메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 26, Issue 2, 2001, Pages 166-188

Discourse and class struggle: The politics of industry in early modern England

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords

ARTICLE; DEVELOPING COUNTRY; ECONOMICS; EDUCATION; ETHNOLOGY; HEALTH; HISTORY; INDUSTRY; LEGAL ASPECT; POLICY; POLITICS; RURAL POPULATION; SOCIAL CHANGE; SOCIAL CLASS; UNITED KINGDOM; URBAN POPULATION;

EID: 0013240909     PISSN: 03071022     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1080/03071020110039733     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (10)

References (112)
  • 1
    • 0043193228 scopus 로고
    • Of commerce
    • Stephen Copley and Andrew Edgar (eds), Oxford
    • David Hume, 'Of commerce' in Stephen Copley and Andrew Edgar (eds), Selected Essays (Oxford, 1993), 119.
    • (1993) Selected Essays , pp. 119
    • Hume, D.1
  • 2
    • 0042692226 scopus 로고
    • ed. Andrew Skinner Harmondsworth
    • Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, ed. Andrew Skinner (Harmondsworth, 1974), 192.
    • (1974) The Wealth of Nations , pp. 192
    • Smith, A.1
  • 3
    • 0043193285 scopus 로고
    • History, historicism and the social logic of the text in the Middle Ages
    • Gabrielle Spiegel, 'History, historicism and the social logic of the text in the Middle Ages', Past and Present, CXXXI (1991), repr. in Keith Jenkins (ed.), The Postmodern History Reader (London and New York, 1997), 181.
    • (1991) Past and Present , vol.131
    • Spiegel, G.1
  • 4
    • 0004113887 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • repr. London and New York
    • Gabrielle Spiegel, 'History, historicism and the social logic of the text in the Middle Ages', Past and Present, CXXXI (1991), repr. in Keith Jenkins (ed.), The Postmodern History Reader (London and New York, 1997), 181.
    • (1997) The Postmodern History Reader , pp. 181
    • Jenkins, K.1
  • 5
    • 0002149625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The determinist fix: Some obstacles to the further development of the linguistic approach to history in the 1990s
    • Autumn
    • Gareth Stedman Jones, 'The determinist fix: some obstacles to the further development of the linguistic approach to history in the 1990s', History Workshop Journal, XLII (Autumn 1996); but cf. Neville Kirk's argument that '[Patrick] Joyces and Stedman Jones's views and practices at times lack clarity and consistency, and [above all, in my view] exhibit ambiguity' in crucial points: 'History, language, ideas and postmodernism', repr. in Keith Jenkins (ed.), op. cit., chap. 28, 330.
    • (1996) History Workshop Journal , vol.42
    • Jones, G.S.1
  • 6
    • 0002149625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • History, language, ideas and postmodernism
    • repr. chap. 28
    • Gareth Stedman Jones, 'The determinist fix: some obstacles to the further development of the linguistic approach to history in the 1990s', History Workshop Journal, XLII (Autumn 1996); but cf. Neville Kirk's argument that '[Patrick] Joyces and Stedman Jones's views and practices at times lack clarity and consistency, and [above all, in my view] exhibit ambiguity' in crucial points: 'History, language, ideas and postmodernism', repr. in Keith Jenkins (ed.), op. cit., chap. 28, 330.
    • History Workshop Journal , pp. 330
    • Jenkins, K.1
  • 9
    • 0040784504 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Linguistic approach or return to subjectivism? In search of an alternative to social history
    • January
    • Miguel A. Cabrera, 'Linguistic approach or return to subjectivism? In search of an alternative to social history'. Social History, XXIV, 1 (January 1999).
    • (1999) Social History , vol.24 , Issue.1
    • Cabrera, M.A.1
  • 11
    • 0022217708 scopus 로고
    • Industrialization and the proletarian family in England
    • May
    • David Levine, 'Industrialization and the proletarian family in England', Past and Present, CVII (May 1985), 169, argues that 'the first phase of capitalism' began around 'the middle of the sixteenth century'.
    • (1985) Past and Present , vol.107 , pp. 169
    • Levine, D.1
  • 12
    • 84974489132 scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization: The first phase of the industrialization process
    • Mendels, 'Proto-industrialization: the first phase of the industrialization process', Journal of Economic History, XXXII (1972), 241-61; the quote is from Mendels. 'Proto-industrialization: theory and reality', Eighth International Economic History Congress, Budapest 1982, 77.
    • (1972) Journal of Economic History , vol.32 , pp. 241-261
    • Mendels1
  • 13
    • 84974489132 scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization: Theory and reality
    • quote Budapest
    • Mendels, 'Proto-industrialization: the first phase of the industrialization process', Journal of Economic History, XXXII (1972), 241-61; the quote is from Mendels. 'Proto-industrialization: theory and reality', Eighth International Economic History Congress, Budapest 1982, 77.
