메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 8, Issue 1, 1997, Pages 151-171

The subtle vices behind environmental values

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0031390218     PISSN: 10643958     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Conference Paper
Times cited : (2)

References (111)
  • 1
    • 0040504691 scopus 로고
    • Assessing and Managing Risks
    • Critics of probabilism have contended that the method furthers a "right-wing political agenda." See William Leiss, Assessing and Managing Risks, 25 POL'Y SCI. 341, 343 (1992).
    • (1992) Pol'y Sci. , vol.25 , pp. 341
    • Leiss, W.1
  • 2
    • 0012345005 scopus 로고
    • Risk Objectivism and Risk Subjectivism: When Are Risks Real?
    • Paul B. Thompson, Risk Objectivism and Risk Subjectivism: When Are Risks Real?, 1 RISK: ISSUES IN HEALTH AND SAFETY 3, 22 (1990).
    • (1990) Risk: Issues in Health and Safety , vol.1 , pp. 3
    • Thompson, P.B.1
  • 3
    • 7844238645 scopus 로고
    • Afterthoughts
    • Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds.
    • See, e.g., Adam Finkel, Afterthoughts, in WORST THINGS FIRST?: THE DEBATE OVER RISK-BASED NATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL PRIORITIES 335, 336-37 (Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds., 1994) (suggesting that citizens' value assessments should prevail over scientific estimation). Others have a more nuanced view. Cass Sunstein suggests that citizens' value judgments about risk deserve respect so long as they are "both reflective and informed. " Cass R. Sunstein, Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48 STAN L. REV. 247, 267 (1996). While the thrust of the article appears to credit public perceptions, his caveats of informed reflection might well obliterate a role for such perceptions. In addition, he has also observed that the "mere fact that certain values are expressed through public action does not, of course, mean that those values must be endorsed. " Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 71 n.233 (1995). This article attempts to elaborate the seldom recognized point that public values about risk may be unworthy of incorporation in government regulation.
    • (1994) Worst Things First?: The Debate over Risk-based National Environmental Priorities , pp. 335
    • Finkel, A.1
  • 4
    • 84937276351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State
    • See, e.g., Adam Finkel, Afterthoughts, in WORST THINGS FIRST?: THE DEBATE OVER RISK-BASED NATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL PRIORITIES 335, 336-37 (Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds., 1994) (suggesting that citizens' value assessments should prevail over scientific estimation). Others have a more nuanced view. Cass Sunstein suggests that citizens' value judgments about risk deserve respect so long as they are "both reflective and informed. " Cass R. Sunstein, Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48 STAN L. REV. 247, 267 (1996). While the thrust of the article appears to credit public perceptions, his caveats of informed reflection might well obliterate a role for such perceptions. In addition, he has also observed that the "mere fact that certain values are expressed through public action does not, of course, mean that those values must be endorsed. " Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 71 n.233 (1995). This article attempts to elaborate the seldom recognized point that public values about risk may be unworthy of incorporation in government regulation.
    • (1996) Stan L. Rev. , vol.48 , pp. 247
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 5
    • 84885215480 scopus 로고
    • Reinventing the Regulatory State
    • See, e.g., Adam Finkel, Afterthoughts, in WORST THINGS FIRST?: THE DEBATE OVER RISK-BASED NATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL PRIORITIES 335, 336-37 (Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds., 1994) (suggesting that citizens' value assessments should prevail over scientific estimation). Others have a more nuanced view. Cass Sunstein suggests that citizens' value judgments about risk deserve respect so long as they are "both reflective and informed. " Cass R. Sunstein, Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State, 48 STAN L. REV. 247, 267 (1996). While the thrust of the article appears to credit public perceptions, his caveats of informed reflection might well obliterate a role for such perceptions. In addition, he has also observed that the "mere fact that certain values are expressed through public action does not, of course, mean that those values must be endorsed. " Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1, 71 n.233 (1995). This article attempts to elaborate the seldom recognized point that public values about risk may be unworthy of incorporation in government regulation.
    • (1995) U. Chi. L. Rev. , vol.62 , Issue.233 , pp. 1
    • Pildes, R.H.1    Sunstein, C.R.2
  • 6
    • 79951603045 scopus 로고
    • Valuing Food Safety in Experimental Auction Markets
    • It is also important to recognize that public perception may underestimate risks. While the typical debate confronts a public perceiving high risk vs. low probability estimates, the public probably underestimates more risks. See, e.g., Dermot J. Hayes et al., Valuing Food Safety in Experimental Auction Markets, 77 AM. J. AGRIC. ECON. 40 (1995) (documenting public underestimation of risk from foodborne pathogens).
    • (1995) Am. J. Agric. Econ. , vol.77 , pp. 40
    • Hayes, D.J.1
  • 7
    • 84909285546 scopus 로고
    • Preferences and Politics
    • See Cass R. Sunstein, Preferences and Politics, 20 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 3 (1991). He observes that the "phenomenon of endogenous preferences casts doubt on the notion that a democratic government ought to respect private desires and beliefs in all or almost all contexts." Id. at 5. With respect to risk perception, see William H. Foege, Plagues: Perceptions of Risk and Social Responses, 55 SOC. RES. 331, 334-335 (1988) (concluding that we "know from recent studies that the perception of risk that people have for many conditions is unrealistic, unstable, and influenced by illusions of control").
