메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 76, Issue 1-2, 1996, Pages 201-213

The criminal-civil distinction and the utility of desert

(1)  Robinson, Paul H a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0030526079     PISSN: 00068047     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (43)

References (60)
  • 3
    • 0042432979 scopus 로고
    • Siegfried Wyler & Barbara Wyler eds., rev. ed., Remak Verlag Zürich
    • Compare IVY WILLIAMS, SWISS CIVIL CODE: ENGLISH VERSION (Siegfried Wyler & Barbara Wyler eds., rev. ed., Remak Verlag Zürich 1987) (1925) with The Swiss Federal Criminal Code of December 21, 1937, 30 J. AM. INST. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 1 (Walter Friedlander & W. Abraham Goldberg trans., Supp. 1939-1940).
    • (1987) Swiss Civil Code: English Version
    • Williams, I.1
  • 4
    • 0041430500 scopus 로고
    • The Swiss federal criminal code of December 21, 1937
    • Walter Friedlander & W. Abraham Goldberg trans., Supp. 1939-1940
    • Compare IVY WILLIAMS, SWISS CIVIL CODE: ENGLISH VERSION (Siegfried Wyler & Barbara Wyler eds., rev. ed., Remak Verlag Zürich 1987) (1925) with The Swiss Federal Criminal Code of December 21, 1937, 30 J. AM. INST. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 1 (Walter Friedlander & W. Abraham Goldberg trans., Supp. 1939-1940).
    • (1925) J. Am. Inst. Crim. L. & Criminology , vol.30
  • 5
    • 0041931955 scopus 로고
    • Helen C. Metz ed., 5th ed.
    • See FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, SAUDI ARABIA: A COUNTRY STUDY 201-03, 278-86 (Helen C. Metz ed., 5th ed. 1993).
    • (1993) Saudi Arabia: A Country Study , pp. 201-203
  • 9
    • 0041430497 scopus 로고
    • Diversion from criminal to administrative justice: Soviet law, practice, and conflicts of policy
    • F.J.M. Feldbrugge & William B. Simons eds.
    • See Peter H. Juviler, Diversion From Criminal to Administrative Justice: Soviet Law, Practice, and Conflicts of Policy, in PERSPECTIVES ON SOVIET LAW FOR THE 1980s, at 153, 155-62 (F.J.M. Feldbrugge & William B. Simons eds., 1982).
    • (1982) Perspectives on Soviet Law for the 1980s , pp. 153
    • Juviler, P.H.1
  • 17
    • 77955254791 scopus 로고
    • An economic theory of the criminal law
    • See, e.g., Richard A. Posner, An Economic Theory of the Criminal Law, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1193, 1195 (1985) ("Much of this market bypassing cannot be deterred by tort law - that is, by privately enforced damage suits. The optimal damages hat would be required for deterrence would so frequently exceed the offender's ability to pay that public enforcement and nonmonetary sanctions such as imprisonment are required.").
    • (1985) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1193
    • Posner, R.A.1
  • 18
    • 85050831674 scopus 로고
    • Foreword: The criminal-civil distinction and dangerous blameless offenders
    • The authority to incarcerate persons is not limited to the criminal law. Under the civil law, the state has the authority to commit persons civilly who are mentally ill or who have contagious diseases. E.g., Paul H. Robinson, Foreword: The Criminal-Civil Distinction and Dangerous Blameless Offenders, 83 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 693, 700 n.23 (1993) (listing state civil commitment statutes); id. at 712 n.57 (listing state statutes for the detention of persons with communicable diseases). At the same time, a significant percentage of criminal offenders are not imprisoned, but rather merely receive sanctions, such as fines or probation restrictions, that could have been imposed by civil law as damages, fines, or restraining orders. See BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, SOURCEBOOK OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE STATISTICS - 1992, at 516-17, tbl. 5.37 (1993) (Defendants Sentenced in U.S. District Courts) (showing that for the year ending June 30, 1991, 37.7% of sentenced federal defendants were not incarcerated; 29.5% received probation, 8.1% were only fined, and 0.1% received punishment classified as "other"); id. at 529, tbl. 5.52 (Felony Sentences Imposed by State Courts) (showing that in 1990, 29% of felons sentenced in state court received punishments other than incarceration). The one sanction civil law cannot impose is the death penalty, but the criminal system has always included many more offenses for which the death penalty was not available than those for which it was.
