메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 71, Issue 4, 1997, Pages 569-602

The reichskuratorium für wirtschaftlichkeit: Fordism and organized capitalism in Germany, 1918-1945

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0031329790     PISSN: 00076805     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/3116307     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (15)

References (159)
  • 1
    • 84977111405 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.
    • Charles S. Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade after World War I (Princeton, N.J., 1978); Gerald D. Feldman, Army, Industry, and Labor in Germany, 1914-1918 (Princeton, N.J., 1966); idem., Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916-1923 (Princeton, N.J., 1977); and most recently his definitive work, The Great Disorder. Politics, Economy, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914-1924 (Oxford, 1993).
    • (1978) Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade after World War I
    • Maier, C.S.1
  • 2
    • 0010213381 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.
    • Charles S. Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade after World War I (Princeton, N.J., 1978); Gerald D. Feldman, Army, Industry, and Labor in Germany, 1914-1918 (Princeton, N.J., 1966); idem., Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916-1923 (Princeton, N.J., 1977); and most recently his definitive work, The Great Disorder. Politics, Economy, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914-1924 (Oxford, 1993).
    • (1966) Army, Industry, and Labor in Germany, 1914-1918
    • Feldman, G.D.1
  • 3
    • 84922079319 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.
    • Charles S. Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade after World War I (Princeton, N.J., 1978); Gerald D. Feldman, Army, Industry, and Labor in Germany, 1914-1918 (Princeton, N.J., 1966); idem., Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916-1923 (Princeton, N.J., 1977); and most recently his definitive work, The Great Disorder. Politics, Economy, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914-1924 (Oxford, 1993).
    • (1977) Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916-1923
    • Feldman, G.D.1
  • 4
    • 0004037421 scopus 로고
    • Oxford
    • Charles S. Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe: Stabilization in France, Germany, and Italy in the Decade after World War I (Princeton, N.J., 1978); Gerald D. Feldman, Army, Industry, and Labor in Germany, 1914-1918 (Princeton, N.J., 1966); idem., Iron and Steel in the German Inflation, 1916-1923 (Princeton, N.J., 1977); and most recently his definitive work, The Great Disorder. Politics, Economy, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914-1924 (Oxford, 1993).
    • (1993) The Great Disorder. Politics, Economy, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914-1924
  • 6
    • 0003853324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe, 141-142. Feldman, The Great Disorder, 137-155. See also Wichard von Moellendorff, Konservativer Sozialismus (Berlin, 1932), 166-195.
    • Recasting Bourgeois Europe , pp. 141-142
    • Maier1
  • 7
    • 0010105977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe, 141-142. Feldman, The Great Disorder, 137-155. See also Wichard von Moellendorff, Konservativer Sozialismus (Berlin, 1932), 166-195.
    • The Great Disorder , pp. 137-155
    • Feldman1
  • 8
    • 0039059972 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe, 141-142. Feldman, The Great Disorder, 137-155. See also Wichard von Moellendorff, Konservativer Sozialismus (Berlin, 1932), 166-195.
    • (1932) Konservativer Sozialismus , pp. 166-195
    • Von Moellendorff, W.1
  • 9
    • 0003853324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe, 140-141; Peter von Oertzen, Betriebsräte in der Novemberrevolution (Düsseldorf, 1963); Feldman, The Great Disorder, 138-143, 289-292.
    • Recasting Bourgeois Europe , pp. 140-141
    • Maier1
  • 11
    • 0010105977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Maier, Recasting Bourgeois Europe, 140-141; Peter von Oertzen, Betriebsräte in der Novemberrevolution (Düsseldorf, 1963); Feldman, The Great Disorder, 138-143, 289-292.
    • The Great Disorder , pp. 138-143
    • Feldman1
  • 13
    • 0040243897 scopus 로고
    • Big business and the Kapp Putsch
    • The putsch effort occurred in the early days of March 1920 and was centered in Berlin. It was defeated by a general strike of Berlin's working classes. The business and labor representatives of the ZAG disagreed about appropriate reaction to the effort to overthrow the new Republic. See Gerald D. Feldman, "Big Business and the Kapp Putsch," Central European History 4 (1971): 91-130; Gerald D. Feldman and Irmgard Steinisch, Industrie und Gewerkschaften, 1918-1924. Die überforderte Zentralarbeitsgemeinschaft (Stuttgart, 1985).
    • (1971) Central European History , vol.4 , pp. 91-130
    • Feldman, G.D.1
  • 14
    • 0040243897 scopus 로고
    • Stuttgart
    • The putsch effort occurred in the early days of March 1920 and was centered in Berlin. It was defeated by a general strike of Berlin's working classes. The business and labor representatives of the ZAG disagreed about appropriate reaction to the effort to overthrow the new Republic. See Gerald D. Feldman, "Big Business and the Kapp Putsch," Central European History 4 (1971): 91-130; Gerald D. Feldman and Irmgard Steinisch, Industrie und Gewerkschaften, 1918-1924. Die überforderte Zentralarbeitsgemeinschaft (Stuttgart, 1985).
    • (1985) Industrie und Gewerkschaften, 1918-1924. Die Überforderte Zentralarbeitsgemeinschaft
    • Feldman, G.D.1    Steinisch, I.2
  • 15
    • 0040838457 scopus 로고
    • ed. Hagen Schulze Boppard am Rhein, documents 63a, 272-283 and 63b, 284-289, respectively. The original documents may be found in the Bundes-Archiv, Koblenz (BA), R 43 I/1146
    • Moellendorff's white paper, or Denkschrift, on the planned economy, which he submitted to the Reich Economics Ministry, has been published as "Denkschrift des Reichswirtschaftsministeriums zur wirtschaftspolitischen Lage" and "Wirtschaftsprogramm des Reichswirtschaftsministeriums," both of 7 May 1919, in Akten der Reichskanzlei, Weimarer Republik. Das Kabinett Scheidemann, 13. Februar bis 20. Juni 1919, ed. Hagen Schulze (Boppard am Rhein, 1971), documents 63a, 272-283 and 63b, 284-289, respectively. The original documents may be found in the Bundes-Archiv, Koblenz (BA), R 43 I/1146.
    • (1971) Akten der Reichskanzlei, Weimarer Republik. Das Kabinett Scheidemann, 13. Februar Bis 20. Juni 1919
  • 17
    • 0040243901 scopus 로고
    • Die auseinandersetzung um die sozialisierung der kohle in Deutschland 1920/21
    • On the collapse of coal socialization efforts, see P. Wulf, "Die Auseinandersetzung um die Sozialisierung der Kohle in Deutschland 1920/21," Vierteljahresschrift für Zeitgeschichte 25(1977): 46-98.
    • (1977) Vierteljahresschrift für Zeitgeschichte , vol.25 , pp. 46-98
    • Wulf, P.1
  • 18
    • 0004000957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Berkeley, Calif.
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • (1933) The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning
    • Brady, R.A.1
  • 19
    • 0040243905 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • National productivity board
    • Oxford
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany , vol.1994
    • Nolan, M.1
  • 20
    • 0040838450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Oxford
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • (1994) The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry
    • Parnell, M.F.1
  • 21
    • 0040838462 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ed. Heinrich August Winkler Göttinngen
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge , pp. 1974
  • 22
    • 0003853324 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • Recasting Bourgeois Europe.
    • Maier, C.S.1
  • 23
    • 84972778550 scopus 로고
    • The first post-liberal nation: Stages in the development of corporatism in Germany
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • (1984) European History Quarterly , vol.14 , pp. 285-318
  • 24
    • 0040838450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period
    • Translating the title "Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit" is difficult. The word Wirtschaftlichkeit has no single equivalent in English. The German word connotes, in general, the overall effectiveness of an industrial or economic enterprise or production process. Robert A. Brady, writing in the 1930's, rendered the name as "National Board for Economy and Efficiency." See Robert A. Brady, The Rationalization Movement in German Industry: A Study in Economic Planning (Berkeley, Calif., 1933). More recently, Mary Nolan has opted for "National Productivity Board." See her Visions of Modernity: American Business and the Modernization of Germany (Oxford, 1994). Martin Parnell adopts the somewhat anachronistic variation, "Imperial Institute of Efficiency," since the organization was not founded until after the collapse of the German Empire in 1918. See Martin F. Parnell The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism. Self Government in the Coal Industry (Oxford, 1994) On the German tradition of "organized capitalism," see Organisierter Kapitalismus. Voraussetzungen und Anfänge, ed. Heinrich August Winkler (Göttinngen, 1974); Charles S. Maier has elaborated a variation of "corporatism" in his Recasting Bourgeois Europe. Werner Abelshauser, "The First Post-Liberal Nation: Stages in the Development of Corporatism in Germany," European History Quarterly 14 (1984): 285-318, argues that the "heyday of German corporatism was the interwar era (296-304); more recently, Parnell, in his The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, stresses the dimension of industrial "self-regulation" (Selbstverwaltung) within industry-state relations in Germany since the imperial period.
    • The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism
    • Parnell1
  • 25
    • 0003624740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Frederick Winslow Taylor died in 1915. He is associated with scientific and stopwatch studies of labor processes and shop-floor production practices, and the planning of such industrial tasks by a managerial echelon. Ford developed the techniques of assembly line and flow manufacture. On Taylor, the most recent biography is Robert Kanigel, The One Best Way: Frederick Winslow Taylor and the Enigma of Efficiency (New York, 1997). See also Daniel Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management (Madison, Wise., 1980). On Henry Ford, see Keith Sward, The Legend of Henry Ford (New York, 1968).
    • (1997) The One Best Way: Frederick Winslow Taylor and the Enigma of Efficiency
    • Kanigel, R.1
  • 26
    • 0003575341 scopus 로고
    • Madison, Wise
    • Frederick Winslow Taylor died in 1915. He is associated with scientific and stopwatch studies of labor processes and shop-floor production practices, and the planning of such industrial tasks by a managerial echelon. Ford developed the techniques of assembly line and flow manufacture. On Taylor, the most recent biography is Robert Kanigel, The One Best Way: Frederick Winslow Taylor and the Enigma of Efficiency (New York, 1997). See also Daniel Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management (Madison, Wise., 1980). On Henry Ford, see Keith Sward, The Legend of Henry Ford (New York, 1968).