    • (1991) Phil. & Pub. Aff. , vol.20 , pp. 3
    • Sunstein, C.R.1
  • 8
    • 84928838205 scopus 로고
    • Plagues: Perceptions of Risk and Social Responses
    • See Cass R. Sunstein, Preferences and Politics, 20 PHIL. & PUB. AFF. 3 (1991). He observes that the "phenomenon of endogenous preferences casts doubt on the notion that a democratic government ought to respect private desires and beliefs in all or almost all contexts." Id. at 5. With respect to risk perception, see William H. Foege, Plagues: Perceptions of Risk and Social Responses, 55 SOC. RES. 331, 334-335 (1988) (concluding that we "know from recent studies that the perception of risk that people have for many conditions is unrealistic, unstable, and influenced by illusions of control").
    • (1988) Soc. Res. , vol.55 , pp. 331
    • Foege, W.H.1
  • 9
    • 0041299561 scopus 로고
    • The Public Role in Risk Control
    • See Frank B. Cross, The Public Role in Risk Control, 24 ENVTL. L. 887, 897-912 (1994).
    • (1994) Envtl. L. , vol.24 , pp. 887
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 10
    • 0002677403 scopus 로고
    • Characterizing Perceived Risk
    • Robert W. Kates et al. eds.
    • See Paul Slovic et al., Characterizing Perceived Risk, in PERILOUS PROGRESS: MANAGING THE HAZARDS OF TECHNOLOGY 91, 1115 (Robert W. Kates et al. eds., 1985); George A. Quattrone & Amos Tversky, Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice, 82 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 719, 735 (1988). See also Cross, supra note 6, at 891.
    • (1985) Perilous Progress: Managing the Hazards of Technology , pp. 91
    • Slovic, P.1
  • 11
    • 84971721852 scopus 로고
    • Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice
    • See Paul Slovic et al., Characterizing Perceived Risk, in PERILOUS PROGRESS: MANAGING THE HAZARDS OF TECHNOLOGY 91, 1115 (Robert W. Kates et al. eds., 1985); George A. Quattrone & Amos Tversky, Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice, 82 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 719, 735 (1988). See also Cross, supra note 6, at 891.
    • (1988) Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. , vol.82 , pp. 719
    • Quattrone, G.A.1    Tversky, A.2
  • 12
    • 7844224423 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Cross, supra note 6, at 891
    • See Paul Slovic et al., Characterizing Perceived Risk, in PERILOUS PROGRESS: MANAGING THE HAZARDS OF TECHNOLOGY 91, 1115 (Robert W. Kates et al. eds., 1985); George A. Quattrone & Amos Tversky, Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analyses of Political Choice, 82 AM. POL. SCI. REV. 719, 735 (1988). See also Cross, supra note 6, at 891.
  • 13
    • 7844245807 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cross, supra note 6, at 889-90
    • See Cross, supra note 6, at 889-90.
  • 14
    • 7844237901 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 891-95
    • See id. at 891-95.
  • 15
    • 7844235499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 892, 898-99
    • See id. at 892, 898-99.
  • 16
    • 0012145894 scopus 로고
    • Public Choices between Lifesaving Programs: How Important Are Lives Saved?
    • Aug.
    • See Maureen L. Cropper & Uma Subramanian, Public Choices Between Lifesaving Programs: How Important Are Lives Saved?, WORLD BANK POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER No. 1497 (Aug. 1995). The variation in preference among lifesaving programs was up to 2.5 times the probabilistic life saving. This is roughly consistent with other research. See, e.g., John M. Mendeloff & Robert M. Kaplan, Are Large Differences in "Lifesaving" Costs Justified? A Psychometric Study of the Relative Value Placed on Preventing Deaths, 9 RISK ANALYSIS 349 (1989) (finding differences up to two-fold in preferences among programs with equal lifesaving).
    • (1995) World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1497
    • Cropper, M.L.1    Subramanian, U.2
  • 17
    • 0024450198 scopus 로고
    • Are Large Differences in "Lifesaving" Costs Justified? A Psychometric Study of the Relative Value Placed on Preventing Deaths
    • See Maureen L. Cropper & Uma Subramanian, Public Choices Between Lifesaving Programs: How Important Are Lives Saved?, WORLD BANK POLICY RESEARCH WORKING PAPER No. 1497 (Aug. 1995). The variation in preference among lifesaving programs was up to 2.5 times the probabilistic life saving. This is roughly consistent with other research. See, e.g., John M. Mendeloff & Robert M. Kaplan, Are Large Differences in "Lifesaving" Costs Justified? A Psychometric Study of the Relative Value Placed on Preventing Deaths, 9 RISK ANALYSIS 349 (1989) (finding differences up to two-fold in preferences among programs with equal lifesaving).
    • (1989) Risk Analysis , vol.9 , pp. 349
    • Mendeloff, J.M.1    Kaplan, R.M.2
  • 18
    • 0004265832 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., HOWARD MARGOLIS, DEALING WITH RISK 114 (1996) (suggesting that factors identified as causes of public concern may simply be ways to rationalize such concerns). People give relatively little heed to certain catastrophic risks, such as dam failure.
    • (1996) Dealing with Risk , pp. 114
    • Margolis, H.1
  • 19
    • 7844238644 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cross supra note 6, at 914-918, 924-926
    • See Cross supra note 6, at 914-918, 924-926.
  • 20
    • 7844232973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 924 n.130
    • See id. at 924 n.130.