    • (1993) J. Crim. L. & Criminology , vol.83 , Issue.23 , pp. 693
    • Robinson, P.H.1
  • 19
    • 0003684227 scopus 로고
    • tbl. 5.37
    • The authority to incarcerate persons is not limited to the criminal law. Under the civil law, the state has the authority to commit persons civilly who are mentally ill or who have contagious diseases. E.g., Paul H. Robinson, Foreword: The Criminal-Civil Distinction and Dangerous Blameless Offenders, 83 J. CRIM. L. & CRIMINOLOGY 693, 700 n.23 (1993) (listing state civil commitment statutes); id. at 712 n.57 (listing state statutes for the detention of persons with communicable diseases). At the same time, a significant percentage of criminal offenders are not imprisoned, but rather merely receive sanctions, such as fines or probation restrictions, that could have been imposed by civil law as damages, fines, or restraining orders. See BUREAU OF JUSTICE STATISTICS, U.S. DEP'T OF JUSTICE, SOURCEBOOK OF CRIMINAL JUSTICE STATISTICS - 1992, at 516-17, tbl. 5.37 (1993) (Defendants Sentenced in U.S. District Courts) (showing that for the year ending June 30, 1991, 37.7% of sentenced federal defendants were not incarcerated; 29.5% received probation, 8.1% were only fined, and 0.1% received punishment classified as "other"); id. at 529, tbl. 5.52 (Felony Sentences Imposed by State Courts) (showing that in 1990, 29% of felons sentenced in state court received punishments other than incarceration). The one sanction civil law cannot impose is the death penalty, but the criminal system has always included many more offenses for which the death penalty was not available than those for which it was.
    • (1993) Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics - 1992 , pp. 516-517
  • 20
    • 21144467159 scopus 로고
    • Getting beyond the civil-criminal distinction: A new approach to the regulation of indirect contempts
    • See, e.g., Earl C. Dudley, Jr., Getting Beyond the Civil-Criminal Distinction: A New Approach to the Regulation of Indirect Contempts, 79 VA. L. REV. 1025, 1065 (1993) (noting the constitutional requirement for greater procedural safeguards in criminal proceedings and suggesting that the stigmatizing effect unique to criminal sanctions necessitates these greater safeguards).
    • (1993) Va. L. Rev. , vol.79 , pp. 1025
    • Dudley E.C., Jr.1
  • 21
    • 0041430486 scopus 로고
    • (Albania), (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore)
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • (1993) The 1993 Report on Human Rights Around the World , vol.49 , pp. 93-97
  • 22
    • 0042933718 scopus 로고
    • Burma
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • (1993) Asia Watch & The Women's Rights Project, A Modern Form of Slavery: Trafficking of Burmese Women and Girls into Brothels in Thailand , pp. 28
  • 23
    • 0042933739 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 11 (Singapore)
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • Chan1
  • 24
    • 0003445115 scopus 로고
    • Cuba
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • (1994) Revolution in the Balance: Law and Society in Contemporary Cuba , pp. 150-153
    • Evenson, D.1
  • 25
    • 0041430511 scopus 로고
    • Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. North Korea
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • (1994) North Korea: A Country Study , pp. 179-180
  • 26
    • 0042933719 scopus 로고
    • supra note 1 (China); Albania
    • For example, Albania, China, Cuba, North Korea, Burma, and Singapore have all been criticized for failure to follow international standards for fair criminal procedure and for arbitrary and abusive police practices. E.g., AMNESTY INT'L, THE 1993 REPORT ON HUMAN RIGHTS AROUND THE WORLD 49 (Albania), 93-97 (China), 108-11 (Cuba), 180-81 (North Korea), 215-18 (Burma), 257-58 (Singapore) (1993). Yet each country maintains a separate and distinct criminal law. See, e.g., ASIA WATCH & THE WOMEN'S RIGHTS PROJECT, A MODERN FORM OF SLAVERY: TRAFFICKING OF BURMESE WOMEN AND GIRLS INTO BROTHELS IN THAILAND 28 (1993) (Burma); CHAN, supra note 11 (Singapore); DEBRA EVENSON, REVOLUTION IN THE BALANCE: LAW AND SOCIETY IN CONTEMPORARY CUBA 150-53 (1994) (Cuba); FEDERAL RESEARCH DIVISION, LIBRARY OF CONGRESS, NORTH KOREA: A COUNTRY STUDY 179-80, 267-75 (Andrea M. Savada, ed., 4th ed. 1994) (North Korea); MEIJER, supra note 1 (China); MINNESOTA LAWYERS INT'L HUMAN RIGHTS COMMITTEE, HUMAN RIGHTS IN THE PEOPLE'S SOCIALIST REPUBLIC OF ALBANIA 41-48 (1990) (Albania).
