메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 48, Issue 3, 1996, Pages 358-390

Rationality in international relations: A game-theoretic and empirical study of the U.S.-China case

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

GAME THEORY; GEOPOLITICAL RELATIONS; HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE; INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS; MODELLING APPROACH; POLITICAL STRATEGY; RATIONAL BEHAVIOUR; SINO-AMERICAN RELATIONS;

EID: 0029750141     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/wp.1996.0012     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (74)
  • 1
    • 0000320684 scopus 로고
    • A Survey of Game Models of Peace and War
    • Robert Aumann and Sergiu Hart, eds., New York: Springer-Verlag
    • An extensive survey of that literature is given by Barry O'Neill, "A Survey of Game Models of Peace and War," in Robert Aumann and Sergiu Hart, eds., Handbook of Game Theory, vol. 2 (New York: Springer-Verlag, 1992).
    • (1992) Handbook of Game Theory , vol.2
    • O'Neill, B.1
  • 2
    • 33747856809 scopus 로고
    • Re-examination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games
    • Strategies are in subgame-perfect equilibrium (SGPE) if each is best against the other(s) in any contingency. The concept of SGPE comes from Reinhart Selten, "Re-examination of the Perfectness Concept for Equilibrium Points in Extensive Games," International Journal of Game Theory 4 (1975).
    • (1975) International Journal of Game Theory , pp. 4
    • Selten, R.1
  • 3
    • 84971922880 scopus 로고
    • Realism, Game Theory, and Cooperation
    • April
    • Robert Jervis, "Realism, Game Theory, and Cooperation," World Politics 40 (April 1988).
    • (1988) World Politics , pp. 40
    • Jervis, R.1
  • 4
    • 0003636206 scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • Loosely speaking, this means that players share the same expectation of future interaction, thus determining the path of future play. See James D. Morrow, Game Theory for Political Science (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994).
    • (1994) Game Theory for Political Science
    • Morrow, J.D.1
  • 5
    • 85033028986 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • If each side punishes its opponent for not meeting its expectation, those expectations must be identical or they will remain hopelessly out of equilibrium. This requires a coordination of expectations.
  • 6
    • 85033026187 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our characterization of SGPEs in Appendix 2 also suggests how to test whether countervailing strategies have been adopted, by searching in the data for traces of coordination. Such tests, performed on data for U.S.-China relations for the period 1972 to 1988 and reported in Appendix 4, support the hypothesis that a pure countervailing strategy rather than any other type of strategy was adopted by the two countries during the period under consideration.
  • 7
    • 85033029488 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In 2×2 games, if C denotes cooperate, D defect, and XY the choices X by row and Y by column, a Prisoner's Dilemma structure for row means his preferences satisfy DC > CC > DD > CD. There are several Deadlock-type games. The relevant one here satisfies DD > CD > DC > CC.
  • 8
    • 85033031537 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • We refer here to the noncooperative models that assume individualistic actors
    • We refer here to the noncooperative models that assume individualistic actors.
  • 12
    • 0000028492 scopus 로고
    • The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information
    • The folk theorem asserts that any "individually rational" outcome (i.e., no worse than the minimax) can be supported by a trigger strategy equilibrium in a repeated game. See Drew Fudenberg and Eric Maskin, "The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information," Econometrica 54 (1986).
    • (1986) Econometrica , pp. 54
    • Fudenberg, D.1    Maskin, E.2
  • 13
    • 85033030380 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For example, it is not enough to recognize that one's opponent has chosen to play a trigger strategy (which involves collaborating as long as the other players do and reverting to noncooperative play for a fixed number of turns to punish the opponent for deviating from cooperative play). Each player must understand which particular trigger strategy has been chosen (how many punishment turns and which precise outcome is considered as the cooperative point) and chose to adopt the same one, since, if not, the strategies do not form an equilibrium.
  • 15
    • 85033012896 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jervis(fn. 3)
    • Jervis(fn. 3).
  • 16
    • 85033013313 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • While countervailing is inherently reciprocative, the additional punishment of unexpected play could lead to retaliations for cooperative initiatives!. This paradox is inherent to all trigger strategy schemes in continuous games.
  • 17
    • 0003391154 scopus 로고
    • Arms Races and Cooperation
    • Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • See, among others, George W. Downs, David M. Rocke and Randolph M. Siverson, "Arms Races and Cooperation," in Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986); and Kenneth A. Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," in Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy.
    • (1986) Cooperation under Anarchy
    • Downs, G.W.1    Rocke, D.M.2    Siverson, R.M.3
  • 18
    • 0041073391 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies
    • Oye, ed.