  • 21
    • 0021408029 scopus 로고
    • Modeling the Societal Impact of Fatal Accidents
    • Paul Slovic, Sarah Lichtenstein, & Baruch Fischhoff, Modeling the Societal Impact of Fatal Accidents, 30 MGMT. SCI. 464, 467 (1984).
    • (1984) Mgmt. Sci. , vol.30 , pp. 464
    • Slovic, P.1    Lichtenstein, S.2    Fischhoff, B.3
  • 22
    • 0030130888 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Developing a Subject-Derived Terminology to Describe Perceptions of Chemicals in Foods
    • Monique M. Raats & Richard Shepherd, Developing a Subject-Derived Terminology to Describe Perceptions of Chemicals in Foods, 16 RISK ANALYSIS 133 (1996).
    • (1996) Risk Analysis , vol.16 , pp. 133
    • Raats, M.M.1    Shepherd, R.2
  • 24
    • 0012310737 scopus 로고
    • The Risk of Reliance on Perceived Risk
    • Frank B. Cross, The Risk of Reliance on Perceived Risk, 3 RISK: ISSUES IN HEALTH & SAFETY 59, 66 (1992).
    • (1992) Risk: Issues in Health & Safety , vol.3 , pp. 59
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 25
    • 0026722936 scopus 로고
    • Perceived Risk and Fear of Crime: Role of Social and Physical Incivilities
    • Randy LaGrange, Kenneth Ferraro & Michael Supancic, Perceived Risk and Fear of Crime: Role of Social and Physical Incivilities, 29 J. RES. IN CRIME & DELINQUENCY 311, 319 (1992).
    • (1992) J. Res. in Crime & Delinquency , vol.29 , pp. 311
    • LaGrange, R.1    Ferraro, K.2    Supancic, M.3
  • 26
    • 7844224033 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 328
    • Id. at 328.
  • 29
    • 0000851209 scopus 로고
    • Environmental Equity: A Law and Planning Approach to Environmental Racism
    • See Robert W. Collin, Environmental Equity: A Law and Planning Approach to Environmental Racism, 11 VA. ENVTL. L.J. 495, 509-510 (1992).
    • (1992) Va. Envtl. L.J. , vol.11 , pp. 495
    • Collin, R.W.1
  • 30
    • 5844240168 scopus 로고
    • What's Fairness Got to Do with It? Environmental Justice and the Siting of Locally Undesirable Land Uses
    • See Vicki Been, What's Fairness Got To Do with It? Environmental Justice and the Siting of Locally Undesirable Land Uses, 78 CORNELL L. REV. 1001 (1993).
    • (1993) Cornell L. Rev. , vol.78 , pp. 1001
    • Been, V.1
  • 31
    • 7844243643 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Risk-Based Priorities and Environmental Justice
    • supra note 3, at 267, 268
    • Albert L. Nichols, Risk-Based Priorities and Environmental Justice, in WORST THINGS FIRST?, supra note 3, at 267, 268.
    • Worst Things First?
    • Nichols, A.L.1
  • 32
    • 0003016635 scopus 로고
    • Black, Brown, Poor & Poisoned: Minority Grassroots Environmentalism and the Quest for Eco-Justice
    • Regina Austin & Michael H. Schill, Black, Brown, Poor & Poisoned: Minority Grassroots Environmentalism and the Quest for Eco-Justice, 1 KAN. J.L. & PUB. POL'Y 69, 78 (1991).
    • (1991) Kan. J.L. & Pub. Pol'y , vol.1 , pp. 69
    • Austin, R.1    Schill, M.H.2
  • 34
    • 85046673410 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paradigms, Process and Politics: Risk and Regulatory Design
    • supra note 3, at 147, 160
    • See Donald T. Hornstein, Paradigms, Process and Politics: Risk and Regulatory Design, in WORST THINGS FIRST?, supra note 3, at 147, 160 (indicating that the EDB ban was "based on overblown fears of consumer carcinogenicity and an underestimate of the risks to pesticide applicators who would be forced to use more carcinogenic substitutes").
    • Worst Things First?
    • Hornstein, D.T.1
  • 35
    • 7844224420 scopus 로고
    • Nonpessimistic Risk Assessment and de Minimis Risk as Risk Management Tools
    • Dennis J. Paustenbach ed.
    • Chris Whipple, Nonpessimistic Risk Assessment and De Minimis Risk as Risk Management Tools, in THE RISK ASSESSMENT OF ENVIRONMENTAL AND HUMAN HEALTH HAZARDS 1109 (Dennis J. Paustenbach ed., 1989).
    • (1989) The Risk Assessment of Environmental and Human Health Hazards , pp. 1109
    • Whipple, C.1
  • 36
    • 85052062166 scopus 로고
    • Asbestos in Schools: A Remonstrance Against Panic
    • See Frank B. Cross, Asbestos in Schools: A Remonstrance Against Panic, 11 COLUM J. ENVTL. L. 73 (1986).
    • (1986) Colum J. Envtl. L. , vol.11 , pp. 73
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 38
    • 7844221401 scopus 로고
    • Environmentalism and Racism
    • February
    • See Tom Arrandale, Environmentalism and Racism, GOVERNING, February 1992, at 63 (reporting how EPA "overlooked minority protests by approving such objectionable projects as a PCB disposal facility in predominantly black Warren County, North Carolina, and a hazardous waste landfill in Kettleman City, a Latino farmworker community in California").