    • (1980) Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management
    • Nelson, D.1
  • 27
    • 0004049770 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Frederick Winslow Taylor died in 1915. He is associated with scientific and stopwatch studies of labor processes and shop-floor production practices, and the planning of such industrial tasks by a managerial echelon. Ford developed the techniques of assembly line and flow manufacture. On Taylor, the most recent biography is Robert Kanigel, The One Best Way: Frederick Winslow Taylor and the Enigma of Efficiency (New York, 1997). See also Daniel Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management (Madison, Wise., 1980). On Henry Ford, see Keith Sward, The Legend of Henry Ford (New York, 1968).
    • (1968) The Legend of Henry Ford
    • Sward, K.1
  • 28
    • 84972742818 scopus 로고
    • Between taylorism and technocracy: European ideologies and the vision of industrial productivity in the 1920's
    • Charles S. Maier, "Between Taylorism and Technocracy: European Ideologies and the Vision of Industrial Productivity in the 1920's," Journal of Contemporary History 5 (1970): 27-61. Maier argues here that both the European Left and Right came to view technocratic and efficiency measures, based largely on the production time studies and efficiency efforts of the American engineer Frederick W. Taylor from the prewar years, as having potential to circumvent the "zero-sum" class conflict between labor and industry in the immediate years after 1918. His analysis and argument, however, do not extend very far beyond the collapse of these utopian strivings in the early 1920's.
    • (1970) Journal of Contemporary History , vol.5 , pp. 27-61
    • Maier, C.S.1
  • 29
    • 79957719805 scopus 로고
    • Probleme der zeit
    • R. Hilferding, "Probleme der Zeit," Die Gesellschaft I/I (1924), 2, quoted in Harold James, The German Slump: Politics and Economics 1924-1936 (Oxford, 1986), 119. For the original full statement of Hilferding's theory of "finance capitalism," see Rudolf Hilferding, Finanzkapital. Eine Studie über die jüngste Entwicklung des Kapitalismus (Vienna, 1910).
    • (1924) Die Gesellschaft I/I , pp. 2
    • Hilferding, R.1
  • 30
    • 0003421197 scopus 로고
    • Oxford
    • R. Hilferding, "Probleme der Zeit," Die Gesellschaft I/I (1924), 2, quoted in Harold James, The German Slump: Politics and Economics 1924-1936 (Oxford, 1986), 119. For the original full statement of Hilferding's theory of "finance capitalism," see Rudolf Hilferding, Finanzkapital. Eine Studie über die jüngste Entwicklung des Kapitalismus (Vienna, 1910).
    • (1986) The German Slump: Politics and Economics 1924-1936 , pp. 119
    • James, H.1
  • 31
    • 0039059946 scopus 로고
    • Vienna
    • R. Hilferding, "Probleme der Zeit," Die Gesellschaft I/I (1924), 2, quoted in Harold James, The German Slump: Politics and Economics 1924-1936 (Oxford, 1986), 119. For the original full statement of Hilferding's theory of "finance capitalism," see Rudolf Hilferding, Finanzkapital. Eine Studie über die jüngste Entwicklung des Kapitalismus (Vienna, 1910).
    • (1910) Finanzkapital. Eine Studie Über die Jüngste Entwicklung des Kapitalismus
    • Hilferding, R.1
  • 33
    • 0040838456 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The classic study of Germany's integrated and regulated war economy during World War I is Feldman, Army, Industry, and Labor. See also Friedrich Zunkel, Industrie und Staatssozialismus. Der Kampf um die Wirtschaftsordnung in Deutschland 1914-1918 (Düsseldorf, 1974).
    • Army, Industry, and Labor
    • Feldman1
  • 35
    • 0003488577 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge, Mass., especially 393-395 and 587-592. Chandler does identify a declining significance of the large private German banks, or "Grossbanken," by the 1930s, however. See pp. 590-591
    • Alfred D. Chandler, Jr., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism (Cambridge, Mass., 1990), 393-592, especially 393-395 and 587-592. Chandler does identify a declining significance of the large private German banks, or "Grossbanken," by the 1930s, however. See pp. 590-591.
    • (1990) Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism , pp. 393-592
    • Chandler A.D., Jr.1
  • 36
    • 80054435837 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Der deutsche organisierte kapitalismus während der kriegsund inflationsjahre 1914-1923
    • Winkler ed., quotation from p. 166
    • Gerald D. Feldman, "Der deutsche Organisierte Kapitalismus während der Kriegsund Inflationsjahre 1914-1923," in Winkler ed., Organisierter Kapitalismus, 150-171; quotation from p. 166.
    • Organisierter Kapitalismus , pp. 150-171
    • Feldman, G.D.1
  • 39
    • 0040838450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While acknowledging a concept of "organized capitalism" in describing German political economy before World War I, Martin Parnell argues strongly that its chief quality has been the autonomy of self-regulatory industrial institutions. Parnell offers a case study of the Rhenish-Westphalian Coal Syndicate, whose history he traces from its inception in the late nineteenth century through the post-World War II era. See Parnell, The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism.
    • The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism
    • Parnell1
  • 40
    • 0040243883 scopus 로고
    • Das reichskuratorium für wirtschaftlichkeit
    • Organized labor was relatively slow to recognize the potential of rationalization and efficiency organizations such as the RKW for affecting labor issues in the Weimar era. The first real critique by the Weimar Left of the RKW for lack of significant labor input came only in 1930 by Otto Suhr, the Social Democrat. See Otto Suhr, "Das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit," Die Arbeit 7 (1930): 454-464.
    • (1930) Die Arbeit , vol.7 , pp. 454-464
    • Suhr, O.1
  • 41
    • 0040838450 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Though stressing the same three-part character of current German corporatism as does Abelshauser, namely that of capital, labor, and the state, Parnell acknowledges the primacy of industrial and state cooperation as the origins of German corporatism. The participation of organized labor came later, following World War I, and was integrated into a corporatist system whose foundations were laid before the war. See Parnell, The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism, 234-235.
    • The German Tradition of Organized Capitalism , pp. 234-235
    • Parnell1
  • 43
    • 0040838459 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The United States: Competitive managerial capitalism
    • See Chandler, "The United States: Competitive Managerial Capitalism," Scale and Scope, 47-233.
    • Scale and Scope , pp. 47-233
    • Chandler1
  • 44
    • 0040243890 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • On the Kaiser Wilhelm Gesellschaft, a state supported scientific research institution with interests in several areas, including biology, coal, and chemistry, see, Festschrift der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften zu ihren zehnjährigen Jubiläum dargebracht von ihren Instituten (Berlin, 1921), and Handbuch der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften (Berlin, 1928). Both were released by the institution itself. On the society in the Nazi era, see Kristie Macrakis, Surviving the Swastika: Scientific Research in Nazi Germany (New York, 1993).
    • (1921) Festschrift der Kaiser Wilhelm-gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften zu Ihren Zehnjährigen Jubiläum Dargebracht von Ihren Instituten
  • 45
    • 0039652127 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • On the Kaiser Wilhelm Gesellschaft, a state supported scientific research institution with interests in several areas, including biology, coal, and chemistry, see, Festschrift der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften zu ihren zehnjährigen Jubiläum dargebracht von ihren Instituten (Berlin, 1921), and Handbuch der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften (Berlin, 1928). Both were released by the institution itself. On the society in the Nazi era, see Kristie Macrakis, Surviving the Swastika: Scientific Research in Nazi Germany (New York, 1993).
    • (1928) Handbuch der Kaiser Wilhelm-gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften
  • 46
    • 0003605268 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • On the Kaiser Wilhelm Gesellschaft, a state supported scientific research institution with interests in several areas, including biology, coal, and chemistry, see, Festschrift der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften zu ihren zehnjährigen Jubiläum dargebracht von ihren Instituten (Berlin, 1921), and Handbuch der Kaiser Wilhelm-Gesellschaft zur Förderung der Wissenschaften (Berlin, 1928). Both were released by the institution itself. On the society in the Nazi era, see Kristie Macrakis, Surviving the Swastika: Scientific Research in Nazi Germany (New York, 1993).
    • (1993) Surviving the Swastika: Scientific Research in Nazi Germany
    • Macrakis, K.1
  • 47
    • 0039059945 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In this respect, the RKW resembled another supra-industrial interest organization, the Reichsverband der Deutschen Industrie (RDI) which was founded near the end of World War I to lobby the interests of big business in a concerted way. The RDI, however, was more strictly a lobby and interest representation organization. The RKW actively sought to find new techniques of efficiency and cost savings.
  • 51
    • 0004000957 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The American economist, Robert A. Brady, drew attention to the RKW along with numerous other planning and rationalization organizations as early as 1933. See his Rationalization Movement in German Industry; the RKW offered its own account of itself in 1928 and its relation to the Weimar "rationalization movement" in one of its own publications. See Hans Hinnenthal, Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung und das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit (Berlin, 1928). See also Hans Wolfgang Büttner, Das Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft (Düsseldorf, 1973). One recent exception to the RKW's neglect is Nolan, Visions of Modernity.
    • (1933) Rationalization Movement in German Industry
    • Brady, R.A.1
  • 52
    • 84895591540 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • The American economist, Robert A. Brady, drew attention to the RKW along with numerous other planning and rationalization organizations as early as 1933. See his Rationalization Movement in German Industry; the RKW offered its own account of itself in 1928 and its relation to the Weimar "rationalization movement" in one of its own publications. See Hans Hinnenthal, Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung und das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit (Berlin, 1928). See also Hans Wolfgang Büttner, Das Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft (Düsseldorf, 1973). One recent exception to the RKW's neglect is Nolan, Visions of Modernity.
