메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 5, Issue 3-4, 1995, Pages 219-236

Market power in California electricity markets

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

ELECTRICITY INDUSTRY; ELECTRICITY MARKET; INDUSTRIAL RESTRUCTURING; MARKET POWER;

EID: 0029432144     PISSN: 09571787     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1016/0957-1787(96)00005-7     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (77)

References (35)
  • 1
    • 84919307693 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • There are, however, a number of foreign precedents from which we can draw experience, namely Norway, Latin America, and the UK.
  • 6
    • 84919307690 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In the future, large generation companies in the UK will be required to report their availability policies for the upcoming year. It is unclear at this time whether this will be an effective deterrent to the strategic games.
  • 7
    • 84919307689 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For instance, home security companies charge for the ‘on call’ service. In some cases, they also charge a ‘per visit’ fee when the contingent demand for their service arises.
  • 10
    • 84919307688 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • While the vertical integration and transmission constraints may create concerns that incumbent firms will be able to discourage new entry, it seems unlikely that large firms could engage in profitable predation to drive out firms that are already operating. Profitable predation requires that the predator increase output substantially to drive price below the prey's short-run average cost, but then reduce output once the prey is eliminated. Because short-run average cost is generally quite low once an electricity-generating facility is operating, this would require a significant depressing of price for a significant period of time. Furthermore, the predator would need to have sufficient capacity to expand output, capacity that it would not want to use (in this market) after the predatory behavior ends.
  • 13
    • 0001519094 scopus 로고
    • Supply function equilibria in oligopoly under uncertainty
    • (1989) Econometrica , vol.57 , Issue.6 , pp. 1243-1277
    • Klemperer1    Meyer2
  • 15
    • 0003088971 scopus 로고
    • Supply function equilibria and the danger of tacit collusion
    • (1992) Energy Economics , vol.12 , Issue.2 , pp. 94-102
    • Bolle1
  • 18
    • 84919307685 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Joskow, op cit, ref 2.
  • 19
    • 84919307684 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The example has identical linear demands in the two markets and zero marginal cost.
  • 21
    • 84919307682 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • It is important to note that for the first 5 years after restructuring, the three California IOUs are required to supply their energy only through the spot market, and are therefore not eligible suppliers of PPCs. The concentration of suppliers for this transition period may be drastically different, although spot electricity combined with financial instruments remains available as a substitute for PPCs.
  • 24
    • 84919307681 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Newbery, op cit, ref 5.
  • 25
    • 84919307680 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allez and Vila, op cit, ref 22.
  • 28
    • 84919307679 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Allez and Vila, op cit, ref 22.
  • 29
    • 84919307678 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Newbery, op cit, ref 5.
  • 31
    • 84919307677 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Another potentially contentious question is what penalties should be paid by suppliers who deviate from their bids. We do not address this question here.
  • 33
    • 0001686436 scopus 로고
    • Markets in real electric networks require reactive pricing
    • (1993) Energy Journal , vol.14 , Issue.3 , pp. 171-200
    • Hogan1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.