    • (1990) Human Rights in the People's Socialist Republic of Albania , pp. 41-48
    • Meijer1
  • 27
    • 0009918541 scopus 로고
    • Does "unlawful" mean "criminal"?: Reflections on the disappearing tort/crime distinction in American law
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Does "Unlawful" Mean "Criminal"?: Reflections on the Disappearing Tort/Crime Distinction in American Law, 71 B.U. L. REV. 193, 194 (1991) ("Characteristically, tort law prices, while criminal law prohibits."); Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1548-50 (1984) (suggesting that the explanation for the criminal-civil distinction is that the information requirements for pricing crime are prohibitive in relation to the information requirements for sanctioning crimes).
    • (1991) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.71 , pp. 193
    • Coffee J.C., Jr.1
  • 28
    • 84935322680 scopus 로고
    • Prices and sanctions
    • See John C. Coffee, Jr., Does "Unlawful" Mean "Criminal"?: Reflections on the Disappearing Tort/Crime Distinction in American Law, 71 B.U. L. REV. 193, 194 (1991) ("Characteristically, tort law prices, while criminal law prohibits."); Robert Cooter, Prices and Sanctions, 84 COLUM. L. REV. 1523, 1548-50 (1984) (suggesting that the explanation for the criminal-civil distinction is that the information requirements for pricing crime are prohibitive in relation to the information requirements for sanctioning crimes).
    • (1984) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.84 , pp. 1523
    • Cooter, R.1
  • 29
    • 0042432973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Coffee admirably acknowledges this weakness in his theory, stating that his claim "is not that tort law only prices and criminal law only prohibits, but that each has a dominant tendency that explains much of its institutional and doctrinal structure." Coffee, supra note 19, at 194 n.4. It is hard to see why this conceded weakness does not undo his theory, however. Coffee might argue that making crimes torts is useful because tort liability can add to the deterrent threat of criminal punishment. If that were the case, one would expect all crimes to be torts, which they are not. The prohibition-pricing distinction also does not explain the host of other differences between the two systems, as discussed below. See infra text accompanying notes 21-23.
  • 30
    • 0040965307 scopus 로고
    • § 18 5th ed.
    • In tort, consent ordinarily bars recovery. E.g., W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § 18 (5th ed. 1984) ("Consent ordinarily bars recovery for intentional interferences with person or property."). On the other hand, consent is rarely a defense in criminal law. See, e.g., MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.11(1) (1985) (stating the general rule that consent is a defense if it negates an element of an offense or precludes the infliction of harm that a law sought to prevent).
    • (1984) Prosser and Keeton on the Law of Torts
    • Page Keeton, W.1
  • 31
    • 0004665517 scopus 로고
    • § 2.11(1)
    • In tort, consent ordinarily bars recovery. E.g., W. PAGE KEETON ET AL., PROSSER AND KEETON ON THE LAW OF TORTS § 18 (5th ed. 1984) ("Consent ordinarily bars recovery for intentional interferences with person or property."). On the other hand, consent is rarely a defense in criminal law. See, e.g., MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.11(1) (1985) (stating the general rule that consent is a defense if it negates an element of an offense or precludes the infliction of harm that a law sought to prevent).
    • (1985) Model Penal Code
  • 32
    • 0004665517 scopus 로고
    • § 2.12(2)
    • Criminal law recognizes a defense if the harm or evil was "too trivial to warrant the condemnation of conviction." See MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.12(2) (1985) (setting forth the rule regarding de minimis infractions). Conversely, tort law imposes liability independent of the amount of harm caused; a minor harm from a violation will simply result in minor damages. See KEETON ET AL., supra note 21, § 85, at 608 (discussing the fault principle, under which intended harms and unintended harms involving undue risk are compensable, no matter how small the damages).