    • (1928) Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung und das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit
    • Hinnenthal, H.1
  • 53
    • 4244064902 scopus 로고
    • Düsseldorf
    • The American economist, Robert A. Brady, drew attention to the RKW along with numerous other planning and rationalization organizations as early as 1933. See his Rationalization Movement in German Industry; the RKW offered its own account of itself in 1928 and its relation to the Weimar "rationalization movement" in one of its own publications. See Hans Hinnenthal, Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung und das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit (Berlin, 1928). See also Hans Wolfgang Büttner, Das Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft (Düsseldorf, 1973). One recent exception to the RKW's neglect is Nolan, Visions of Modernity.
    • (1973) Das Rationalisierungs-kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft
    • Büttner, H.W.1
  • 54
    • 0002722911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The American economist, Robert A. Brady, drew attention to the RKW along with numerous other planning and rationalization organizations as early as 1933. See his Rationalization Movement in German Industry; the RKW offered its own account of itself in 1928 and its relation to the Weimar "rationalization movement" in one of its own publications. See Hans Hinnenthal, Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung und das Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichkeit (Berlin, 1928). See also Hans Wolfgang Büttner, Das Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft (Düsseldorf, 1973). One recent exception to the RKW's neglect is Nolan, Visions of Modernity.
    • Visions of Modernity.
    • Nolan1
  • 55
    • 0039059932 scopus 로고
    • Stuttgart
    • On Carl Friedrich von Siemens and his career, see, Herbert Goetzeler et al., Wilhelm und Carl Friedrich von Siemens: die zweite Unternehmergeneration (Stuttgart, 1986); and Georg Siemens, Carl Friedrich von Siemens; ein grosser Unternehmer (Freiberg, 1962). On Carl Köttgen, see the short biographical sketch in Meister der Rationalisierung, ed. Kurt Pentzlin (Düsseldorf, 1963), 458-462; and The Golden Book of Management. An Historical Record of the Life and Work of Seventy Pioneers, ed. L. Urwick (London, 1956), 152-154.
    • (1986) Wilhelm und Carl Friedrich von Siemens: Die Zweite Unternehmergeneration
    • Goetzeler, H.1
  • 56
    • 84943610898 scopus 로고
    • Freiberg
    • On Carl Friedrich von Siemens and his career, see, Herbert Goetzeler et al., Wilhelm und Carl Friedrich von Siemens: die zweite Unternehmergeneration (Stuttgart, 1986); and Georg Siemens, Carl Friedrich von Siemens; ein grosser Unternehmer (Freiberg, 1962). On Carl Köttgen, see the short biographical sketch in Meister der Rationalisierung, ed. Kurt Pentzlin (Düsseldorf, 1963), 458-462; and The Golden Book of Management. An Historical Record of the Life and Work of Seventy Pioneers, ed. L. Urwick (London, 1956), 152-154.
    • (1962) Carl Friedrich Von Siemens; Ein Grosser Unternehmer
    • Siemens, G.1
  • 57
    • 26144476363 scopus 로고
    • ed. Kurt Pentzlin Düsseldorf
    • On Carl Friedrich von Siemens and his career, see, Herbert Goetzeler et al., Wilhelm und Carl Friedrich von Siemens: die zweite Unternehmergeneration (Stuttgart, 1986); and Georg Siemens, Carl Friedrich von Siemens; ein grosser Unternehmer (Freiberg, 1962). On Carl Köttgen, see the short biographical sketch in Meister der Rationalisierung, ed. Kurt Pentzlin (Düsseldorf, 1963), 458-462; and The Golden Book of Management. An Historical Record of the Life and Work of Seventy Pioneers, ed. L. Urwick (London, 1956), 152-154.
    • (1963) Meister der Rationalisierung , pp. 458-462
    • Köttgen, C.1
  • 58
    • 0040838454 scopus 로고
    • ed. L. Urwick London
    • On Carl Friedrich von Siemens and his career, see, Herbert Goetzeler et al., Wilhelm und Carl Friedrich von Siemens: die zweite Unternehmergeneration (Stuttgart, 1986); and Georg Siemens, Carl Friedrich von Siemens; ein grosser Unternehmer (Freiberg, 1962). On Carl Köttgen, see the short biographical sketch in Meister der Rationalisierung, ed. Kurt Pentzlin (Düsseldorf, 1963), 458-462; and The Golden Book of Management. An Historical Record of the Life and Work of Seventy Pioneers, ed. L. Urwick (London, 1956), 152-154.
    • (1956) The Golden Book of Management. An Historical Record of the Life and Work of Seventy Pioneers , pp. 152-154
  • 60
    • 0040243899 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In this year Adolf Schilling took over the position of editor of the journal Technik und Wirtschaft. Schilling had been named the original Geschäftsführer or Administrative Manager of the RKW in 1921. The journal was published by the widely known and respected organization of German engineers, the Verein Deutscher Ingenieure or VDI.
  • 61
    • 0039652131 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geschäftsbericht für das jahr 1921/22
    • On the Deutscher Verband technisch-wissenschaftlicher Vereine (German Association of technical-scientific organizations, or VD), see the organization's business report for the year 1921-1922, "Geschäftsbericht für das Jahr 1921/22," in the Historical Archive of the Siemens-Konzern in Munich, Germany, Siemens-Akten-Archiv, (hereafter SAA), 4/LF 564. The organization is relatively obscure and fully unstudied, but included well known member organizations such as the Association of German Engineers (Verein Deutscher Ingenieure (VDI)), Association of German Foundrymen (Verein Deutscher Eisenhüttenleute), and the Association of German Chemists (Verein Deutscher Chemiker), among many others. The 1921-22 business report lists twenty-six scientific and technical organizations among the Verband's members. It's director at this point was A. Thiele. The organization held its 1922 annual business meeting in the "Ingenieurbaus" in Berlin. See Ibid., 1.
    • Siemens-Akten-Archiv
  • 62
    • 0040838453 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the Deutscher Verband technisch-wissenschaftlicher Vereine (German Association of technical-scientific organizations, or VD), see the organization's business report for the year 1921-1922, "Geschäftsbericht für das Jahr 1921/22," in the Historical Archive of the Siemens-Konzern in Munich, Germany, Siemens-Akten-Archiv, (hereafter SAA), 4/LF 564. The organization is relatively obscure and fully unstudied, but included well known member organizations such as the Association of German Engineers (Verein Deutscher Ingenieure (VDI)), Association of German Foundrymen (Verein Deutscher Eisenhüttenleute), and the Association of German Chemists (Verein Deutscher Chemiker), among many others. The 1921-22 business report lists twenty-six scientific and technical organizations among the Verband's members. It's director at this point was A. Thiele. The organization held its 1922 annual business meeting in the "Ingenieurbaus" in Berlin. See Ibid., 1.
    • Siemens-Akten-Archiv , pp. 1
  • 63
    • 0039059941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bericht über die gründungsversammlung des reichskuratoriums für wirtschaftlichkeit in industrie und handwerk am 10. Juni 1921 im ingenieurhaus zu Berlin
    • See, SAA 4/LF 668, "Bericht über die Gründungsversammlung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit in Industrie und Handwerk am 10. Juni 1921 im Ingenieurhaus zu Berlin."
    • SAA 4/LF 668
  • 64
    • 0040243888 scopus 로고
    • Freiburg/Munich
    • As one of the newer, "dynamic" industries of the late nineteenth century, the Siemens firm counted as a leader in many trends that are considered characteristic of modern, efficient business practice. These efforts included increasing bureaucratization and managerial supervision of production, the use of more complex cost accounting, and central work offices for planning and coordinating production. On the general history of the firm, see Georg Siemens, Geschichte des Hauses Siemens (Freiburg/Munich, 1947-1952); on bureaucratic modernization, see Jürgen Kocka's now standard work, Unternehmsverwaltung und Angestellenschaft am Beispiel Siemens 1847-1914 (Stuttgart, 1969), and idem, "Family and Bureaucracy in German Industrial Management, 1850-1914," Business History Review 45 (1971): 133-156. Also, more recently, Thomas von Freyberg, Industrielle Rationalisierung in der Weimarer Repbulik. Untersucht an Beispielen aus dem Maschinenbau und Elektroindustrie (Frankfurt, 1989).
    • (1947) Geschichte des Hauses Siemens
    • Siemens, G.1
  • 65
    • 0010098053 scopus 로고
    • Stuttgart
    • As one of the newer, "dynamic" industries of the late nineteenth century, the Siemens firm counted as a leader in many trends that are considered characteristic of modern, efficient business practice. These efforts included increasing bureaucratization and managerial supervision of production, the use of more complex cost accounting, and central work offices for planning and coordinating production. On the general history of the firm, see Georg Siemens, Geschichte des Hauses Siemens (Freiburg/Munich, 1947-1952); on bureaucratic modernization, see Jürgen Kocka's now standard work, Unternehmsverwaltung und Angestellenschaft am Beispiel Siemens 1847-1914 (Stuttgart, 1969), and idem, "Family and Bureaucracy in German Industrial Management, 1850-1914," Business History Review 45 (1971): 133-156. Also, more recently, Thomas von Freyberg, Industrielle Rationalisierung in der Weimarer Repbulik. Untersucht an Beispielen aus dem Maschinenbau und Elektroindustrie (Frankfurt, 1989).
    • (1969) Unternehmsverwaltung und Angestellenschaft Am Beispiel Siemens 1847-1914
    • Kocka, J.1
  • 66
    • 84972298418 scopus 로고
    • Family and bureaucracy in German Industrial Management, 1850-1914
    • As one of the newer, "dynamic" industries of the late nineteenth century, the Siemens firm counted as a leader in many trends that are considered characteristic of modern, efficient business practice. These efforts included increasing bureaucratization and managerial supervision of production, the use of more complex cost accounting, and central work offices for planning and coordinating production. On the general history of the firm, see Georg Siemens, Geschichte des Hauses Siemens (Freiburg/Munich, 1947-1952); on bureaucratic modernization, see Jürgen Kocka's now standard work, Unternehmsverwaltung und Angestellenschaft am Beispiel Siemens 1847-1914 (Stuttgart, 1969), and idem, "Family and Bureaucracy in German Industrial Management, 1850-1914," Business History Review 45 (1971): 133-156. Also, more recently, Thomas von Freyberg, Industrielle Rationalisierung in der Weimarer Repbulik. Untersucht an Beispielen aus dem Maschinenbau und Elektroindustrie (Frankfurt, 1989).