    • (1992) Governing , pp. 63
    • Arrandale, T.1
  • 39
    • 0001860609 scopus 로고
    • Unequal Protection: The Racial Divide in Environmental Law
    • Sept. 21
    • See Marianne Lavell & Marcia Coyle, Unequal Protection: The Racial Divide in Environmental Law, NAT. L.J., Sept. 21, 1992, at S1.
    • (1992) Nat. L.J.
    • Lavell, M.1    Coyle, M.2
  • 40
    • 21144472007 scopus 로고
    • Environmental Policy and Equity: The Case of Superfund
    • John A. Hird, Environmental Policy and Equity: The Case of Superfund, 12 J. POL'Y ANALYSIS & MGMT. 323, 338 (1993).
    • (1993) J. Pol'y Analysis & Mgmt. , vol.12 , pp. 323
    • Hird, J.A.1
  • 41
    • 7844251918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 42
    • 7844232971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • BULLARD, supra note 22, at 17
    • BULLARD, supra note 22, at 17.
  • 43
    • 0037734862 scopus 로고
    • Who Pays for Industrial Pollution Abatement?
    • See H. David Robison, Who Pays for Industrial Pollution Abatement?, REV. ECON. STAT. 702, 703 (1985).
    • (1985) Rev. Econ. Stat. , pp. 702
    • Robison, H.D.1
  • 44
    • 21844515876 scopus 로고
    • When Environmental Regulations Kill: The Role of Health/Health Analysis
    • Frank B. Cross, When Environmental Regulations Kill: The Role of Health/Health Analysis, 22 ECOL. L.Q. 729, 763 (1995) (citing multiple studies on the regressive incidence of pollution control costs). The costs of water pollution control requirements in Boston reportedly have forced 100,000 households to "cut back on food, clothing, and medical care. " David Stipp, Poor Pay a Big Price to Drink Clean Water, WALL ST. J., Jan. 15, 1992, at B1.
    • (1995) Ecol. L.Q. , vol.22 , pp. 729
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 45
    • 4243686107 scopus 로고
    • Poor Pay a Big Price to Drink Clean Water
    • Jan. 15
    • Frank B. Cross, When Environmental Regulations Kill: The Role of Health/Health Analysis, 22 ECOL. L.Q. 729, 763 (1995) (citing multiple studies on the regressive incidence of pollution control costs). The costs of water pollution control requirements in Boston reportedly have forced 100,000 households to "cut back on food, clothing, and medical care. " David Stipp, Poor Pay a Big Price to Drink Clean Water, WALL ST. J., Jan. 15, 1992, at B1.
    • (1992) Wall St. J.
    • Stipp, D.1
  • 46
    • 21344485321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cross, supra note 38, at 763
    • Cross, supra note 38, at 763. See also Ralph L. Keeney, Mortality Risks Induced by the Costs of Regulation, 8 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 95, 106 (1994) (suggesting that environmental regulations shift job opportunities from manufacturing to white collar occupations).
  • 47
    • 21344485321 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mortality Risks Induced by the Costs of Regulation
    • Cross, supra note 38, at 763. See also Ralph L. Keeney, Mortality Risks Induced by the Costs of Regulation, 8 J. RISK & UNCERTAINTY 95, 106 (1994) (suggesting that environmental regulations shift job opportunities from manufacturing to white collar occupations).
    • (1994) J. Risk & Uncertainty , vol.8 , pp. 95
    • Keeney, R.L.1
  • 48
    • 0023605622 scopus 로고
    • Predation Through Regulation: The Wage and Profit Effects of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration and the Environmental Protection Agency
    • See Ann P. Bartel & Lacy Glenn Thomas, Predation Through Regulation: The Wage and Profit Effects of the Occupational Safety and Health Administration and the Environmental Protection Agency, 30 J.L. & ECON. 239, 246 (1987).
    • (1987) J.L. & Econ. , vol.30 , pp. 239
    • Bartel, A.P.1    Thomas, L.G.2
  • 49
    • 0003462695 scopus 로고
    • It is suggested that "[a]voiding technological risks is a central preoccupation of our age." SHEILA JASANOFF, RISK MANAGEMENT AND POLITICAL CULTURE 1 (1986); see generally, Robin Gregory, James Flynn, & Paul Slovic, Technological Stigma, AM. SCI., May/June 1995, at 220-223.
    • (1986) Risk Management and Political Culture , pp. 1
    • Jasanoff, S.1
  • 50
    • 0001399783 scopus 로고
    • Technological Stigma
    • May/June
    • It is suggested that "[a]voiding technological risks is a central preoccupation of our age." SHEILA JASANOFF, RISK MANAGEMENT AND POLITICAL CULTURE 1 (1986); see generally, Robin Gregory, James Flynn, & Paul Slovic, Technological Stigma, AM. SCI., May/June 1995, at 220-223.
    • (1995) Am. Sci. , pp. 220-223
    • Gregory, R.1    Flynn, J.2    Slovic, P.3
  • 51
    • 7844225179 scopus 로고
    • Beware of False Gods in Rio
    • June 1
    • Beware of False Gods in Rio, WALL ST. J., June 1, 1992, at A12.
    • (1992) Wall St. J.
  • 52
    • 7844244336 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There's No Going Back to Nature
    • Sept./Oct.