    • (1985) Model Penal Code
  • 33
    • 0042432999 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 21, § 85
    • Criminal law recognizes a defense if the harm or evil was "too trivial to warrant the condemnation of conviction." See MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.12(2) (1985) (setting forth the rule regarding de minimis infractions). Conversely, tort law imposes liability independent of the amount of harm caused; a minor harm from a violation will simply result in minor damages. See KEETON ET AL., supra note 21, § 85, at 608 (discussing the fault principle, under which intended harms and unintended harms involving undue risk are compensable, no matter how small the damages).
    • Keeton1
  • 34
    • 0042432978 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 21, § 82
    • Generally, tortfeasors are permitted to pay damages through insurance while convicted criminals are not. See, e.g., KEETON ET AL., supra note 21, § 82, at 586 (describing the interaction of liability insurance and the criminal law); SAMUEL WILLISTON, 7 A TREATISE ON THE LAW OF CONTRACTS § 901, at 60 (Walter H.E. Jaeger ed., 3d ed. 1963) ("Almost all attempted [criminal liability] insurance has been declared illegal as opposed to public policy.").
    • Keeton1
  • 35
    • 0041430508 scopus 로고
    • § 901, Walter H.E. Jaeger ed., 3d ed.
    • Generally, tortfeasors are permitted to pay damages through insurance while convicted criminals are not. See, e.g., KEETON ET AL., supra note 21, § 82, at 586 (describing the interaction of liability insurance and the criminal law); SAMUEL WILLISTON, 7 A TREATISE ON THE LAW OF CONTRACTS § 901, at 60 (Walter H.E. Jaeger ed., 3d ed. 1963) ("Almost all attempted [criminal liability] insurance has been declared illegal as opposed to public policy.").
    • (1963) A Treatise on the Law of Contracts , vol.7 , pp. 60
    • Williston, S.1
  • 36
    • 0042933720 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 15
    • See, e.g., Posner, supra note 15, at 1195 (explaining that criminal law doctrines promote economic efficiency, just as tort law does); Steven Shavell, Criminal Law and the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions as a Deterrent, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1232, 1235 (1985) ("Whether . . . a party will . . . commit an act . . . depends on his perception of the possibility that he will suffer a sanction . . . . A party will commit an act [only] if . . . the expected sanction [is] less than the expected private benefits. If he decides not to commit an act, he [has been] deterred.").
    • Posner1
  • 37
    • 84867666491 scopus 로고
    • Criminal law and the optimal use of nonmonetary sanctions as a deterrent
    • See, e.g., Posner, supra note 15, at 1195 (explaining that criminal law doctrines promote economic efficiency, just as tort law does); Steven Shavell, Criminal Law and the Optimal Use of Nonmonetary Sanctions as a Deterrent, 85 COLUM. L. REV. 1232, 1235 (1985) ("Whether . . . a party will . . . commit an act . . . depends on his perception of the possibility that he will suffer a sanction . . . . A party will commit an act [only] if . . . the expected sanction [is] less than the expected private benefits. If he decides not to commit an act, he [has been] deterred.").
    • (1985) Colum. L. Rev. , vol.85 , pp. 1232
    • Shavell, S.1
  • 38
    • 0041009938 scopus 로고
    • Restitution: A new paradigm of criminal justice
    • Randy E. Barnett & John Hagel III eds.
    • Some writers do not dispute that the current criminal-civil distinction reflects the special place of criminal law as having a focus on blameworthiness and a punishment function, but argue for the virtues of shifting to the use of a different distinction. See, e.g., Randy E. Barnett, Restitution: A New Paradigm of Criminal Justice, in ASSESSING THE CRIMINAL: RESTITUTION, RETRIBUTION, AND THE LEGAL PROCESS 349 (Randy E. Barnett & John Hagel III eds., 1977) (acknowledging the punishment focus of criminal law, but arguing for a "new paradigm" of criminal law organized around a restitution principle).
    • (1977) Assessing the Criminal: Restitution, Retribution, and the Legal Process , vol.349
    • Barnett, R.E.1
  • 40
    • 0041931948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 693 (emphasis added)
    • Id. at 693 (emphasis added).
  • 41
    • 0004665517 scopus 로고
    • § 2.12(2)
    • MODEL PENAL CODE § 2.12(2) (1985). Note that even the highly utilitarian drafters of the Code believe that "condemnation" is implicit in "conviction."