    • (1971) Business History Review , vol.45 , pp. 133-156
    • Kocka, J.1
  • 67
    • 0039059929 scopus 로고
    • Frankfurt
    • As one of the newer, "dynamic" industries of the late nineteenth century, the Siemens firm counted as a leader in many trends that are considered characteristic of modern, efficient business practice. These efforts included increasing bureaucratization and managerial supervision of production, the use of more complex cost accounting, and central work offices for planning and coordinating production. On the general history of the firm, see Georg Siemens, Geschichte des Hauses Siemens (Freiburg/Munich, 1947-1952); on bureaucratic modernization, see Jürgen Kocka's now standard work, Unternehmsverwaltung und Angestellenschaft am Beispiel Siemens 1847-1914 (Stuttgart, 1969), and idem, "Family and Bureaucracy in German Industrial Management, 1850-1914," Business History Review 45 (1971): 133-156. Also, more recently, Thomas von Freyberg, Industrielle Rationalisierung in der Weimarer Repbulik. Untersucht an Beispielen aus dem Maschinenbau und Elektroindustrie (Frankfurt, 1989).
    • (1989) Industrielle Rationalisierung in der Weimarer Repbulik. Untersucht an Beispielen aus dem Maschinenbau und Elektroindustrie
    • Von Freyberg, T.1
  • 68
    • 0039059938 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two of the most important organizations quickly subordinated to the new RKW were the Normenausschuss der Deutschen Industrie (Committee on German Industrial Norms, NDI) and the Ausschuss für wirtschaftliche Fertigung (Committee for Efficient Manufacture, AwF). Both these organizations emerged during World War I. See Brady, Rationalization Movement, 422-423. See also Hinnenthal, Die deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung, 12-16; and Büttner, Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft, 1-25.
    • Rationalization Movement , pp. 422-423
    • Brady1
  • 69
    • 0039059942 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two of the most important organizations quickly subordinated to the new RKW were the Normenausschuss der Deutschen Industrie (Committee on German Industrial Norms, NDI) and the Ausschuss für wirtschaftliche Fertigung (Committee for Efficient Manufacture, AwF). Both these organizations emerged during World War I. See Brady, Rationalization Movement, 422-423. See also Hinnenthal, Die deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung, 12-16; and Büttner, Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft, 1-25.
    • Die Deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung , pp. 12-16
    • Hinnenthal1
  • 70
    • 4243923621 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Two of the most important organizations quickly subordinated to the new RKW were the Normenausschuss der Deutschen Industrie (Committee on German Industrial Norms, NDI) and the Ausschuss für wirtschaftliche Fertigung (Committee for Efficient Manufacture, AwF). Both these organizations emerged during World War I. See Brady, Rationalization Movement, 422-423. See also Hinnenthal, Die deutsche Rationalisierungsbewegung, 12-16; and Büttner, Rationalisierungs-Kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft, 1-25.
    • Rationalisierungs-kuratorium der Deutschen Wirtschaft , pp. 1-25
    • Büttner1
  • 71
    • 0040243896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Satzung des reichskuratoriums für wirtschaftlichkeit in industrie und handwerk beim deutschen verband technisch-wissenscahftlicher vereine, e.V
    • Section 8
    • See, SAA 4/LF 668, "Satzung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit in Industrie und Handwerk beim Deutschen Verband technisch-wissenscahftlicher Vereine, e.V," Section 8; and "Bericht Über die Gründungsversammlung," p. 3, where Siemens noted that, "Der Industrie muss Kritik darüber zustehen, welche Arbeiten wesentlich erscheinen und aufzunehmen sind. Dies ist einer der Hauptgründe, warum das Reichskuratorium mit führenden Herren der Industrie zu besetzen ist.-Die Grundlage wäre Selbständigkeit der Arbeitsstellen in Bezug auf ihr Arbeitsgebiet. Die Pflicht der Organisationen bestände nicht nur in der Berichterstattung."
    • SAA 4/LF 668
  • 72
    • 0040838442 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, SAA 4/LF 668, "Satzung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit in Industrie und Handwerk beim Deutschen Verband technisch-wissenscahftlicher Vereine, e.V," Section 8; and "Bericht Über die Gründungsversammlung," p. 3, where Siemens noted that, "Der Industrie muss Kritik darüber zustehen, welche Arbeiten wesentlich erscheinen und aufzunehmen sind. Dies ist einer der Hauptgründe, warum das Reichskuratorium mit führenden Herren der Industrie zu besetzen ist.-Die Grundlage wäre Selbständigkeit der Arbeitsstellen in Bezug auf ihr Arbeitsgebiet. Die Pflicht der Organisationen bestände nicht nur in der Berichterstattung."
    • Bericht Über Die Gründungsversammlung , pp. 3
  • 73
    • 0039059930 scopus 로고
    • Berlin, passim, but especially
    • For similar industrial attitudes in heavy industry in the Ruhr, especially in the coal mining sector, see Rudolf Tschirbs, Tarifpolitik im Ruhrbergbau, 1918-1933 (Berlin, 1986), passim, but especially 286-299.
    • (1986) Tarifpolitik im Ruhrbergbau, 1918-1933 , pp. 286-299
    • Tschirbs, R.1
  • 74
    • 0040838444 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bericht über die gründungsversammlung
    • Other members at this first meeting included the chemist and industrialist Carl Duisberg, Professor Adolf Schilling, and Fritz Neuhaus, the General Director of the machine building firm Borsig A.G. in Berlin-Tegel. From the Reich Postal Ministry came Julius Lerche, while the Reich Economics Ministry sent Paul Freiherr von Buttlar and Heinrich Ruelberg. Georg Klingenberg and Arthur Thiele represented the Deutscher Verband für technisch-wissenschaftlicher Vereine and Waldemar Hellmich participated on behalf of the Association of German Engineers (Verein Deutscher Ingenieure, VDI). See, SAA 4/LF 668, "Bericht über die Gründungsversammlung."
    • SAA 4/LF 668
  • 75
    • 0039652130 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mitglieder des reichskuratoriums für wirtschaftlichkeit in industrie und handwerk beim deutschen verband technisch-wissenschaflicher vereine
    • SAA 4/LF, 668 "Mitglieder des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit in Industrie und Handwerk beim Deutschen Verband technisch-wissenschaflicher Vereine." Document is undated, but belongs either to late 1921 or 1922. The phrase "beim Deutschen Verband technischen-wissenschaftlicher Vereine" in the RKW's title did not appear for more than a year or two after the founding of the organization.
    • SAA 4/LF, 668
  • 76
    • 0040838448 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This new group of members included figures such as Albert Vogler, director of the then large Deutsch-Luxembourg Mining and Smelting company; Georg Lippart, a director of the MAN machine building firm in Nuremberg; and Felix Deutsch, chairman of the board of directors of the AEG electrical conglomerate in Berlin. Next to Siemens as Chair (Vorsitzender) and Köttgen as Vice-Chair (stellvertretender Vorsitzender) of the organization, the number three position of leadership went to Prof. Adolf Schilling who became Administrative Director (Geschäftsführer).
  • 77
    • 0039059939 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bericht über die gründungsversammlung
    • "...der Zweck des Reichskuratoriums ist in erster Linie die Hebung der Wirtschaftlichkeit industrieller und gewerblicher Produktion auf allen Fachgebieten durch rationelle Wirtschaft und Stützung des Einzelunternehmens," in "Bericht über die Gründungsversammlung," SAA 4/LF 668, 1.
    • SAA 4/LF 668 , pp. 1
  • 78
    • 0040838446 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Satzung des reichskuratoriums
    • Siemens declared the RKW's purpose to include, "Förderung aller Bestrebungen zur Hebung der industriellen und gewerblichen Fertigung." "Satzung des Reichskuratoriums," SAA 4/LF 668, 1.
    • SAA 4/LF 668 , pp. 1
  • 79
    • 0039059937 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Geschichtliche entwicklung
    • SAA 4/LF 668, "Geschichtliche Entwicklung," 5.
    • SAA 4/LF 668 , pp. 5
  • 80
    • 0039652086 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bericht über die gründungsversammlung
    • SAA 4/LF 668, "Bericht über die Gründungsversammlung," 2.
    • SAA 4/LF 668 , pp. 2
  • 82
    • 0040243893 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Bericht über die gründungsversammlung
    • For quotations as well as the discussion of the legal character of the new RKW, see "Bericht über die Gründungsversammlung," SAA 4/LF 668, 9-10.
    • SAA 4/LF 668 , pp. 9-10
  • 83
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Industrielles management. Konzeptionen und modelle in Deutschland vor 1914
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1969) Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte , vol.56 , pp. 332-372
    • Kocka, J.1
  • 84
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Administrative coordination, allocation and monitoring concepts and comparisons
    • ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka Göttingen
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1979) Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen Im 19. und Frühen 20. Jahrhundert , pp. 28-54
    • Chandler A.D., Jr.1    Daems, H.2
  • 85
    • 0040838435 scopus 로고
    • Frankfurt
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton,
    • (1981) Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften Zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr , pp. 34-35
    • Stollberg, G.1
  • 86
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Princeton, N.J.
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1983) Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century , pp. 77-78
    • Licht, W.1
  • 87
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Baltimore, Md.