    • For a vigorous liberal defense of technology and criticism of much contemporary environmentalism as Luddite, see Walter Truett Anderson, There's No Going Back to Nature, MOTHER JONES, Sept./Oct. 1996, at 34. The anti-technology bias of ecofeminism is particularly ironic, as women have consistently benefited from advances. See also Johana Brenner & Nancy Holmstrom, Women's Self-Organization, 34 MONTHLY REV. 34 (1983) (technology had enabled women to advance in the workplace); Sharon Camp, Population: The Critical Decade, FOREIGN POL'Y, March 22, 1993, at 126 (describing how additional technological advance can "further improve women's status and economic security"). In poorer nations, the "preservation of species and the protection of nature" have depended "upon social exclusion of races, of women, and of other nationalities. " Cecile Jackson, Environmentalisms and Gender Interests in the Third World, 24 DEV. & CHANGE 649, 654 (1993).
    • (1996) Mother Jones , pp. 34
    • Anderson, W.T.1
  • 53
    • 7844246183 scopus 로고
    • Women's Self-Organization
    • For a vigorous liberal defense of technology and criticism of much contemporary environmentalism as Luddite, see Walter Truett Anderson, There's No Going Back to Nature, MOTHER JONES, Sept./Oct. 1996, at 34. The anti-technology bias of ecofeminism is particularly ironic, as women have consistently benefited from advances. See also Johana Brenner & Nancy Holmstrom, Women's Self-Organization, 34 MONTHLY REV. 34 (1983) (technology had enabled women to advance in the workplace); Sharon Camp, Population: The Critical Decade, FOREIGN POL'Y, March 22, 1993, at 126 (describing how additional technological advance can "further improve women's status and economic security"). In poorer nations, the "preservation of species and the protection of nature" have depended "upon social exclusion of races, of women, and of other nationalities. " Cecile Jackson, Environmentalisms and Gender Interests in the Third World, 24 DEV. & CHANGE 649, 654 (1993).
    • (1983) Monthly Rev. , vol.34 , pp. 34
    • Brenner, J.1    Holmstrom, N.2
  • 54
    • 85055294901 scopus 로고
    • Population: The Critical Decade
    • March 22
    • For a vigorous liberal defense of technology and criticism of much contemporary environmentalism as Luddite, see Walter Truett Anderson, There's No Going Back to Nature, MOTHER JONES, Sept./Oct. 1996, at 34. The anti-technology bias of ecofeminism is particularly ironic, as women have consistently benefited from advances. See also Johana Brenner & Nancy Holmstrom, Women's Self-Organization, 34 MONTHLY REV. 34 (1983) (technology had enabled women to advance in the workplace); Sharon Camp, Population: The Critical Decade, FOREIGN POL'Y, March 22, 1993, at 126 (describing how additional technological advance can "further improve women's status and economic security"). In poorer nations, the "preservation of species and the protection of nature" have depended "upon social exclusion of races, of women, and of other nationalities. " Cecile Jackson, Environmentalisms and Gender Interests in the Third World, 24 DEV. & CHANGE 649, 654 (1993).
    • (1993) Foreign Pol'y , pp. 126
    • Camp, S.1
  • 55
    • 0027714085 scopus 로고
    • Environmentalisms and Gender Interests in the Third World
    • For a vigorous liberal defense of technology and criticism of much contemporary environmentalism as Luddite, see Walter Truett Anderson, There's No Going Back to Nature, MOTHER JONES, Sept./Oct. 1996, at 34. The anti-technology bias of ecofeminism is particularly ironic, as women have consistently benefited from advances. See also Johana Brenner & Nancy Holmstrom, Women's Self-Organization, 34 MONTHLY REV. 34 (1983) (technology had enabled women to advance in the workplace); Sharon Camp, Population: The Critical Decade, FOREIGN POL'Y, March 22, 1993, at 126 (describing how additional technological advance can "further improve women's status and economic security"). In poorer nations, the "preservation of species and the protection of nature" have depended "upon social exclusion of races, of women, and of other nationalities. " Cecile Jackson, Environmentalisms and Gender Interests in the Third World, 24 DEV. & CHANGE 649, 654 (1993).
    • (1993) Dev. & Change , vol.24 , pp. 649
    • Jackson, C.1
  • 56
    • 0003731425 scopus 로고
    • WILLIAM TUCKER, PROGRESS AND PRIVILEGE: AMERICA IN THE AGE OF ENVIRONMENTALISM 37 (1982). Carl Anthony describes a Berkeley public hearing at which antidevelopment environmentalists booed blacks testifying on the need for jobs, causing him to feel as if he were dealing with the Ku Klux Klan. See Carl Anthony, Eco-Justice, TURNING WHEEL, Spring 1993, at 19.
    • (1982) Progress and Privilege: America in the Age of Environmentalism , pp. 37
    • Tucker, W.1
  • 57
    • 7844241260 scopus 로고
    • Eco-Justice
    • Spring
    • WILLIAM TUCKER, PROGRESS AND PRIVILEGE: AMERICA IN THE AGE OF ENVIRONMENTALISM 37 (1982). Carl Anthony describes a Berkeley public hearing at which antidevelopment environmentalists booed blacks testifying on the need for jobs, causing him to feel as if he were dealing with the Ku Klux Klan. See Carl Anthony, Eco-Justice, TURNING WHEEL, Spring 1993, at 19.