    • (1982) Eighth International Economic History Congress , pp. 77
    • Mendels1
  • 14
    • 85015127929 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization revisited: Demography, social structure, and domestic industry
    • special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • Continuity and Change , vol.8 , Issue.2 , pp. 219
    • Kriedt, P.1    Medick, H.2    Schlumbohm, J.3
  • 15
    • 0017027880 scopus 로고
    • The demographic implications of rural industrialization
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1976) Social History , vol.2
    • Levine, D.1
  • 16
    • 85040870906 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1987) Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History
    • Levine1
  • 17
    • 0002297673 scopus 로고
    • Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851
    • Levine (ed.), Orlando
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1984) Proletarianization and Family History
    • Levine1
  • 18
    • 0004008279 scopus 로고
    • Chapters 4 and 5 London
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1992) The Industrial Revolution
    • Hudson, P.1
  • 19
    • 0003455606 scopus 로고
    • trans. Beate Schempe Cambridge
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1981) Industrialization Before Industrialization
    • Kriedte1    Medick2    Schlumbohm3
  • 20
    • 84980237518 scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization: A concept too many
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1983) Economic History Review , vol.36
    • Coleman, D.C.1
  • 21
    • 84928095201 scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1984) Historical Journal , vol.27 , pp. 473
    • Houston, R.1    Snell, K.D.M.2
  • 22
    • 85015115625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Proto-industrialization in Europe
    • Ogilvie
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • Historical Journal
    • Ogilvie, S.M.1
  • 23
    • 0004000130 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge
    • 'Franklin Mendels … made the relationship between rural industry and demographic change the cornerstone of the concept of proto-industrialization': Peter Kriedt, Hans Medick and Jurgen Schlumbohm, 'Proto-industrialization revisited: demography, social structure, and domestic industry' in Continuity and Change, VIII, 2, special number on proto-industrialization, ed. Sheilagh C. Ogilvie, 219; David Levine, 'The demographic implications of rural industrialization', Social History, II (1976); Levine, Reproducing Families: The Political Economy of English Population History (Cambridge, 1987); Levine, 'Production, reproduction, and the proletarian family in England, 1500-1851', in Levine (ed.), Proletarianization and Family History (Orlando, 1984). Chapters 4 and 5 of Pat Hudson, The Industrial Revolution (London, 1992), provide a judicious summary of the field; Hudson notes (142) that 'empirical work has exposed a large gap between theory and reality'; further critical perspectives are to be found in two early reviews of Kriedte, Medick and Schlumbohm, Industrialization Before Industrialization, trans. Beate Schempe (Cambridge, 1981): D. C. Coleman, 'Proto-industrialization: a concept too many', Economic History Review, XXXVI (1983), Rab Houston and K. D. M. Snell, 'Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change and industrial revolution'. Historical Journal, XXVII (1984), 473; cf. also Sheila M. Ogilvie, 'Proto-industrialization in Europe' in Ogilvie, op. cit.; and Michael Zell, Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century (Cambridge Studies in Population, Economy and Society in Past Time, Cambridge, 1994).
    • (1994) Industry in the Countryside: Wealden Society in the Sixteenth Century
    • Zell, M.1
  • 24
    • 0010887241 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "Proto-industrialization" as a research strategy and a historical period -A balance sheet
    • Sheilagh C. Ogilvie and Marcus Cerman (eds), Cambridge
    • Jurgen Schlumbohm, '"Proto-industrialization" as a research strategy and a historical period -a balance sheet' in Sheilagh C. Ogilvie and Marcus Cerman (eds), European Proto-industrialization (Cambridge, 1996), 12, writes that the concept 'aimed to introduce into economic and social history a new approach which would overcome the divorce between previously separate fields of research' and to bring 'together industrial and agrarian history, adding to them historical demography and the history of the family, and also including the history of everyday culture and the development of institutions'; Geoff Eley, 'The social history of industrialization: proto-industry and the origins of capitalism', Economy and Society, XIII, 4 (November 1984), also stressed the synthetic possibilities of the (then relatively) new field of research.
    • (1996) European Proto-industrialization , pp. 12
    • Schlumbohm, J.1
  • 25
    • 79952248412 scopus 로고
    • The social history of industrialization: Proto-industry and the origins of capitalism