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1984) American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States
    • Hounshell, D.A.1
  • 88
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Entrepreneurs in heavy industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913
    • Spring
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1979) Business History Review , vol.53 , pp. 65-78
    • Pierenkemper, T.1
  • 89
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Göttingen
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1979) Die Westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und Unternehmerischer Erfolg
    • Pierenkemper, T.1
  • 90
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • Die wirtschaftlichen führungsschichten des ruhrgebietes in der zeit von 1890 bis 1933
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1972) Blätter für Deutsche Landesgeschichte , vol.108 , pp. 143-159
    • Croon, H.1
  • 91
    • 84925164767 scopus 로고
    • Rulers of the ruhr: Leadership and authority in German big business before 1914
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1979) Business History Review , vol.57
    • Spencer, E.G.1
  • 92
    • 0039059898 scopus 로고
    • New Brunswick, N.J.
    • The leadership of Germany's machine building and electrotechnical branches in the Weimar era has never been as thoroughly studied as its counterpart in heavy industry. I have taken this overview from the short biographical sketches provided by Pentzlin (himself a member of the movement in his early career), in Meister der Rationalisierung (Düsseldorf, 1963). The following is a brief table of birth dates for the seven important German industrialists from the 1920s that Pentzlin included in his collection of rationalization experts: Walther Rathenau 1867 Fr. von Gottl-Ottlilienfeld 1868 Carl Köttgen 1871 Fritz Neuhaus 1872 Carl F. von Siemens 1872 Georg Schlesinger 1874 Willy Hellpach 1877 Willy Hellpach was the youngest of the above and did not completely fit the pattern in that he was an academic psychologist and not an industrialist. He had strong ties, however, to the emerging field of industrial psychology, or Psychotechnik, and adhered to the rationalization movement from its early years. He was only five or six years younger than Siemens and Köttgen. On organization and managerial trends in Germany before and after World War I, see Jürgen Kocka, "Industrielles Management. Konzeptionen und Modelle in Deutschland vor 1914," Vierteljahresheft für Sozial-und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 56 (1969): 332-372 . For a general conceptual and historical overview, see Alfred D. Chandler, Jr. and Herman Daems, "Administrative Coordination, Allocation and Monitoring Concepts and Comparisons," in Recht und Entwicklung der Großunternehmen im 19. und frühen 20. Jahrhundert, ed. Norbert Horn and Jürgen Kocka (Göttingen, 1979), 28-54. Why these trends appeared first, or predominantly, in the machine building sector is an unanswered question. In part, the answer for Germany is simplified by the fact that these techniques first appeared in America's metal and machine building branches. As these trends were transferred to Germany, they came naturally into those sectors for which they needed little adaptation. Though in Germany it was not simply a question of methods transferred from America. For the influence of Italian trends in shop management in German iron and steel plants in the late nineteenth century, see Gunnar Stollberg, Rationalisierungsdebatte 1908-1933. Freie Gewerkschaften zwischen Mitwirkung und Gegenwehr (Frankfurt, 1981), 34-35. That many of these trends did appear first in American machine building and metal working sectors is an important issue. A technological answer is that the character of machine building technology lends itself to repetition, part standardization and, hence, rationalization and mass production. Assumedly, America was the most advanced industrial country in this respect, due in part to its traditional shortage of skilled labor. For a skeptical view of the labor shortage thesis for the American case, however, see Walter Licht, Working for the Railroad: The Organization of Work in the Nineteenth Century (Princeton, N.J., 1983), 77-78. The most important and thorough work in the development of mass production techniques in America is David A. Hounshell, From the American System to Mass Production, 1800-1932: The Development of Manufacturing Technology in the United States (Baltimore, Md., 1984). For a sampling of the extensive literature on Ruhr industrialists, see Toni Pierenkemper, "Entrepreneurs in Heavy Industry: Upper Silesia and the Westphalian Ruhr Region, 1852 to 1913," Business History Review 53 (Spring 1979): 65-78; idem., Die westfälischen Schwerindustriellen, 1852-1913: Soziale Struktur und unternehmerischer Erfolg (Göttingen, 1979); Helmuth Croon, "Die wirtschaftlichen Führungsschichten des Ruhrgebietes in der Zeit von 1890 bis 1933," Blätter für deutsche Landesgeschichte 108 (1972): 143-159; Elaine Glovka Spencer, "Rulers of the Ruhr: Leadership and Authority in German Big Business before 1914," Business History Review 57 (1979); and idem., Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists as Employers, 1896-1914 (New Brunswick, N.J., 1984).
    • (1984) Management and Labor in Imperial Germany: Ruhr Industrialists As Employers, 1896-1914
    • Spencer, E.G.1
  • 93
    • 0039059928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For revisions of the RKW's By-laws (Satzungen) and administrative rules (Geschäftsordnungen), see the various drafts from 1925 with marginal comments by Carl Köttgen and Prof. Adolf Schilling, among others, in SAA 4/LF 668 and SAA 61/LF 109. See also the succinct instructions from Köttgen to the RKW's legal advisor, Justizrat Dr. Zimmer, in Köttgen's letter of 28 Feb. 1925, in SAA 61/LF 109. Köttgen described briefly the problems of determining what the optimal legal form for the RKW should be, as well as the delays this created, in an Aktennotiz dated 17 March 1925, in SAA 61/LF 109. For the final versions of the Satzungen and Geschäftsordnungen, see the copies in SAA 4/LF 668 and SAA 11/LF 109.
  • 94
    • 0039059896 scopus 로고
    • Köttgen's letter to Raumer of 27 Feb. 1925
    • See the draft of Köttgen's letter to Raumer of 27 Feb. 1925, in SAA 11/LF 115.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115.
  • 95
    • 4243888098 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • See Carl Köttgen, Das wirtschaftliche Amerika (Berlin, 1925). Köttgen was among the host of German industrialists, engineers, and trade unionists who flocked to America after the end of the inflation to observe first hand the economic miracle that was in progress there. America became fashionable as never before on the Continent. See Nolan, Visions of Modernity, chap. 2, "Journeys to America," 17-29. Interestingly, each group saw in America what it wanted to see. Industrialists stressed the homogeneous domestic market, relatively low taxes and the willingness of the American worker to submit to higher labor intensity. Trade unionists pointed to the high wages and high purchasing power of the American worker. All agreed, however, that much of what America had, Germany needed. The main question was how to make Germany's industrial system emulate the American. For a contrast to Köttgen's volume, see the report published by the Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschäftsbund (ADGB), on the trip of a group of German labor leaders to America in 1925, Amerikareise deutscher Gewerkschaftsführer (Berlin, 2. ed., 1926). The objective as well as subjective impact of American industrial practice in Germany in the interwar era, of which the above literature is an example, is a relatively neglected topic. For one assessment stressing the influence on German trade union wage policy, see Peter Berg, Amerika und Deutschland. Über das deutsche Amerikabild der zwanziger Jahre (Düsseldorf, 1963). Lothar Burchardt's "Technischer Fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das Beispiel der Taylorismus-Rezeption," in Wilhelm Treue ed., Deutsche Technikgeschichte (Göttigen, 1977), 52-98, carries the analysis of the reception of Taylorism only up to the early 1920s. Maier's "Between Taylorism and Technocracy" likewise emphasizes only the early 1920s. Neither stresses the adoption of American methods into actual practice in Germany.
    • (1925) Das Wirtschaftliche Amerika
    • Köttgen, C.1
  • 96
    • 0040243854 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Visions of modernity
    • chap. 2
    • See Carl Köttgen, Das wirtschaftliche Amerika (Berlin, 1925). Köttgen was among the host of German industrialists, engineers, and trade unionists who flocked to America after the end of the inflation to observe first hand the economic miracle that was in progress there. America became fashionable as never before on the Continent. See Nolan, Visions of Modernity, chap. 2, "Journeys to America," 17-29. Interestingly, each group saw in America what it wanted to see. Industrialists stressed the homogeneous domestic market, relatively low taxes and the willingness of the American worker to submit to higher labor intensity. Trade unionists pointed to the high wages and high purchasing power of the American worker. All agreed, however, that much of what America had, Germany needed. The main question was how to make Germany's industrial system emulate the American. For a contrast to Köttgen's volume, see the report published by the Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschäftsbund (ADGB), on the trip of a group of German labor leaders to America in 1925, Amerikareise deutscher Gewerkschaftsführer (Berlin, 2. ed., 1926). The objective as well as subjective impact of American industrial practice in Germany in the interwar era, of which the above literature is an example, is a relatively neglected topic. For one assessment stressing the influence on German trade union wage policy, see Peter Berg, Amerika und Deutschland. Über das deutsche Amerikabild der zwanziger Jahre (Düsseldorf, 1963). Lothar Burchardt's "Technischer Fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das Beispiel der Taylorismus-Rezeption," in Wilhelm Treue ed., Deutsche Technikgeschichte (Göttigen, 1977), 52-98, carries the analysis of the reception of Taylorism only up to the early 1920s. Maier's "Between Taylorism and Technocracy" likewise emphasizes only the early 1920s. Neither stresses the adoption of American methods into actual practice in Germany.
    • Journeys to America , pp. 17-29
    • Nolan1
  • 97
    • 0039059934 scopus 로고
    • Düsseldorf
    • See Carl Köttgen, Das wirtschaftliche Amerika (Berlin, 1925). Köttgen was among the host of German industrialists, engineers, and trade unionists who flocked to America after the end of the inflation to observe first hand the economic miracle that was in progress there. America became fashionable as never before on the Continent. See Nolan, Visions of Modernity, chap. 2, "Journeys to America," 17-29. Interestingly, each group saw in America what it wanted to see. Industrialists stressed the homogeneous domestic market, relatively low taxes and the willingness of the American worker to submit to higher labor intensity. Trade unionists pointed to the high wages and high purchasing power of the American worker. All agreed, however, that much of what America had, Germany needed. The main question was how to make Germany's industrial system emulate the American. For a contrast to Köttgen's volume, see the report published by the Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschäftsbund (ADGB), on the trip of a group of German labor leaders to America in 1925, Amerikareise deutscher Gewerkschaftsführer (Berlin, 2. ed., 1926). The objective as well as subjective impact of American industrial practice in Germany in the interwar era, of which the above literature is an example, is a relatively neglected topic. For one assessment stressing the influence on German trade union wage policy, see Peter Berg, Amerika und Deutschland. Über das deutsche Amerikabild der zwanziger Jahre (Düsseldorf, 1963). Lothar Burchardt's "Technischer Fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das Beispiel der Taylorismus-Rezeption," in Wilhelm Treue ed., Deutsche Technikgeschichte (Göttigen, 1977), 52-98, carries the analysis of the reception of Taylorism only up to the early 1920s. Maier's "Between Taylorism and Technocracy" likewise emphasizes only the early 1920s. Neither stresses the adoption of American methods into actual practice in Germany.
