메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 81, Issue 1, 1995, Pages 149-160

The Mind and Heart of Progressive Legal Thought

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0029464696     PISSN: 00210552     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: None     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (45)
  • 3
    • 0002071502 scopus 로고
    • The Problem of Social Cost
    • Ronald R. Coase, The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J.L. & Econ. 1 (1960).
    • (1960) J.L. & Econ. , vol.3 , pp. 1
    • Coase, R.R.1
  • 5
    • 0003736594 scopus 로고
    • See Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation 210, 215, 219-20, 234-35 (1984) (describing the influence of Progressive economists and jurists on regulatory policy); Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 1667 (1975) (same). For a much more optimistic work on reforming administrative law, see James M. Landis, The Administrative Process (1938).
    • (1984) Prophets of Regulation , pp. 210
    • McCraw, T.K.1
  • 6
    • 0000942437 scopus 로고
    • The Reformation of American Administrative Law
    • See Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation 210, 215, 219-20, 234-35 (1984) (describing the influence of Progressive economists and jurists on regulatory policy); Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 1667 (1975) (same). For a much more optimistic work on reforming administrative law, see James M. Landis, The Administrative Process (1938).
    • (1975) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.88 , pp. 1667
    • Stewart, R.B.1
  • 7
    • 0003833360 scopus 로고
    • See Thomas K. McCraw, Prophets of Regulation 210, 215, 219-20, 234-35 (1984) (describing the influence of Progressive economists and jurists on regulatory policy); Richard B. Stewart, The Reformation of American Administrative Law, 88 Harv. L. Rev. 1667 (1975) (same). For a much more optimistic work on reforming administrative law, see James M. Landis, The Administrative Process (1938).
    • (1938) The Administrative Process
    • Landis, J.M.1
  • 11
    • 84935560114 scopus 로고
    • See generally, Mary O. Furner, Advocacy and Objectivity; A Crisis in the Professionalization of American Social Science, 1865-1905 (1975) (describing the influence of theory of evolution on social science theory); Dorothy Ross, The Origins of American Social Science (1991) (same).
    • (1991) The Origins of American Social Science
    • Ross, D.1
  • 12
    • 0041187326 scopus 로고
    • Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence
    • See Herbert Hovenkamp, Evolutionary Models in Jurisprudence, 64 Tex. L. Rev. 645 (1985) (describing the influence of theory of evolution on American legal and political thought).
    • (1985) Tex. L. Rev. , vol.64 , pp. 645
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 13
    • 0004220926 scopus 로고
    • J.H. Burns & H.L.A. Hart eds., 1970
    • Jeremy Bentham, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation (J.H. Burns & H.L.A. Hart eds., 1970) (1789); Jeremy Bentham, The Theory of Legislation (posthumous) (R. Hildreth trans., 1896) (London, Kegan, Paul, Trendi, Trubner & Co. 1896). Bentham did not come close to developing the theory of marginal cost or theories of value based on marginalism.
    • (1789) An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation
    • Bentham, J.1
  • 14
    • 0040994759 scopus 로고
    • (posthumous) (R. Hildreth trans., 1896) London, Kegan, Paul, Trendi, Trubner & Co.
    • Jeremy Bentham, An Introduction to the Principles of Morals and Legislation (J.H. Burns & H.L.A. Hart eds., 1970) (1789); Jeremy Bentham, The Theory of Legislation (posthumous) (R. Hildreth trans., 1896) (London, Kegan, Paul, Trendi, Trubner & Co. 1896). Bentham did not come close to developing the theory of marginal cost or theories of value based on marginalism.
    • (1896) The Theory of Legislation
    • Bentham, J.1
  • 15
    • 0004148224 scopus 로고
    • London, MacMillan
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1888) The Theory of Political Economy 3d Ed.
    • Jevons, W.S.1
  • 16
    • 0007131267 scopus 로고
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1975) The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall
    • Whitaker, J.K.1
  • 17
    • 0009949357 scopus 로고
    • Boston, Ginn & Co.
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1886) The Philosophy of Wealth , pp. 56-90
    • Clark, J.B.1
  • 18
    • 0004203360 scopus 로고
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1954) History of Economic Analysis , pp. 868
    • Schumpeter, J.A.1
  • 19
    • 0003746324 scopus 로고
    • James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1871) Principles of Economics
    • Menger, C.1
  • 20
    • 84923714852 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
  • 21
    • 84923714850 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
  • 22
    • 84935190124 scopus 로고
    • The First Great Law & Economics Movement
    • William Stanley Jevons, The Theory of Political Economy (3d ed. London, MacMillan 1888). Alfred Marshall also deserves part of the credit. See The Early Economic Writings of Alfred Marshall (J.K. Whitaker ed., 1975) (early marginalist essays). In the United States, John Bates Clark probably came to his marginalism independently. See John Bates Clark, The Philosophy of Wealth 56-90 (Boston, Ginn & Co. 1886); Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis 868 (1954) (discussing the independence of Clark's marginalism); see also Carl Menger, Principles of Economics (James Dingwall & Bert F. Hoselitz trans., 1981) (1871) (applying the marginal utility theory to value and price theory). Menger's work was less influential in the United States than Jevons's work, since Menger stood outside the British classical tradition. However, a large group of American graduate students in political economy who went abroad for graduate study in the late nineteenth century ended up on the Continent, especially in Germany, and many of them studied Menger. For a discussion of the influence of German historicism on Progressive Era economics, see Furner, supra note 8, at 50-58; Ross, supra note 8, at 104-06; Herbert Hovenkamp, The First Great Law & Economics Movement, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 993, 996-97 (1990).