    • See, among others, George W. Downs, David M. Rocke and Randolph M. Siverson, "Arms Races and Cooperation," in Kenneth A. Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986); and Kenneth A. Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," in Oye, ed., Cooperation under Anarchy.
    • Cooperation under Anarchy
    • Oye, K.A.1
  • 20
    • 85033020662 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Axelrod(fn. 11)
    • Axelrod(fn. 11).
  • 21
    • 84965736413 scopus 로고
    • Evaluating Alternative Foreign Policy Decision-Making Models: An Empirical Test between Arms Race Models and an Organizational Politics Model
    • See Charles W. Ostrom, "Evaluating Alternative Foreign Policy Decision-Making Models: An Empirical Test between Arms Race Models and an Organizational Politics Model," Journal of Conflict Resolution 21 (1977); Steven J. Majeski and David Jones, "Arms Race Modeling: Causality Analysis and Model Specification," Journal of Conflict Resolution 25 (1981); and Kendall D. Moll and Gregory Luebbert, "Arms Race and Military Expenditure Models: A Review," Journal of Conflict Resolution 24 (1980).
    • (1977) Journal of Conflict Resolution , pp. 21
    • Ostrom, C.W.1
  • 22
    • 84965673546 scopus 로고
    • Arms Race Modeling: Causality Analysis and Model Specification
    • See Charles W. Ostrom, "Evaluating Alternative Foreign Policy Decision-Making Models: An Empirical Test between Arms Race Models and an Organizational Politics Model," Journal of Conflict Resolution 21 (1977); Steven J. Majeski and David Jones, "Arms Race Modeling: Causality Analysis and Model Specification," Journal of Conflict Resolution 25 (1981); and Kendall D. Moll and Gregory Luebbert, "Arms Race and Military Expenditure Models: A Review," Journal of Conflict Resolution 24 (1980).
    • (1981) Journal of Conflict Resolution , pp. 25
    • Majeski, S.J.1    Jones, D.2
  • 23
    • 84970104239 scopus 로고
    • Arms Race and Military Expenditure Models: A Review
    • See Charles W. Ostrom, "Evaluating Alternative Foreign Policy Decision-Making Models: An Empirical Test between Arms Race Models and an Organizational Politics Model," Journal of Conflict Resolution 21 (1977); Steven J. Majeski and David Jones, "Arms Race Modeling: Causality Analysis and Model Specification," Journal of Conflict Resolution 25 (1981); and Kendall D. Moll and Gregory Luebbert, "Arms Race and Military Expenditure Models: A Review," Journal of Conflict Resolution 24 (1980).
    • (1980) Journal of Conflict Resolution , pp. 24
    • Moll, K.D.1    Luebbert, G.2
  • 24
    • 84934095796 scopus 로고
    • Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?
    • See William J. Dixon, "Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?" American Journal of Political Science 30 (1986); and Michael D. Ward, "Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior," International Studies Quarterly 26 (1982). See also Dina Zinnes, "Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher," International Studies Quarterly 24 (1980); Bruce Russett, The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1983); and Walter Isard and Charles Anderton, "Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis," Conflict Management and Peace Science 8, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1986) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 30
    • Dixon, W.J.1
  • 25
    • 0002945096 scopus 로고
    • Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior
    • See William J. Dixon, "Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?" American Journal of Political Science 30 (1986); and Michael D. Ward, "Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior," International Studies Quarterly 26 (1982). See also Dina Zinnes, "Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher," International Studies Quarterly 24 (1980); Bruce Russett, The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1983); and Walter Isard and Charles Anderton, "Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis," Conflict Management and Peace Science 8, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1982) International Studies Quarterly , pp. 26
    • Ward, M.D.1
  • 26
    • 84925925049 scopus 로고
    • Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher
    • See William J. Dixon, "Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?" American Journal of Political Science 30 (1986); and Michael D. Ward, "Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior," International Studies Quarterly 26 (1982). See also Dina Zinnes, "Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher," International Studies Quarterly 24 (1980); Bruce Russett, The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1983); and Walter Isard and Charles Anderton, "Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis," Conflict Management and Peace Science 8, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1980) International Studies Quarterly , pp. 24
    • Zinnes, D.1
  • 27
    • 0007035979 scopus 로고
    • San Francisco: W. H. Freeman
    • See William J. Dixon, "Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?" American Journal of Political Science 30 (1986); and Michael D. Ward, "Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior," International Studies Quarterly 26 (1982). See also Dina Zinnes, "Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher," International Studies Quarterly 24 (1980); Bruce Russett, The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1983); and Walter Isard and Charles Anderton, "Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis," Conflict Management and Peace Science 8, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1983) The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control
    • Russett, B.1
  • 28
    • 84965886774 scopus 로고
    • Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis
    • See William J. Dixon, "Reciprocity in United States-Soviet Relations: Multiple Symmetry or Issue Linkage?" American Journal of Political Science 30 (1986); and Michael D. Ward, "Cooperation and Conflict in Foreign Policy Behavior," International Studies Quarterly 26 (1982). See also Dina Zinnes, "Three Puzzles in Search of a Researcher," International Studies Quarterly 24 (1980); Bruce Russett, The Prisoner's Insecurity: Nuclear Deterrence, the Arms Race and Arms Control (San Francisco: W. H. Freeman, 1983); and Walter Isard and Charles Anderton, "Arms Race Models: A Survey and Synthesis," Conflict Management and Peace Science 8, no. 2 (1985).