    • (1963) Amerika und Deutschland. Über Das Deutsche Amerikabild der Zwanziger Jahre
    • Berg, P.1
  • 98
    • 0039059899 scopus 로고
    • Technischer fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das beispiel der taylorismus-rezeption
    • Wilhelm Treue ed., Göttigen
    • See Carl Köttgen, Das wirtschaftliche Amerika (Berlin, 1925). Köttgen was among the host of German industrialists, engineers, and trade unionists who flocked to America after the end of the inflation to observe first hand the economic miracle that was in progress there. America became fashionable as never before on the Continent. See Nolan, Visions of Modernity, chap. 2, "Journeys to America," 17-29. Interestingly, each group saw in America what it wanted to see. Industrialists stressed the homogeneous domestic market, relatively low taxes and the willingness of the American worker to submit to higher labor intensity. Trade unionists pointed to the high wages and high purchasing power of the American worker. All agreed, however, that much of what America had, Germany needed. The main question was how to make Germany's industrial system emulate the American. For a contrast to Köttgen's volume, see the report published by the Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschäftsbund (ADGB), on the trip of a group of German labor leaders to America in 1925, Amerikareise deutscher Gewerkschaftsführer (Berlin, 2. ed., 1926). The objective as well as subjective impact of American industrial practice in Germany in the interwar era, of which the above literature is an example, is a relatively neglected topic. For one assessment stressing the influence on German trade union wage policy, see Peter Berg, Amerika und Deutschland. Über das deutsche Amerikabild der zwanziger Jahre (Düsseldorf, 1963). Lothar Burchardt's "Technischer Fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das Beispiel der Taylorismus-Rezeption," in Wilhelm Treue ed., Deutsche Technikgeschichte (Göttigen, 1977), 52-98, carries the analysis of the reception of Taylorism only up to the early 1920s. Maier's "Between Taylorism and Technocracy" likewise emphasizes only the early 1920s. Neither stresses the adoption of American methods into actual practice in Germany.
    • (1977) Deutsche Technikgeschichte , pp. 52-98
    • Burchardt, L.1
  • 99
    • 0040838449 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Carl Köttgen, Das wirtschaftliche Amerika (Berlin, 1925). Köttgen was among the host of German industrialists, engineers, and trade unionists who flocked to America after the end of the inflation to observe first hand the economic miracle that was in progress there. America became fashionable as never before on the Continent. See Nolan, Visions of Modernity, chap. 2, "Journeys to America," 17-29. Interestingly, each group saw in America what it wanted to see. Industrialists stressed the homogeneous domestic market, relatively low taxes and the willingness of the American worker to submit to higher labor intensity. Trade unionists pointed to the high wages and high purchasing power of the American worker. All agreed, however, that much of what America had, Germany needed. The main question was how to make Germany's industrial system emulate the American. For a contrast to Köttgen's volume, see the report published by the Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschäftsbund (ADGB), on the trip of a group of German labor leaders to America in 1925, Amerikareise deutscher Gewerkschaftsführer (Berlin, 2. ed., 1926). The objective as well as subjective impact of American industrial practice in Germany in the interwar era, of which the above literature is an example, is a relatively neglected topic. For one assessment stressing the influence on German trade union wage policy, see Peter Berg, Amerika und Deutschland. Über das deutsche Amerikabild der zwanziger Jahre (Düsseldorf, 1963). Lothar Burchardt's "Technischer Fortschritt und sozialer Wandel. Das Beispiel der Taylorismus-Rezeption," in Wilhelm Treue ed., Deutsche Technikgeschichte (Göttigen, 1977), 52-98, carries the analysis of the reception of Taylorism only up to the early 1920s. Maier's "Between Taylorism and Technocracy" likewise emphasizes only the early 1920s. Neither stresses the adoption of American methods into actual practice in Germany.
    • Between Taylorism and Technocracy
    • Maier1
  • 100
    • 0039652126 scopus 로고
    • Köttgen to von raumer, 5 march 1925
    • SAA 11/LF 115, Köttgen to von Raumer, 5 March 1925.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115
  • 101
    • 0040243884 scopus 로고
    • Von Raumer to Köttgen, 20 April 1925
    • SAA 11/LF 115, von Raumer to Köttgen, 20 April 1925.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115
  • 102
    • 0040243878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., 2. This was a reference to the description in Köttgen's book of the American study of industrial waste and inefficiency directed by the future American President, Herbert Hoover. See Federated American Engineering Societies, Committee on the Elimination of Waste in Industry, Waste in Industry (New York, 1921). The goals and attention to eliminating inefficiencies in business and industry were common to the Hoover report and the RKW However, the Hoover report did not give rise directly to a well supported and well financed institutional effort as was the case with the RKW.
    • SAA 11/LF 115 , pp. 2
  • 103
    • 0040761029 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • Ibid., 2. This was a reference to the description in Köttgen's book of the American study of industrial waste and inefficiency directed by the future American President, Herbert Hoover. See Federated American Engineering Societies, Committee on the Elimination of Waste in Industry, Waste in Industry (New York, 1921). The goals and attention to eliminating inefficiencies in business and industry were common to the Hoover report and the RKW However, the Hoover report did not give rise directly to a well supported and well financed institutional effort as was the case with the RKW.
    • (1921) Waste in Industry
  • 104
    • 0040243856 scopus 로고
    • Von Raumer to Köttgen, 20 April 1925
    • SAA 11/LF 115, von Raumer to Köttgen, 20 April 1925, 2-3.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115 , pp. 2-3
  • 107
    • 0039059930 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • For an exhaustive account of corporatist collective bargaining negotiations in the Ruhr coal sector, see Rudolf Tschirbs, Tarifpolitik im Ruhrbergbau 1918-1933 (Berlin, 1986). For a parallel account in the automobile industry, see Bernard Bellon, Mercedes in Peace and War: German Automobile Workers, 1903-1945 (New York, 1990).
    • (1986) Tarifpolitik Im Ruhrbergbau 1918-1933
    • Tschirbs, R.1
  • 108
    • 0040243855 scopus 로고
    • New York
    • For an exhaustive account of corporatist collective bargaining negotiations in the Ruhr coal sector, see Rudolf Tschirbs, Tarifpolitik im Ruhrbergbau 1918-1933 (Berlin, 1986). For a parallel account in the automobile industry, see Bernard Bellon, Mercedes in Peace and War: German Automobile Workers, 1903-1945 (New York, 1990).
    • (1990) Mercedes in Peace and War: German Automobile Workers, 1903-1945
    • Bellon, B.1
  • 109
    • 0039652128 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The logic for why Koenen assumed rationalization would not be possible under the Dawes plan is not clear from the sources, but undoubtedly had to do with the scarcity of available investment capital.
  • 110
    • 0040243891 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., 6428
    • Ibid., 6428.
  • 111
    • 0040243892 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "Es könnte den Anschein haben, wenn wir einen solchen Streichungsantrag stellen, als ob wir nicht für eine Hebung der Wirtschaftlichkeit der gewerblichen und industriellen Produktion eintreten wollten. Das ist aber bei weitem nicht unsere Absicht." Ibid.
  • 112
    • 0040838440 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The Institut für Konjunkturforschung is another neglected topic in Weimar business and economic history. For a statement of its purposes and the American model that in part inspired its founding, see the initial issue in 1926 of its major quarterly publication, Vierteljahreshefi für Konjunkturforschung.
  • 113
    • 0039059925 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wir glauben also, daß die rationalisierung, soweit sie sozial eine bedeutung hat, bei diesem institut (für konjunkturforschung) entsprechend bearbeitet wird
    • "Wir glauben also, daß die Rationalisierung, soweit sie sozial eine Bedeutung hat, bei diesem Institut (für Konjunkturforschung) entsprechend bearbeitet wird." Verhandlungen des Reichstags, 6428.
    • Verhandlungen des Reichstags , pp. 6428
  • 114
    • 0040243887 scopus 로고
    • Kötigen to von Raumer of 2 Feb. 1925
    • Köttgen took care to invite a large number of special guests to the 2 April meeting of the RKW in 1925 when the organization released its resolution for direct Reichstag funding and announced its reorganization. These included Reichstag members such as Prof. Schreiber of the Catholic Center Party, Rudolf Hilferding, and Rudolf Wisseil. See Kötigen to von Raumer of 2 Feb. 1925, SAA 11/LF 115. A copy of the 2 April resolution, "An den Reichstag, den Reichsrat und die Reichsregierung," may be found in SAA 4/LF 668. For Carl Friedrich von Siemens' address to the meeting, see the draft of the "Ansprache von Dr. Ing. e h. Carl Friedrich von Siemens in der Sitzung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit am 2 April 1925" in SAA 4/LF 668.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115.
  • 115
    • 0040838438 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An den reichstag, den reichsrat und die reichsregierung
    • Köttgen took care to invite a large number of special guests to the 2 April meeting of the RKW in 1925 when the organization released its resolution for direct Reichstag funding and announced its reorganization. These included Reichstag members such as Prof. Schreiber of the Catholic Center Party, Rudolf Hilferding, and Rudolf Wisseil. See Kötigen to von Raumer of 2 Feb. 1925, SAA 11/LF 115. A copy of the 2 April resolution, "An den Reichstag, den Reichsrat und die Reichsregierung," may be found in SAA 4/LF 668. For Carl Friedrich von Siemens' address to the meeting, see the draft of the "Ansprache von Dr. Ing. e h. Carl Friedrich von Siemens in der Sitzung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit am 2 April 1925" in SAA 4/LF 668.
    • SAA 4/LF 668.