    • (1993) Turning Wheel , pp. 19
    • Anthony, C.1
  • 59
    • 7844229882 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • S. 2806, 102d Cong. (1992)
    • S. 2806, 102d Cong. (1992).
  • 60
    • 7844243280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 61
    • 7844251553 scopus 로고
    • Concentrations of Lead in Blood Drop Steeply
    • July 27
    • See Sandra Blakeslee, Concentrations of Lead in Blood Drop Steeply, N.Y. TIMES, July 27, 1994, at A18 (reporting a 78% reduction in lead levels in the bloodstream of the affected public).
    • (1994) N.Y. Times
    • Blakeslee, S.1
  • 62
    • 7844249279 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Nichols, supra note 25, at 270
    • See Nichols, supra note 25, at 270.
  • 63
    • 7844251207 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 268
    • Id. at 268.
  • 66
    • 85050712534 scopus 로고
    • Populist Influences on American Fascism
    • See, e.g., RICHARD HOFSTADTER, THE AMERICAN POLITICAL TRADITION (1948); Victor Ferkiss, Populist Influences on American Fascism, 10 WESTERN POL. Q. 350 (1957)
    • (1957) Western Pol. Q. , vol.10 , pp. 350
    • Ferkiss, V.1
  • 68
    • 7844242267 scopus 로고
    • Cultural Values affecting Risk Perception: Individualism and the Perception of Toxicological Risks
    • Louis A. Cox, Jr. & Paolo F. Ricci, eds.
    • See Janet M. Fitchen, Cultural Values affecting Risk Perception: Individualism and the Perception of Toxicological Risks, in NEW RISKS: ISSUES AND MANAGEMENT 602 (Louis A. Cox, Jr. & Paolo F. Ricci, eds., 1990).
    • (1990) New Risks: Issues and Management , pp. 602
    • Fitchen, J.M.1
  • 69
    • 0012510439 scopus 로고
    • Choosing and Managing Technology-Induced Risk
    • Theodore S. Glickman & Michael Gough eds.
    • See M. Granger Morgan, Choosing and Managing Technology-Induced Risk, in READINGS IN RISK 21 (Theodore S. Glickman & Michael Gough eds., 1990).
    • (1990) Readings in Risk , pp. 21
    • Granger Morgan, M.1
  • 70
    • 7844244685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 86
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 86.
  • 71
    • 7844244335 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 39 (noting that characteristics like voluntariness mean "perceived voluntariness")
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 39 (noting that characteristics like voluntariness mean "perceived voluntariness").
  • 72
    • 0006209298 scopus 로고
    • Poisoning the Wells
    • Douglas MacLean ed.
    • See, e.g., Annette Baier, Poisoning the Wells, in VALUES AT RISK 66 (Douglas MacLean ed., 1986) (observing that a coal miner might accept his employment out of compulsion, "even when he is not, like a member of a chain gang, literally coerced into working there").
    • (1986) Values at Risk , pp. 66
    • Baier, A.1
  • 74
    • 0022923792 scopus 로고
    • Tolerance for Environmental Health Risks: The Influence of Knowledge, Benefits, Voluntariness, and Environmental Attitudes
    • See Brian Baird, Tolerance for Environmental Health Risks: The Influence of Knowledge, Benefits, Voluntariness, and Environmental Attitudes, 6 RISK ANALYSIS 425, 430 (1986).
    • (1986) Risk Analysis , vol.6 , pp. 425
    • Baird, B.1
  • 75
    • 7844231350 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 73
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 73.
  • 76
    • 7844252290 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Baird, supra note 60, at 430 (suggesting that the distinction is between an event "perceived as voluntary while the other is perceived as involuntary")
    • See Baird, supra note 60, at 430 (suggesting that the distinction is between an event "perceived as voluntary while the other is perceived as involuntary").
  • 77
    • 33745796004 scopus 로고
    • Justifying Risk
    • See Andreas Teuber, Justifying Risk, 119 DAEDALUS 235, 249 (1990) (suggesting that "you are not morally required to obtain the permission of everyone who might be in the path of your car should it go out of control on your way to the post office").
    • (1990) Daedalus , vol.119 , pp. 235
    • Teuber, A.1
  • 78
    • 0003439620 scopus 로고
    • Joel Feinberg contends that risks to life cannot be so automatically prohibited without considering "the independent value of the risk-creating conduct both to the actor himself, to others directly affected by it, and to society in general." JOEL FEINBERG, HARM TO OTHERS 191 (1984).
    • (1984) Harm to Others , pp. 191
    • Feinberg, J.1
  • 80
    • 7844248679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 265
    • Id. at 265.
  • 81
    • 0039253464 scopus 로고
    • Acceptable Risk: A Conceptual Proposal
    • Baruch Fischhoff, Acceptable Risk: A Conceptual Proposal, 5 RISK: ISSUES IN HEALTH AND SAFETY 1, 23 (1994). This effect translates into policy - politicians are notoriously hesitant to legislate or regulate when large numbers of citizens are directly involved in the risk-creating activity. See also WILLIAM C. MITCHELL & RANDY T. SIMMONS, BEYOND POLITICS 149 (1994).