    • (1985) Conflict Management and Peace Science , vol.8 , Issue.2
    • Isard, W.1    Anderton, C.2
  • 29
    • 85033008963 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Zinnes (fn. 21)
    • Zinnes (fn. 21).
  • 31
    • 84971738623 scopus 로고
    • U.S.-Soviet-Chinese Relations: Routine Reciprocity, or Rational Expectations?
    • March
    • See Joshua S. Goldstein and John Freeman, "U.S.-Soviet-Chinese Relations: Routine Reciprocity, or Rational Expectations?" American Political Science Review 85 (March 1991); and idem, Three-Way Street: Strategic Reciprocity in World Politics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990).
    • (1991) American Political Science Review , vol.85
    • Goldstein, J.1    Freeman, J.2
  • 32
    • 84971738623 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press
    • See Joshua S. Goldstein and John Freeman, "U.S.-Soviet-Chinese Relations: Routine Reciprocity, or Rational Expectations?" American Political Science Review 85 (March 1991); and idem, Three-Way Street: Strategic Reciprocity in World Politics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990).
    • (1990) Three-Way Street: Strategic Reciprocity in World Politics
    • Goldstein, J.1    Freeman, J.2
  • 33
    • 84928838012 scopus 로고
    • Sophisticated Reaction in the U.S.-Soviet Arms Race: Evidence of Rational Expectations
    • November
    • See John Williams and Michael McGinnis, "Sophisticated Reaction in the U.S.-Soviet Arms Race: Evidence of Rational Expectations," American Journal of Political Science 32 (November 1988).
    • (1988) American Journal of Political Science , pp. 32
    • Williams, J.1    McGinnis, M.2
  • 35
    • 0029518797 scopus 로고
    • Great Power Cooperation under Conditions of Limited Reciprocity: From Empirical to Formal Analysis
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24,1990 and 1991); December
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24,1990 and 1991); and Joshua S. Goldstein, "Great Power Cooperation under Conditions of Limited Reciprocity: From Empirical to Formal Analysis," International Studies Quarterly 39 (December 1995).
    • (1995) International Studies Quarterly , pp. 39
    • Goldstein, J.S.1
  • 39
    • 1542661731 scopus 로고
    • China's Foreign Relations: The Reintegration of China into the World Economy
    • Bill Brugger, ed., London: Crown Helm
    • See Greg O'Leary, "China's Foreign Relations: The Reintegration of China into the World Economy," in Bill Brugger, ed., China since the Gang of Four (London: Crown Helm, 1980).
    • (1980) China since the Gang of Four
    • O'Leary, G.1
  • 40
    • 85033011074 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Well-known mixed-motive 2×2 games include the Prisoner's Dilemma, Chicken, and the Stag Hunt
    • Well-known mixed-motive 2×2 games include the Prisoner's Dilemma, Chicken, and the Stag Hunt.
  • 43
    • 85033013688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Miller (fn. 33)
    • Miller (fn. 33).
  • 44
    • 84974185472 scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Games and the Problem of International Cooperation
    • Harrison Wagner, "The Theory of Games and the Problem of International Cooperation," American Political Science Review 77 (1983), argues that games such as Harmony and Deadlock should be considered before any mixed-motive game. And in a game such as Deadlock, the very meaning of the term cooperate becomes questionable: if both sides prefer the defect-defect outcome, is this not mutual accommodation?
    • (1983) American Political Science Review , pp. 77
    • Wagner, H.1
  • 45
    • 85033033766 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990 and 1991)
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990 and 1991).
  • 46
    • 85033017087 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ch = 1/2- UC/12, CU being the coded WEIS series representing Chinese behavior.
  • 47
    • 0004251138 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
    • Countervailing does not require a Prisoner's Dilemma structure in order to succeed. Indeed, our empirical estimates for the pre-open-door period (1972-78) point to a different game that, although listed in exhaustive studies, has received little attention; see Steven J. Brams, Theory of Moves (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994). That game has a Nash equilibrium in which both sides defect, leaving one side (China) with its best outcome and the other (U.S.) with its next to worst. But countervailing succeeds in promoting a relatively cooperative outcome while providing an SGPE in that game.