  • 116
    • 0040838437 scopus 로고
    • Ansprache von dr. Ing. e h. Carl Friedrich von Siemens in der sitzung des reichskuratoriums für wirtschaftlichkeit am 2 April 1925
    • Köttgen took care to invite a large number of special guests to the 2 April meeting of the RKW in 1925 when the organization released its resolution for direct Reichstag funding and announced its reorganization. These included Reichstag members such as Prof. Schreiber of the Catholic Center Party, Rudolf Hilferding, and Rudolf Wisseil. See Kötigen to von Raumer of 2 Feb. 1925, SAA 11/LF 115. A copy of the 2 April resolution, "An den Reichstag, den Reichsrat und die Reichsregierung," may be found in SAA 4/LF 668. For Carl Friedrich von Siemens' address to the meeting, see the draft of the "Ansprache von Dr. Ing. e h. Carl Friedrich von Siemens in der Sitzung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit am 2 April 1925" in SAA 4/LF 668.
    • (1925) SAA 4/LF 668.
  • 117
    • 0040243880 scopus 로고
    • Von Raumer to Köttgen of 20 April 1925
    • For the importance of maintaining this appearance for getting the appropriations bill through the Reichstag Budget Committee in 1925, see von Raumer to Köttgen of 20 April 1925, in SAA 11/LF 115. See also the 2 April Resolution cited in the above note.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115.
  • 118
    • 0039652122 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • For a list of the RKW's twenty-five affiliated organizations in 1926, see the RKW's Jahresbericht 1926 (Berlin, 1926), 1-22. A summary of the most important of these is provided in Handbuch der Rationalisierung, ed. Fritz Reuter (3. ed. Berlin, 1932), 3-48.
    • (1926) Jahresbericht 1926 , pp. 1-22
  • 119
    • 0040243881 scopus 로고
    • ed. Fritz Reuter 3. ed. Berlin
    • For a list of the RKW's twenty-five affiliated organizations in 1926, see the RKW's Jahresbericht 1926 (Berlin, 1926), 1-22. A summary of the most important of these is provided in Handbuch der Rationalisierung, ed. Fritz Reuter (3. ed. Berlin, 1932), 3-48.
    • (1932) Handbuch der Rationalisierung , pp. 3-48
  • 120
    • 0039652124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Gruppe hauswirtschaft beim reichskuratorium für wirtschaftlichekeit
    • 3. ed., Berlin
    • See the description of the "Gruppe Hauswirtschaft beim Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichekeit," in Handbuch der Rationalisierung (3. ed., Berlin, 1932), 5-6; also Mary Nolan, "Housework made Easy: the Taylorized Housewife in Weimar Germany's Rationalized Economy," Feminist Studies 16 (1990): 549-578; and Visions of Modernity, chap. 10, "Housework Made Easy," 206-226.
    • Handbuch der Rationalisierung , pp. 5-6
  • 121
    • 0001109984 scopus 로고
    • Housework made easy: The taylorized housewife in Weimar Germany's rationalized economy
    • See the description of the "Gruppe Hauswirtschaft beim Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichekeit," in Handbuch der Rationalisierung (3. ed., Berlin, 1932), 5-6; also Mary Nolan, "Housework made Easy: the Taylorized Housewife in Weimar Germany's Rationalized Economy," Feminist Studies 16 (1990): 549-578; and Visions of Modernity, chap. 10, "Housework Made Easy," 206-226.
    • (1990) Feminist Studies , vol.16 , pp. 549-578
    • Nolan, M.1
  • 122
    • 33746014194 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Housework made easy
    • chap. 10
    • See the description of the "Gruppe Hauswirtschaft beim Reichskuratorium für Wirtschaftlichekeit," in Handbuch der Rationalisierung (3. ed., Berlin, 1932), 5-6; also Mary Nolan, "Housework made Easy: the Taylorized Housewife in Weimar Germany's Rationalized Economy," Feminist Studies 16 (1990): 549-578; and Visions of Modernity, chap. 10, "Housework Made Easy," 206-226.
    • Visions of Modernity , pp. 206-226
  • 123
    • 0039059890 scopus 로고
    • On the international rationalization movement, see the work of the International Management Institute, especially its Bulletin, published beginning in 1922. See also Paul Devinat, Scientific Management in Europe, International Labor Office, Studies and Reports, Series B (Economic Conditions), No. 17, (Geneva, 1927): 223-225, 257-260. The RKW is discussed in several places by Devinat, see especially, 225-227.
    • (1922) Bulletin
  • 124
    • 0003669285 scopus 로고
    • International Labor Office, Studies and Reports, Series B (Economic Conditions), No. 17, Geneva
    • On the international rationalization movement, see the work of the International Management Institute, especially its Bulletin, published beginning in 1922. See also Paul Devinat, Scientific Management in Europe, International Labor Office, Studies and Reports, Series B (Economic Conditions), No. 17, (Geneva, 1927): 223-225, 257-260. The RKW is discussed in several places by Devinat, see especially, 225-227.
    • (1927) Scientific Management in Europe , pp. 223-225
    • Devinat, P.1
  • 125
    • 0039059936 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On the international rationalization movement, see the work of the International Management Institute, especially its Bulletin, published beginning in 1922. See also Paul Devinat, Scientific Management in Europe, International Labor Office, Studies and Reports, Series B (Economic Conditions), No. 17, (Geneva, 1927): 223-225, 257-260. The RKW is discussed in several places by Devinat, see especially, 225-227.
    • Devinat1
  • 126
    • 0039652123 scopus 로고
    • Letter of 26 Oct. 1925
    • Some evidence exists of just this kind of conflict over professional turf between the VDI and the RKW in 1925. Exactly what was at issue is not clear from the documents in the Siemens Archive in Munich. In a letter to Direktor Lippart of the MAN in Nuremberg, Köttgen spoke of "ernsthafte Auseinandersetzungen" with the VDI, especially with its Direktor, Waldemar Hellmich. These problems had stretched out "schon über eine längere Zeit" and concerned "die Art, wie das Reichskuratorium arbeiten soll..." See Köttgen's letter of 26 Oct. 1925, in SAA 11/LF 115. The problem concerned in part a squabble over professional territory. The VDI felt the RKW encroached upon the work of the VDI's affiliated Deutscher Verband für Materialprüfungen, a technical organization dealing with specifications for industrial materials. See Köttgen's attempt to reassure VDI Direktor Hellmich that this was not the case, in Köttgen's letter of 2 April 1925, SAA 11/LF 118. The VDI affair also led to the dismissal of Adolf Schilling as Direktor of the RKW's affiliated Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Verwaltung. See the complaint of the Vertrauensleute der Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Verwaltung of 2 December 1925, that the organization was not being informed concerning the RKW's plans for reorganization, in SAA 11/LF 426. The Gesellschaft demanded clarification of the rumor that the RKW was to be absorbed by the VDI. Köttgen informed Schilling that he was relieved of his responsibilities as Direktor of the Gesellschaft in a letter of 9 December 1925, SAA 11/LF 426.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 115.
  • 127
    • 0039059927 scopus 로고
    • Köttgen letter of 2 April 1925
    • Some evidence exists of just this kind of conflict over professional turf between the VDI and the RKW in 1925. Exactly what was at issue is not clear from the documents in the Siemens Archive in Munich. In a letter to Direktor Lippart of the MAN in Nuremberg, Köttgen spoke of "ernsthafte Auseinandersetzungen" with the VDI, especially with its Direktor, Waldemar Hellmich. These problems had stretched out "schon über eine längere Zeit" and concerned "die Art, wie das Reichskuratorium arbeiten soll..." See Köttgen's letter of 26 Oct. 1925, in SAA 11/LF 115. The problem concerned in part a squabble over professional territory. The VDI felt the RKW encroached upon the work of the VDI's affiliated Deutscher Verband für Materialprüfungen, a technical organization dealing with specifications for industrial materials. See Köttgen's attempt to reassure VDI Direktor Hellmich that this was not the case, in Köttgen's letter of 2 April 1925, SAA 11/LF 118. The VDI affair also led to the dismissal of Adolf Schilling as Direktor of the RKW's affiliated Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Verwaltung. See the complaint of the Vertrauensleute der Gesellschaft für wirtschaftliche Verwaltung of 2 December 1925, that the organization was not being informed concerning the RKW's plans for reorganization, in SAA 11/LF 426. The Gesellschaft demanded clarification of the rumor that the RKW was to be absorbed by the VDI. Köttgen informed Schilling that he was relieved of his responsibilities as Direktor of the Gesellschaft in a letter of 9 December 1925, SAA 11/LF 426.
    • (1925) SAA 11/LF 118.
  • 128
    • 0039059935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • See, for example, letters and applications in SAA 11/LF 115. Figures as prominent as Prof. Eugen Schmalenbach did not hesitate to turn to the RKW. Schmalenbach sought funds to study industrial accounting methods in 1926. See his letter to Carl Friedrich von Siemens of 29 April 1926. Personal connections were also not above use. Hans Blank of a firm in Witten-on-the-Ruhr wrote his old personal friend (Dutzfreund), Köttgen, requesting funding for a relatively obscure organization of technical industrialists. Köttgen's reply was cordial, but pleaded that the RKW did not ordinarily fund purely industrial groups. See his letter to Blank of 18 Feb. 1927 in the same file.
  • 129
    • 0040838436 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • For allocations in this 26 month period, see the table in the RKW's Annual Report (Jahresbericht) of 1927 (Berlin, 1928), 31. The yearly report for 1927 reported allocation decisions up to 31 March, 1928. See also the numerous monthly RKW Finanzberichte with monthly allocation figures for the years 1926-1929, in SAA 11/LF 115.
    • (1928) RKW's Annual Report (Jahresbericht) of 1927 , pp. 31
  • 130
    • 0040243885 scopus 로고
    • Finanzberichte
    • For allocations in this 26 month period, see the table in the RKW's Annual Report (Jahresbericht) of 1927 (Berlin, 1928), 31. The yearly report for 1927 reported allocation decisions up to 31 March, 1928. See also the numerous monthly RKW Finanzberichte with monthly allocation figures for the years 1926-1929, in SAA 11/LF 115.