    • (1985) Model Penal Code
  • 43
    • 35248858781 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An insider's perspective on the significance of the german criminal theory's general system for analyzing criminal acts
    • This is the role of the Tatbestand in the German criminal system. For a general discussion of the German analytic scheme and the role of the Tatbestand within it, see Wolfgang Naucke, An Insider's Perspective on the Significance of the German criminal Theory's General System for Analyzing Criminal Acts, 1984 B.Y.U. L. REV. 305; see also GEORGE P. FLETCHER, RETHINKING CRIMINAL LAW § 7.6.1 (1978) (stating that prohibitory norms shape the contours of the definition of criminal offenses).
    • B.Y.U. L. Rev. , vol.1984 , pp. 305
  • 44
    • 0004273012 scopus 로고
    • § 7.6.1
    • This is the role of the Tatbestand in the German criminal system. For a general discussion of the German analytic scheme and the role of the Tatbestand within it, see Wolfgang Naucke, An Insider's Perspective on the Significance of the German criminal Theory's General System for Analyzing Criminal Acts, 1984 B.Y.U. L. REV. 305; see also GEORGE P. FLETCHER, RETHINKING CRIMINAL LAW § 7.6.1 (1978) (stating that prohibitory norms shape the contours of the definition of criminal offenses).
    • (1978) Rethinking Criminal Law
    • Fletcher, G.P.1
  • 45
    • 0004665517 scopus 로고
    • § 213.1(1) Rape
    • Consent will vitiate the violation of a societal norm only if that norm is expressly defined in terms of lack of consent. This is the case for several offenses against the person, such as rape - only intercourse without consent is rape - and for some offenses against property - only taking without consent is theft. See MODEL PENAL CODE § 213.1(1) (1985) (Rape); id. art. 23 (Theft and Related Offenses). But it is rarely the case for other kinds of criminal offenses - consensual gambling and consensual bribery - and not the case for even many or most criminal offenses committed against the person or property - consensual homicide, arson, and incest. See ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 720, para. 5/28-1 (Smith-Hurd 1993) (Gambling); MODEL PENAL CODE § 240.1 (1985) (Bribery in Official and Political Matters); id. § 210.1 (Criminal Homicide); id. § 220.1(1) (Arson); id. § 230.2 (Incest).
    • (1985) Model Penal Code
  • 46
    • 0041430499 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • ch. 720, para. 5/28-1 (Smith-Hurd 1993) (Gambling)
    • Consent will vitiate the violation of a societal norm only if that norm is expressly defined in terms of lack of consent. This is the case for several offenses against the person, such as rape - only intercourse without consent is rape - and for some offenses against property - only taking without consent is theft. See MODEL PENAL CODE § 213.1(1) (1985) (Rape); id. art. 23 (Theft and Related Offenses). But it is rarely the case for other kinds of criminal offenses - consensual gambling and consensual bribery - and not the case for even many or most criminal offenses committed against the person or property - consensual homicide, arson, and incest. See ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 720, para. 5/28-1 (Smith-Hurd 1993) (Gambling); MODEL PENAL CODE § 240.1 (1985) (Bribery in Official and Political Matters); id. § 210.1 (Criminal Homicide); id. § 220.1(1) (Arson); id. § 230.2 (Incest).
    • Ill. Ann. Stat.
  • 47
    • 0004665517 scopus 로고
    • § 240.1
    • Consent will vitiate the violation of a societal norm only if that norm is expressly defined in terms of lack of consent. This is the case for several offenses against the person, such as rape - only intercourse without consent is rape - and for some offenses against property - only taking without consent is theft. See MODEL PENAL CODE § 213.1(1) (1985) (Rape); id. art. 23 (Theft and Related Offenses). But it is rarely the case for other kinds of criminal offenses - consensual gambling and consensual bribery - and not the case for even many or most criminal offenses committed against the person or property - consensual homicide, arson, and incest. See ILL. ANN. STAT. ch. 720, para. 5/28-1 (Smith-Hurd 1993) (Gambling); MODEL PENAL CODE § 240.1 (1985) (Bribery in Official and Political Matters); id. § 210.1 (Criminal Homicide); id. § 220.1(1) (Arson); id. § 230.2 (Incest).
    • (1985) Model Penal Code
  • 48
    • 0004221326 scopus 로고
    • The most readable full account of this and the reasons for it is found in JAMES Q. WILSON, THE MORAL SENSE (1993).
    • (1993) The Moral Sense
    • Wilson, J.Q.1
  • 49
    • 0041931941 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Competing theories of justification: Deeds vs. Reasons
    • A.T.H. Smith & A. Simester eds.