    • (1990) Stan. L. Rev. , vol.42 , pp. 993
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 23
    • 84923714848 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jevons, supra note 2, at 1
    • Jevons, supra note 2, at 1.
  • 24
    • 84923714847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Id. at 59
    • "[W] hen the person remains satisfied with the distribution he has made, it follows that . . . an increment of commodity would yield exactly as much utility in one use as in another." Id. at 59.
  • 25
    • 0003736757 scopus 로고
    • London, MacMillan
    • The great marginalist economist Alfred Marshall knew that the whole notion of subjective preference meant nothing at all unless preference could be measured behaviorally. Thus, one could speak meaningfully of consumer demand only "as represented by the schedule of the prices at which he is willing to buy different amounts of [something]." Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics 158 (London, MacMillan 1890). In his highly influential eighth edition, Marshall wrote: If then we wish to compare . . . physical gratifications, we must do it not directly, but indirectly by the incentives which they afford to action. If the desires to secure either of two pleasures will induce people in similar circumstances each to do just an hour's extra work, or will induce men in the same rank of life and with the same means each to pay a shilling for it; we then may say that those pleasures are equal for our purposes, because the desires for them are equally strong incentives to action for persons under similar conditions. Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics 13 (8th ed. 1920).
    • (1890) Principles of Economics , pp. 158
    • Marshall, A.1
  • 26
    • 0003736757 scopus 로고
    • 8th ed.
    • The great marginalist economist Alfred Marshall knew that the whole notion of subjective preference meant nothing at all unless preference could be measured behaviorally. Thus, one could speak meaningfully of consumer demand only "as represented by the schedule of the prices at which he is willing to buy different amounts of [something]." Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics 158 (London, MacMillan 1890). In his highly influential eighth edition, Marshall wrote: If then we wish to compare . . . physical gratifications, we must do it not directly, but indirectly by the incentives which they afford to action. If the desires to secure either of two pleasures will induce people in similar circumstances each to do just an hour's extra work, or will induce men in the same rank of life and with the same means each to pay a shilling for it; we then may say that those pleasures are equal for our purposes, because the desires for them are equally strong incentives to action for persons under similar conditions. Alfred Marshall, Principles of Economics 13 (8th ed. 1920).
    • (1920) Principles of Economics , pp. 13
    • Marshall, A.1
  • 27
    • 34147109849 scopus 로고
    • Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice
    • Edwin R.A. Seligman, Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, 9 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 1, 132-33 (1894); Edwin R.A. Seligman, The Theory of Progressive Taxation, 8 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 52 (1893). See also Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1002-05 (discussing efforts to use interpersonal comparisons of utility to justify progressivity in income taxation).
    • (1894) Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 1 , vol.9 , pp. 132-133
    • Seligman, E.R.A.1
  • 28
    • 11244313414 scopus 로고
    • The Theory of Progressive Taxation
    • Edwin R.A. Seligman, Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, 9 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 1, 132-33 (1894); Edwin R.A. Seligman, The Theory of Progressive Taxation, 8 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 52 (1893). See also Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1002-05 (discussing efforts to use interpersonal comparisons of utility to justify progressivity in income taxation).
    • (1893) Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n , vol.8 , pp. 52
    • Seligman, E.R.A.1
  • 29
    • 84923714846 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See also Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1002-05
    • Edwin R.A. Seligman, Progressive Taxation in Theory and Practice, 9 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 1, 132-33 (1894); Edwin R.A. Seligman, The Theory of Progressive Taxation, 8 Publication Am. Econ. Ass'n 52 (1893). See also Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1002-05 (discussing efforts to use interpersonal comparisons of utility to justify progressivity in income taxation).
  • 31
    • 84923714845 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1033-47
    • See Lionel C. Robbins, An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science (2d ed. 1935) (Robbins's original argument against interpersonal utility comparisons); Hovenkamp, supra note 11, at 1033-47 (discussing Robbins).
  • 33
    • 21144473011 scopus 로고
    • The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought
    • Herbert Hovenkamp, The Marginalist Revolution in Legal Thought, 46 Vand. L. Rev. 305, 335-45 (1993).
