm Chemicals, INVESTOR'S BUS. DAILY, July 1, 1996, at B14, and acquired a substantial interest in Calgene, Mara Bovsun, Monsanto to Acquire Half of Calgene for Expertise, $30M, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, July 3, 1995, at 1.
    • (1994) Biotechnology Newswatch , pp. 5
  • 55
    • 18044395257 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Monsanto Using Biotech to Develop New Farm Chemicals
    • July 1
    • For example, Agracetus licensed its cotton technology to Monsanto and Calgene, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, Dec. 19, 1994, at 5; but more recently, Monsanto purchased Agracetus, John A. Jones, Monsanto Using Biotech to Develop New Farm Chemicals, INVESTOR'S BUS. DAILY, July 1, 1996, at B14, and acquired a substantial interest in Calgene, Mara Bovsun, Monsanto to Acquire Half of Calgene for Expertise, $30M, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, July 3, 1995, at 1.
    • (1996) Investor's Bus. Daily
    • Jones, J.A.1
  • 56
    • 84866210801 scopus 로고
    • Monsanto to Acquire Half of Calgene for Expertise, $30M
    • July 3
    • For example, Agracetus licensed its cotton technology to Monsanto and Calgene, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, Dec. 19, 1994, at 5; but more recently, Monsanto purchased Agracetus, John A. Jones, Monsanto Using Biotech to Develop New Farm Chemicals, INVESTOR'S BUS. DAILY, July 1, 1996, at B14, and acquired a substantial interest in Calgene, Mara Bovsun, Monsanto to Acquire Half of Calgene for Expertise, $30M, BIOTECHNOLOGY NEWSWATCH, July 3, 1995, at 1.
    • (1995) Biotechnology Newswatch , pp. 1
    • Bovsun, M.1
  • 57
    • 84866205861 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carpet Seaming Tape Licensing Corp. v. Best Seam Inc., 616 F.2d 1133 (9th Cir. 1980); see generally IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5
    • See Carpet Seaming Tape Licensing Corp. v. Best Seam Inc., 616 F.2d 1133 (9th Cir. 1980); see generally IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5.
  • 58
    • 84866205860 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5 & example 7
    • IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5 & example 7.
  • 59
    • 18044364173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Admittedly, Texas Instruments broke with the pattern and brought suit against competitors under unlicensed patents. See, e.g., Texas Instruments, Inc. v. U.S. Int'l Trade Comm'n, 988 F.2d 1165 (Fed. Cir. 1993). The incentives to do so are strongest for a firm with a relatively weak product position, for such a firm is least vulnerable to countersuit by its competitors.
  • 60
    • 0001765293 scopus 로고
    • Cartels and Patent License Arrangements
    • This analysis assumes, of course, that sham use of a patent arrangement to define price or quantity allocation cartels is an antitrust violation, and deals instead with the impact on innovation. On the price and quantity allocation cartel issues, see George L. Priest, Cartels and Patent License Arrangements, 20 J.L. & ECON. 309 (1977).
    • (1977) J.L. & Econ. , vol.20 , pp. 309
    • Priest, G.L.1
  • 61
    • 21344444303 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Shape of Things to Come: Innovation Market Analysis in Merger Cases
    • See United States v. Automobile Mfrs. Ass'n, 1969 Trade Cas. (CCH) ¶ 72,907 (C.D. Cal. 1969) (cross-license of automobile emissions control technology); Thomas N. Dahdouh & James F. Mongoven, The Shape of Things to Come: Innovation Market Analysis in Merger Cases, 64 ANTITRUST L.J. 405, 425-29 (1996).
    • (1996) Antitrust L.J. , vol.64 , pp. 405
    • Dahdouh, T.N.1    Mongoven, J.F.2
  • 62
    • 84866217414 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 374 U.S. 174 (1963); see also IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5 (citing discussion in Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985))
    • 374 U.S. 174 (1963); see also IP Guidelines, supra note 47, § 5.5 (citing discussion in Northwest Wholesale Stationers, Inc. v. Pacific Stationery & Printing Co., 472 U.S. 284 (1985)).
  • 63
    • 0004542172 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • May see, e.g., The Upjohn Co., 60 Fed. Reg. 56.153 (FTC Nov. 7, 1995); Glaxo plc. 60 Fed. Reg. 16.139 (FTC Mar. 29, 1995); Boston Scientific Corp., 60 Fed. Reg. 12.948 (FTC Mar. 9, 1995)
    • IP Guidelines, supra note 47. §§ 3.2.2 & 3.2.3: FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION STAFF, ANTICIPATING THE 21ST CENTURY: COMPETITION POLICY IN THE NEW HIGH-TECH. GLOBAL MARKET PLACE (May 1996); see, e.g., The Upjohn Co., 60 Fed. Reg. 56.153 (FTC Nov. 7, 1995); Glaxo plc. 60 Fed. Reg. 16.139 (FTC Mar. 29, 1995); Boston Scientific Corp., 60 Fed. Reg. 12.948 (FTC Mar. 9, 1995).
    • (1996) Anticipating the 21st Century: Competition Policy in the New High-tech. Global Market Place
  • 64
    • 21344495002 scopus 로고
    • Symposium: Joint Ventura, Including Strategic Alliances, to Develop Computer Technology
    • This should not, of course, be read to mean that the participants in a focused cross-license designed, as part of a strategic alliance, to develop new technology for a specific market should thereby be held to have lost their right to maintain any form of exclusivity. Such a focused strategic alliance is a competitively desirable business operation. And, in the normal case, the parties to the strategic alliance will not have substantial market power, they will typically not be in direct competition, and their licensing restraints will be limited to those needed to maintain incentives to develop a specific product. See Symposium: Joint Ventura, Including Strategic Alliances, to Develop Computer Technology, 61 ANTITRUST L.J. 859 (1993).
    • (1993) Antitrust L.J. , vol.61 , pp. 859


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.