    • (1994) Theory of Moves
    • Brams, S.J.1
  • 48
    • 85033034148 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • When trying to define an initial date, the question is how far back one should consider past events and political regimes to be relevant to the day-to-day management of a relationship. By focusing on stationary strategies, we avoid this problem, although it is possible to reconstruct strategies that account for a starting date (see fn. 41).
  • 49
    • 85033026124 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 0 will be optimal against the U.S. countervailing strategy we describe below.
  • 50
    • 85033004583 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t's by a tough U.S. stand, the discounted values in (4) decrease as a result.
  • 51
    • 85033009822 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Recall that this means that play prescribed by such strategies maximizes discounted payoff regardless of the prior developments of the game.
  • 52
    • 85032998318 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • us, > 0. But it is possible to relax this restriction and to consider Deadlock-type games.
  • 53
    • 85033014818 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t-1 as in (3a). Of course, the two approaches are equivalent.
  • 54
    • 85033010535 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Again we emphasize that payoff structures other than the Prisoner's Dilemma can be successfully dealt with using our countervailing approach. In other game structures the fear and temptation concepts do not necessarily apply and other relationships emerge.
  • 55
    • 85033002165 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • All other remarks made about the robustness of the countervailing strategy (3a) extend to (14b). In particular, no U.S. strategy could promote a better steady state for the U.S.
  • 56
    • 85033029102 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • us could also be written as a sum. The particular form chosen is for notational convenience when writing out China's move at time (t + 1) as a function of the past history of play.
  • 57
    • 85033028487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • ch. Such cross terms allow for estimation of a wider variety of payoff functions. However, the inferred coefficient on the cross term for the payoff functions were not found to be significantly different from zero.
  • 58
    • 85033006147 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The denominator 6 in the k-term accounts for the range. The use of monthly data leads to aggregation of events and a widening of the range of the data. This would magnify the denominator 6 and would not affect the rest of our analysis. Of course, we still need to assume some bounded interval to guarantee the boundedness of payoffs required by the theorem in Appendix 2.
  • 59
    • 85033013232 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • An autoregression following (18) will identify the parameters of a countervailing strategy. As the main theorem in Appendix 2 demonstrates, strategies that form SGPEs are either countervailing or coordinated. If the players do not adopt a countervailing strategy but instead coordinate play, then the data should reveal punishing responses by each player. As mentioned above, we provide, in Appendix 3, a test of the hypothesis that China and the U.S. could be coordinating their moves rather than implementing countervailing strategies. The data do not support the hypothesis of coordination.
  • 60
    • 85033021164 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In that case, countervailing would not succeed in providing an SGPE. A finding of negative b-coefficients for both sides would therefore refute the countervailing hypothesis.
  • 61
    • 0040840272 scopus 로고
    • Landam: University Press of America, Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990)
    • Jack E. Vincent, Project Theory (Landam: University Press of America, 1979); Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990).
    • (1979) Project Theory
    • Vincent, J.E.1
  • 62
    • 84965404504 scopus 로고
    • A Conflict-Cooperation Scale for WEIS Events Data
    • Joshua S. Goldstein, "A Conflict-Cooperation Scale for WEIS Events Data," Journal of 'Conflict Resolution 36, no. 2 (1992).
    • (1992) Journal of 'Conflict Resolution , vol.36 , Issue.2
    • Goldstein, J.S.1
  • 63
    • 85033033740 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Such a restriction does not imply that the effects of an aggressive move will necessarily evaporate after six months. First, if the defector persists in an aggressive position, countervailing will continue and even deepen with time. And if the defector moves back to cooperation, the countervailing responses will only slowly reestablish cooperation.
  • 66
    • 85033025241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It turns out that when the equations estimated for the period 1972 to 1978 are used to explain subsequent years, a break in the data is apparent about 1979 and is confirmed by a formal Chow test.
  • 67
    • 85032997974 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Even under the standard assumption of normal distribution for the coefficients estimated in (20), the resulting distribution of the b-coefficients is not normal since their derivation involves nonlinear transformations.
  • 68
    • 85033002920 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brams (fn. 39)
    • Brams (fn. 39).
  • 69
    • 85033023151 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990 and 1991)
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 24, 1990 and 1991).
  • 70
    • 85033011209 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 21, 1991); and Goldstein (fn. 27, 1994)
    • Goldstein and Freeman (fn. 21, 1991); and Goldstein (fn. 27, 1994).
  • 71
    • 85033010341 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 2).
  • 72
    • 85033031422 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • i functions.
  • 73
    • 85033032790 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t+1, we may use either one in the equality of the second line of (31).
  • 74
    • 85033031928 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • us≥0.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.