    • (1993) Vand. L. Rev. , vol.46 , pp. 305
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 35
    • 84923714844 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, e.g., the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the antimerger statute, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1988)
    • See, e.g., the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the antimerger statute, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1988) (applying restraints on corporations in their acquisition of another corporation's stock); H.R. Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. 8 (1949) (discussing goals of merger policy as protecting smaller firms from larger, lower cost rivals). The new merger policy, designed to prevent small, high cost firms from being "gobbled up" by larger, more efficient firms was hailed as a triumph of law and economics. See Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 Harv. L. Rev. 226 (1960) (criticizing anti-big business bias in Eisenhower era antitrust policy); Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 J.L. Reform 515 (1988) (same).
  • 36
    • 84923714843 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • H.R. Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. 8 (1949)
    • See, e.g., the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the antimerger statute, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1988) (applying restraints on corporations in their acquisition of another corporation's stock); H.R. Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. 8 (1949) (discussing goals of merger policy as protecting smaller firms from larger, lower cost rivals). The new merger policy, designed to prevent small, high cost firms from being "gobbled up" by larger, more efficient firms was hailed as a triumph of law and economics. See Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 Harv. L. Rev. 226 (1960) (criticizing anti-big business bias in Eisenhower era antitrust policy); Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 J.L. Reform 515 (1988) (same).
  • 37
    • 0043150533 scopus 로고
    • Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics
    • See, e.g., the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the antimerger statute, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1988) (applying restraints on corporations in their acquisition of another corporation's stock); H.R. Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. 8 (1949) (discussing goals of merger policy as protecting smaller firms from larger, lower cost rivals). The new merger policy, designed to prevent small, high cost firms from being "gobbled up" by larger, more efficient firms was hailed as a triumph of law and economics. See Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 Harv. L. Rev. 226 (1960) (criticizing anti-big business bias in Eisenhower era antitrust policy); Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 J.L. Reform 515 (1988) (same).
    • (1960) Harv. L. Rev. , vol.74 , pp. 226
    • Bok, D.C.1
  • 38
    • 0347100903 scopus 로고
    • Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics
    • See, e.g., the 1950 Celler-Kefauver amendments to the antimerger statute, 15 U.S.C. § 18 (1988) (applying restraints on corporations in their acquisition of another corporation's stock); H.R. Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. 8 (1949) (discussing goals of merger policy as protecting smaller firms from larger, lower cost rivals). The new merger policy, designed to prevent small, high cost firms from being "gobbled up" by larger, more efficient firms was hailed as a triumph of law and economics. See Derek C. Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of Law and Economics, 74 Harv. L. Rev. 226 (1960) (criticizing anti-big business bias in Eisenhower era antitrust policy); Herbert Hovenkamp, Derek Bok and the Merger of Law and Economics, 21 J.L. Reform 515 (1988) (same).
    • (1988) J.L. Reform , vol.21 , pp. 515
    • Hovenkamp, H.1
  • 39
    • 84923714842 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Arrow, supra note 6
    • E.g., Arrow, supra note 6 (questioning the possibility of maximizing social welfare through the aggregation of individual choices); Buchanan & Tullock, supra note 7 (analyzing "methodological individualism" in the context of constitutional choices and decision-making rules).
  • 40
    • 84923714841 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Buchanan & Tullock, supra note 7
    • E.g., Arrow, supra note 6 (questioning the possibility of maximizing social welfare through the aggregation of individual choices); Buchanan & Tullock, supra note 7 (analyzing "methodological individualism" in the context of constitutional choices and decision-making rules).
  • 41
    • 84923714840 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • E.g., Coase, supra note 3
    • E.g., Coase, supra note 3 (discussing the role of private bargaining in unregulated markets during the 1960s).
  • 42
    • 84923714839 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 347 U.S. 483 (1954)
    • 347 U.S. 483 (1954).
  • 43
    • 0003395702 scopus 로고
    • See generally Gordon Tullock, Economics of Income Redistribution 111-50 (1983) (explaining how social security and medicare primarily benefit those individuals in the upper and middle classes); Gordon Tullock, The Economics of Special Privilege and Rent Seeking (1989) (arguing that governmental income transfers typically benefit the middle and upper classes as opposed to the poor).
    • (1983) Economics of Income Redistribution , pp. 111-150
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 44
    • 0003413932 scopus 로고
    • See generally Gordon Tullock, Economics of Income Redistribution 111-50 (1983) (explaining how social security and medicare primarily benefit those individuals in the upper and middle classes); Gordon Tullock, The Economics of Special Privilege and Rent Seeking (1989) (arguing that governmental income transfers typically benefit the middle and upper classes as opposed to the poor).
    • (1989) The Economics of Special Privilege and Rent Seeking
    • Tullock, G.1
  • 45
    • 84923714838 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Coase, supra note 3
    • Coase, supra note 3.


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.