    • (1926) SAA 11/LF 115.
  • 131
    • 84917447517 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • The handbook appeared in its first edition in 1930, with two successive editions. The definitive third edition appeared in 1932 and exceeded 1,200 pages. See Fritz Reuter ed. Handbuch der Rationalisierung (Berlin, 1932).
    • (1932) Handbuch der Rationalisierung
    • Reuter, F.1
  • 132
    • 0039059897 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Technik und Wirtschaft was one of Germany's most important journals of industrial economy. It was founded in 1908 by the Association of German Engineers (Verein Deutscher Ingenieure, VDI), the most prominent such organization. The VDI created the journal in the conviction that Germany's highly scientifically-trained technical and engineering professions needed greater awareness of the commercial and economic dimensions of industrial enterprise. On this point, see Homburg, "Die Anfänge des Taylorsystems," 173-174. Up to 1924, the editor had been Friedrich Meyer. Its acquisition by the RKW in 1924 must be seen as an important maneuver.
    • Die Anfänge des Taylorsystems , pp. 173-174
    • Homburg1
  • 133
    • 0040243882 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • For a list of publications in the series up to 1936, see RKW, Verzeichnis der RKW-Veröffentlichungen abgeschlossen im Januar 1936 (Berlin, 1936). The series numbered 97 titles at this point, plus the publications of several dependent organizations.
    • (1936) Verzeichnis der Rkw-veröffentlichungen Abgeschlossen im Januar 1936
  • 134
    • 84917447517 scopus 로고
    • ed. Fritz Reuter 3. ed., Berlin, The first edition came out in
    • See Handbuch der Rationalisierung, ed. Fritz Reuter (3. ed., Berlin, 1932). The first edition came out in 1930.
    • (1930) Handbuch der Rationalisierung
  • 135
    • 0040838412 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The single sheet Resolution "An den Reichstag, den Reichsrat und die Reichsregienmg," 2 April 1925, declared that, "Mehrerzeugung ist heute das Notwendigste, wirtschaftliche Gesundung ist das Dringendste für uns." SAA 4/LF 668.
  • 137
    • 0040838410 scopus 로고
    • "Ansprache" of 2 April 1925
    • C. F. von Siemens, "Eröffnungsansprache" to RKW meeting of 17 Dec. 1925, 3-5; and "Ansprache" of 2 April 1925, 5-6. SAA 4/LF 668.
    • (1925) SAA 4/LF 668. , pp. 5-6
  • 139
    • 0039652087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Ansprache" of 2 April 1925
    • "Ansprache" of 2 April 1925, 1-2, SAA 4/LF 668.
    • SAA 4/LF 668. , pp. 1-2
  • 140
    • 0040838441 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid. 3-5, and "Eröffnungsansprache" to the meeting of 17 Dec. 1925, 5.
    • SAA 4/LF 668. , pp. 3-5
  • 144
    • 0040243845 scopus 로고
    • See the year by year summary of the RKW's history in the 50th anniversary review of the organization in 1971 in Die Rationalisierung, 22 (1971-75): 141-168.
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22 , pp. 141-168
  • 145
  • 146
    • 0039652083 scopus 로고
    • Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75): 144-146; "Wirtschaftlichkeit und Leistungssteigerung. Tagung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit," RKW-Nachrichten 12 (Juni 1938): 45-60. The Congress heard addresses from four keynote speakers. They were Dr. E. Koehler of the Reich Economics Ministry; G. Bauer, Director of the RKW; Gauleiter Wächtler of the Bavarian Ostmark; and Karl Lange from the Wirtschaftsgruppe Maschinenbau (Economic Group for Machine Building).
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22 , pp. 144-146
  • 147
    • 0040838407 scopus 로고
    • Wirtschaftlichkeit und leistungssteigerung. Tagung des reichskuratoriums für wirtschaftlichkeit
    • Juni
    • Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75): 144-146; "Wirtschaftlichkeit und Leistungssteigerung. Tagung des Reichskuratoriums für Wirtschaftlichkeit," RKW-Nachrichten 12 (Juni 1938): 45-60. The Congress heard addresses from four keynote speakers. They were Dr. E. Koehler of the Reich Economics Ministry; G. Bauer, Director of the RKW; Gauleiter Wächtler of the Bavarian Ostmark; and Karl Lange from the Wirtschaftsgruppe Maschinenbau (Economic Group for Machine Building).
    • (1938) RKW-Nachrichten , vol.12 , pp. 45-60
  • 148
    • 0040243851 scopus 로고
    • Seebauer's letter to Siemens of 11 April 1938
    • For the invitation to Siemens to attend the RKW Congress, see Seebauer's letter to Siemens of 11 April 1938, SAA 4/LF 668. For his acceptance, see the 50 Year RKW Retrospective in Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75): 145-146.
    • (1938) SAA 4/LF 668
  • 149
    • 0039059888 scopus 로고
    • 50 year RKW Retrospective
    • For the invitation to Siemens to attend the RKW Congress, see Seebauer's letter to Siemens of 11 April 1938, SAA 4/LF 668. For his acceptance, see the 50 Year RKW Retrospective in Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75): 145-146.
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22 , pp. 145-146
  • 152
    • 0040243848 scopus 로고
    • In its review of the RKW's activities during the 1940s, the editors of the 50 year anniversary journal credited Georg Seebaur, the RKWs Nazi era director, for keeping the professional publications of the organization "free from political influences." Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75): 146. The journal offers no further insight into this brief assertion.
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22 , pp. 146
  • 153
    • 0039652082 scopus 로고
    • 50 Jahre RKW
    • Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75), "50 Jahre RKW," p. 125, portrays photographs of the Chair of the RKW's Board of Directors from its founding by Siemens in 1921 to the current Chair in 1971. Conspicuous is the gap between Köttgen's photograph and his retirement in 1934 and the next occupant of the position, Dr. Adolf Lohse, whose term began in 1950.
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22 , pp. 125
  • 155
    • 0040243852 scopus 로고
    • 50 Jahre RKW
    • Die Rationalisierung 22 (1971-75), "50 Jahre RKW."
    • (1971) Die Rationalisierung , vol.22
  • 157
    • 84869935375 scopus 로고
    • Technik und rationalisierung in deutschland zur zeit der weimarer republik
    • Ulrich Troitsch and Gabriele Wohlauf Frankfurt
    • On the extent of the implementation of assembly line and other Fordist measures during the interwar era, see Jürgen Bönig, "Technik und Rationalisierung in Deutschland zur Zeit der Weimarer Republik," in Technik-Geschichte, ed. Ulrich Troitsch and Gabriele Wohlauf (Frankfurt, 1980), 390-419, who argues that whatever level of assembly line production may have been introduced in the 1920s, it did not constitute a significant transformation of capitalist modes of production. See also Heidrun Homburg, Rationalisierung und Industriearbeit. Arbeirtsmarkt, Management, Arbeiterschaft im Siemens-Konzern 1900-1939 (Berlin, 1991), who argues that the measures of Fordism and more efficient production did not take hold in the Berlin machine building industry until the 1930s after the effects of the Depression began to fade. On the importance of the widespread discussion concerning rationalization measures rather than their actual implementation in the 1920s, see J. Ronald Shearer, "Talking about Efficiency: Politics and the Industrial Rationalization Movement in the Weimar Republic," Central European History 28 (1995): 483-506.
    • (1980) Technik-geschichte , pp. 390-419
    • Bönig, J.1
  • 158
    • 0040243846 scopus 로고
    • Berlin
    • On the extent of the implementation of assembly line and other Fordist measures during the interwar era, see Jürgen Bönig, "Technik und Rationalisierung in Deutschland zur Zeit der Weimarer Republik," in Technik-Geschichte, ed. Ulrich Troitsch and Gabriele Wohlauf (Frankfurt, 1980), 390-419, who argues that whatever level of assembly line production may have been introduced in the 1920s, it did not constitute a significant transformation of capitalist modes of production. See also Heidrun Homburg, Rationalisierung und Industriearbeit. Arbeirtsmarkt, Management, Arbeiterschaft im Siemens-Konzern 1900-1939 (Berlin, 1991), who argues that the measures of Fordism and more efficient production did not take hold in the Berlin machine building industry until the 1930s after the effects of the Depression began to fade. On the importance of the widespread discussion concerning rationalization measures rather than their actual implementation in the 1920s, see J. Ronald Shearer, "Talking about Efficiency: Politics and the Industrial Rationalization Movement in the Weimar Republic," Central European History 28 (1995): 483-506.
    • (1991) Rationalisierung und Industriearbeit. Arbeirtsmarkt, Management, Arbeiterschaft Im Siemens-konzern 1900-1939
    • Homburg, H.1
  • 159
    • 84972481218 scopus 로고
    • Talking about efficiency: Politics and the industrial rationalization movement in the Weimar Republic
    • On the extent of the implementation of assembly line and other Fordist measures during the interwar era, see Jürgen Bönig, "Technik und Rationalisierung in Deutschland zur Zeit der Weimarer Republik," in Technik-Geschichte, ed. Ulrich Troitsch and Gabriele Wohlauf (Frankfurt, 1980), 390-419, who argues that whatever level of assembly line production may have been introduced in the 1920s, it did not constitute a significant transformation of capitalist modes of production. See also Heidrun Homburg, Rationalisierung und Industriearbeit. Arbeirtsmarkt, Management, Arbeiterschaft im Siemens-Konzern 1900-1939 (Berlin, 1991), who argues that the measures of Fordism and more efficient production did not take hold in the Berlin machine building industry until the 1930s after the effects of the Depression began to fade. On the importance of the widespread discussion concerning rationalization measures rather than their actual implementation in the 1920s, see J. Ronald Shearer, "Talking about Efficiency: Politics and the Industrial Rationalization Movement in the Weimar Republic," Central European History 28 (1995): 483-506.
    • (1995) Central European History , vol.28 , pp. 483-506
    • Shearer, J.R.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.