    • I refer here only to the objective form of justification. The subjective form, what I would call mistaken justification, sends no such message. It is, in part, the important difference between these two messages that leads me to argue for an objective formulation of justification defenses, with a separate excuse defense for mistaken justification. Paul H. Robinson, Competing Theories of Justification: Deeds vs. Reasons, in CURRENT PROBLEMS OF CRIMINAL THEORY (A.T.H. Smith & A. Simester eds., 1996).
    • (1996) Current Problems of Criminal Theory
    • Robinson, P.H.1
  • 50
    • 0041430498 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 16
    • See Robinson, supra note 16, at 709 (noting the indeterminate length of civil commitment due to the system of periodic review of a detainee's dangerousness).
    • Robinson1
  • 51
    • 84927458113 scopus 로고
    • Soldiers, martyrs, and criminals: Utilitarian theory and the problem of crime control
    • This is not true of all utilitarians, of course. For a brief discussion of the role of intuitionism in utilitarian theory, see Louis M. Seidman, Soldiers, Martyrs, and Criminals: Utilitarian Theory and the Problem of Crime Control, 94 YALE L.J. 315, 322 n.14 (1984).
    • (1984) Yale L.J. , vol.94 , Issue.14 , pp. 315
    • Seidman, L.M.1
  • 52
    • 49049152301 scopus 로고
    • Economists free ride, does anyone else?
    • I don't want to take too far the claim that economists are just like other people. I note for example that in an experiment designed to test whether students would contribute to a public good, such as a community stereo for a dormitory, the one group of students most likely to free-ride was graduate students in economics. See Gerald Marwell & Ruth E. Ames, Economists Free Ride, Does Anyone Else?, 15 J. PUB. ECON. 295, 306-07 (1981).
    • (1981) J. Pub. Econ. , vol.15 , pp. 295
    • Marwell, G.1    Ames, R.E.2
  • 53
    • 0030529813 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The crime/ tort distinction: A generation later
    • I thought it interesting that at the Symposium at which this paper was presented, Richard Epstein railed at length against overregulation of our lives by both criminal and civil law, treating the two systems as essentially analogous sources of liability. Yet he reserved his greatest feeling of outrage for officials who, because his walkway violated a beachfront construction rule, "were treating me like a criminal!" For details of Professor Epstein's discussion of such regulations, see Richard Epstein, The Crime/ Tort Distinction: A Generation Later, 76 B.U. L. REV. 1, 5-7 (1996).
    • (1996) B.U. L. Rev. , vol.76 , pp. 1
    • Epstein, R.1
  • 54
    • 0042432976 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Punitive damages at civil law may well have been created for a different reason than to mimic criminal liability, and might properly be maintained for this different reason, even in a system that returned to a sharp criminal-civil distinction. Specifically one might speculate that in cases of intentional wrongdoing, which is where punitive damages typically are imposed, the harm of the violation to the victim is actually greater than when the tortfeasor negligently caused the harm. Note, for example, that the sting of discrimination often lies in its intentionality. The victim of the discrimination suffers more when the motive is clear than where the actions might be accidental. The introduction of punitive damages in cases of intentional torts may well have been out of recognition of this greater harm.
  • 55
    • 0042432977 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • supra note 19
    • Coffee, supra note 19, at 215-21 (discussing these "public welfare offenses").
    • Coffee1
  • 56
    • 0041931940 scopus 로고
    • The commission's new option that favors judicial discretion in corporate sentencing
    • Id. at 216 citing n.10
    • Id. at 216 (citing Thomas B. Leary, The Commission's New Option That Favors Judicial Discretion in Corporate Sentencing, 3 FED. SENTENCING REP. 142, 144 n.10 (1990)). Coffee fails to include in his list of criminal-civil muddlings, however, one of his own special interests: the modern invention and increasing use of criminal liability for legal fictions, such as corporations. Corporate liability makes perfect sense when the issue is allocation of a loss suffered by one of the parties. But legal fictions can neither feel nor deserve moral condemnation; only people can.
    • (1990) Fed. Sentencing Rep. , vol.3 , pp. 142
    • Leary, T.B.1
  • 58
    • 0042933722 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For a fuller account of this argument and the social science data in support of it, see id.
  • 59
    • 0042432982 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.
  • 60
    • 0042933721 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See id.
    • See id.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.