    • (1994) Risk: Issues in Health and Safety , vol.5 , pp. 1
    • Fischhoff, B.1
  • 82
    • 0038549501 scopus 로고
    • Baruch Fischhoff, Acceptable Risk: A Conceptual Proposal, 5 RISK: ISSUES IN HEALTH AND SAFETY 1, 23 (1994). This effect translates into policy - politicians are notoriously hesitant to legislate or regulate when large numbers of citizens are directly involved in the risk-creating activity. See also WILLIAM C. MITCHELL & RANDY T. SIMMONS, BEYOND POLITICS 149 (1994).
    • (1994) Beyond Politics , pp. 149
    • Mitchell, W.C.1    Simmons, R.T.2
  • 84
    • 7844235836 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Margolis refers to the situation as "fungibility," where the same person bears both the risk and reaps the benefits. See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 76-77. In the absence of fungibility, individuals can make selfish choices contrary to society's best interests
    • Margolis refers to the situation as "fungibility," where the same person bears both the risk and reaps the benefits. See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 76-77. In the absence of fungibility, individuals can make selfish choices contrary to society's best interests.
  • 85
    • 7844245463 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. at 129
    • See id. at 129.
  • 86
    • 7844250855 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id. 169
    • See id. 169.
  • 87
    • 7844234403 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Margolis would emphasize that the key to decision making is not the actual fungibility of risks and benefits, but the perceptions of risks and benefits. Thus, an individual decides based on whether he or she perceives personal benefits from an activity, not whether actual benefits accrue. This does not change the deontological selfishness of the choice, but does suggest that some people are incompetent at being selfish
    • Margolis would emphasize that the key to decision making is not the actual fungibility of risks and benefits, but the perceptions of risks and benefits. Thus, an individual decides based on whether he or she perceives personal benefits from an activity, not whether actual benefits accrue. This does not change the deontological selfishness of the choice, but does suggest that some people are incompetent at being selfish.
  • 88
    • 84928223576 scopus 로고
    • Safety and the Second Best: The Hazards of Public Risk Management in the Courts
    • Peter Huber, Safety and the Second Best: The Hazards of Public Risk Management in the Courts, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 277, 283 (1985).
    • (1985) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 277
    • Huber, P.1
  • 89
    • 0028252630 scopus 로고
    • Rethinking Informed Consent
    • Peter H. Schuck, Rethinking Informed Consent, 103 YALE L.J. 899, 901 (1994).
    • (1994) Yale L.J. , vol.103 , pp. 899
    • Schuck, P.H.1
  • 91
    • 7844247609 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 40 (observing that "[w]e ordinarily see it as selfish for an individual to insist on absolute protection of his rights and property with no regard for the costs to others or to society generally" and that "we do not feel that it is unfair if the community is less than sympathetic to people demanding their rights when no significant harm is threatened")
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 40 (observing that "[w]e ordinarily see it as selfish for an individual to insist on absolute protection of his rights and property with no regard for the costs to others or to society generally" and that "we do not feel that it is unfair if the community is less than sympathetic to people demanding their rights when no significant harm is threatened").
  • 92
    • 7844233341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 117
    • SHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 117.
  • 93
    • 7844233340 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Surely some whites in places such as Vidor, Texas perceive that allowing blacks or hispanics to settle in their community would present a physical risk. Yet we do not require the consent of each citizen before authorizing a minority housing project in the community
    • Surely some whites in places such as Vidor, Texas perceive that allowing blacks or hispanics to settle in their community would present a physical risk. Yet we do not require the consent of each citizen before authorizing a minority housing project in the community.
  • 94
    • 7844245081 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., Cross, supra note 38
    • See, e.g., Cross, supra note 38.
  • 95
    • 7844231702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SCHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 218. Indeed, the consent requirement can descend into circularity and nihilism. If your withholding consent creates a risk to me, do you need my consent before withholding your consent?
    • SCHRADER-FRECHETTE, supra note 21, at 218. Indeed, the consent requirement can descend into circularity and nihilism. If your withholding consent creates a risk to me, do you need my consent before withholding your consent?
  • 96
    • 7844241939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See GRAHAM & WIENER, supra note 31
    • See GRAHAM & WIENER, supra note 31; See also, Frank B. Cross, Paradoxical Perils of the Precautionary Principle, 53 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 851 (1996) (where I recently provided somewhat less detailed accounts of dozens of circumstances in which efforts to reduce one risk have created greater countervailing risks).
  • 97
    • 0001650575 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Paradoxical Perils of the Precautionary Principle
    • See GRAHAM & WIENER, supra note 31; See also, Frank B. Cross, Paradoxical Perils of the Precautionary Principle, 53 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 851 (1996) (where I recently provided somewhat less detailed accounts of dozens of circumstances in which efforts to reduce one risk have created greater countervailing risks).
    • (1996) Wash. & Lee L. Rev. , vol.53 , pp. 851
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 98
    • 7844223658 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Schuck, supra note 74, at 939
    • See Schuck, supra note 74, at 939.
  • 99
    • 7844231701 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rick Pildes has suggested to me that the nature of voluntariness and the necessity of consent might be defined by a communitarian assessment of risk. While this alleviates some of the obvious practicality problems of requiring consent for environmental risks, the approach simultaneously obliterates much of the libertarian appeal of the consent standard itself
    • Rick Pildes has suggested to me that the nature of voluntariness and the necessity of consent might be defined by a communitarian assessment of risk. While this alleviates some of the obvious practicality problems of requiring consent for environmental risks, the approach simultaneously obliterates much of the libertarian appeal of the consent standard itself.
  • 100
    • 7844227351 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 31 (contending that "it is hard to believe that there has never been a single good case in which lay judgment turned out to be better than expert judgment")
    • See MARGOLIS, supra note 12, at 31 (contending that "it is hard to believe that there has never been a single good case in which lay judgment turned out to be better than expert judgment").
  • 101
    • 0004289224 scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., JAMES FISHKIN, DEMOCRACY AND DELIBERATION 36 (1991) (generally making the case for deliberation over a plebiscitary democracy); Sunstein, supra note 5, at 4 (noting that U.S. democracy is deliberative and involves "institutions of representation" rather than "an aggregation of interests").
    • (1991) Democracy and Deliberation , pp. 36
    • Fishkin, J.1
  • 102
    • 7844234069 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See Pildes & Sunstein, supra note 3, at 59 (suggesting that "[o]urs is a republic, not a pure democracy, and a high premium is placed on deliberation rather than on snapshots of public opinion"); Cross, supra note 6, at 953 (urging that deliberation be a fundamental aspect of risk governance). The Harvard School of Public Health risk policy group contends that it "is not plausible to think that existing risk regulation reflects a considered democratic judgment," as it "appears to be a response to sensationalistic anecdotes, or to interest-group pressures, rather than to deliberative judgments by the public about priorities for risk management." HARVARD GROUP ON RISK MANAGEMENT REFORM, supra note 51, at 17.
  • 103
    • 3242884714 scopus 로고
    • Hammers Don't Cut Wood, Why We Need Pollution Prevention and Comparative Risk Assessment
    • Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds.
    • See Cross, supra note 18, at 68-69 (relating the liberating effects of reliance on science vs. subjectivism). John Graham contends that the transparency of scientific analysis "is consistent with the principles of Jeffersonian democracy." John D. Graham, Hammers Don't Cut Wood, Why We Need Pollution Prevention and Comparative Risk Assessment, in WORST THINGS FIRST?: THE DEBATE OVER RISK-BASED NATIONAL ENVIRONMENTAL PRIORITIES 229, 233 (Adam M. Finkel & Dominic Golding eds., 1994).
    • (1994) Worst Things First?: The Debate over Risk-based National Environmental Priorities , pp. 229
    • Graham, J.D.1
  • 104
    • 0344641908 scopus 로고
    • The Risk Not Reduced
    • See John D. Graham, The Risk Not Reduced, 3 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 382, 399 (1995) (suggesting that people "recognize that it is dangerous to allow the whims of journalists and public opinion to be the primary determinants of risk policy"); Frank B. Cross, Why Shouldn't We Regulate the Worst Things First?, 4 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 312, 317-318 (1996) (citing various sources indicating that credibility of environmental policy depends on grounding in sound science).
    • (1995) N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. , vol.3 , pp. 382
    • Graham, J.D.1
  • 105
    • 0041800070 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Why Shouldn't We Regulate the Worst Things First?
    • See John D. Graham, The Risk Not Reduced, 3 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 382, 399 (1995) (suggesting that people "recognize that it is dangerous to allow the whims of journalists and public opinion to be the primary determinants of risk policy"); Frank B. Cross, Why Shouldn't We Regulate the Worst Things First?, 4 N.Y.U. ENVTL. L.J. 312, 317-318 (1996) (citing various sources indicating that credibility of environmental policy depends on grounding in sound science).
    • (1996) N.Y.U. Envtl. L.J. , vol.4 , pp. 312
    • Cross, F.B.1
  • 107
    • 0005083149 scopus 로고
    • The Pathology of Symbolic Legislation
    • When government policies are based on public perceptions, they tend to produce only symbolic action with relatively little beneficial effect. See John Dwyer, The Pathology of Symbolic Legislation, 17 ECOLOGY L.Q. 233 (1990).
    • (1990) Ecology L.Q. , vol.17 , pp. 233
    • Dwyer, J.1
  • 108
    • 0011372761 scopus 로고
    • Preferences for Pesticide Regulation
    • See John Horowitz, Preferences for Pesticide Regulation, 76 AM. J. AGRIC. ECON. 396 (1994) (finding particular concern for pesticide regulation vs. auto exhaust regulation but also discovering that 71% of subjects would prefer the regulation that saved the most lives regardless of the risk source).
    • (1994) Am. J. Agric. Econ. , vol.76 , pp. 396
    • Horowitz, J.1
  • 109
    • 0024450198 scopus 로고
    • Are Large Differences in "Lifesaving" Costs Justified? A Psychometric Study of the Relative Value Placed on Preventing Deaths
    • See, e.g., John M. Mendeloff & Robert M. Kaplan, Are Large Differences in "Lifesaving" Costs Justified? A Psychometric Study of the Relative Value Placed on Preventing Deaths, 9 RISK ANALYSIS 349 (1989) (finding variance in public value preferences to be far smaller than actual differences in government actions to reduce risk).
    • (1989) Risk Analysis , vol.9 , pp. 349
    • Mendeloff, J.M.1    Kaplan, R.M.2
  • 110
    • 7844227005 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 111
    • 7844223657 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Cross, supra note 6, at 933 (quoting former EPA Administrator William Reilly to the effect that "public concerns are constantly changing, demanding that we make everything a top priority")
    • See Cross, supra note 6, at 933 (quoting former EPA Administrator William Reilly to the effect that "public concerns are constantly changing, demanding that we make everything a top priority").


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.