    • November
    • Jurgen Schlumbohm, '"Proto-industrialization" as a research strategy and a historical period - a balance sheet' in Sheilagh C. Ogilvie and Marcus Cerman (eds), European Proto-industrialization (Cambridge, 1996), 12, writes that the concept 'aimed to introduce into economic and social history a new approach which would overcome the divorce between previously separate fields of research' and to bring 'together industrial and agrarian history, adding to them historical demography and the history of the family, and also including the history of everyday culture and the development of institutions'; Geoff Eley, 'The social history of industrialization: proto-industry and the origins of capitalism', Economy and Society, XIII, 4 (November 1984), also stressed the synthetic possibilities of the (then relatively) new field of research.
    • (1984) Economy and Society , vol.13 , Issue.4
    • Eley, G.1
  • 26
    • 0028579549 scopus 로고
    • Oxford
    • Joan Thirsk has argued that to 'concentrate attention on the well-established economic activities of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries -wool clothmaking [in particular] - is like viewing England through a telescope stationed half-way to the moon. Only the most conspicuous landmarks are visible … none of the subtle changes within the structures of innumerable local economies can be discerned': Economic Policy and Projects: The Development of a Consumer Society in Early Modern England (Oxford, 1978), 7. I take Thirsk's point that 'industry' (or the 'mania' for 'projects') meant more than just the 'well-established' manufactures, which represented a movement, a widespread enterprising habit of mind, almost an ideology. On this topic, cf. Jan de Vries, 'The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution'. Journal of Economic History, LIV, 2 (June 1994), 249-70. This said, the cloth industry was the most widespread and prominent form which 'projects' took, and it is perhaps best seen as the 'vanguard' of the movement in that it was via clothmaking that 'industry' inserted itself into national constitutional discourse.
    • (1978) Economic Policy and Projects: The Development of a Consumer Society in Early Modern England , pp. 7
    • Thirsk, J.1
  • 27
    • 0028579549 scopus 로고
    • The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution
    • June
    • Joan Thirsk has argued that to 'concentrate attention on the well-established economic activities of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries - wool clothmaking [in particular] - is like viewing England through a telescope stationed half-way to the moon. Only the most conspicuous landmarks are visible … none of the subtle changes within the structures of innumerable local economies can be discerned': Economic Policy and Projects: The Development of a Consumer Society in Early Modern England (Oxford, 1978), 7. I take Thirsk's point that 'industry' (or the 'mania' for 'projects') meant more than just the 'well-established' manufactures, which represented a movement, a widespread enterprising habit of mind, almost an ideology. On this topic, cf. Jan de Vries, 'The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution'. Journal of Economic History, LIV, 2 (June 1994), 249-70. This said, the cloth industry was the most widespread and prominent form which 'projects' took, and it is perhaps best seen as the 'vanguard' of the movement in that it was via clothmaking that 'industry' inserted itself into national constitutional discourse.
    • (1994) Journal of Economic History , vol.54 , Issue.2 , pp. 249-270
    • De Vries, J.1
  • 28
    • 79959044144 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The return of history: Postmodernism and the politics of academic history in Britain
    • February
    • Referring to the weak impact of the Enlightenment on British culture, Patrick Joyce writes that 'in comparison to much of Europe … Britain's well-developed political institutions meant that historically there was less difficulty in defining "society" in relation to the state (unlike much of Europe, where sociology was born out of social crisis': 'The return of history: postmodernism and the politics of academic history in Britain', Past and Present, CLVIII (February 1998), 217. I would argue that it was the nascent discourse that became political economy that helped teach the English to think (in a particular way) about 'society' and, as I am suggesting here, political economy was born out of an earlier social, economic and political crisis, when the political institutions and culture that Voltaire, for example, so admired were not yet 'well developed'. I am not of course suggesting that the discourse about industry, trade, the state and the common weal (i.e. early political economy) was the only element in the 'field of force': for the revolution in legal discourse, cf. Alan Cromartie, 'The constitutionalist revolution: the transformation of political culture in early Stuart England', Past and Present, CLXIII (May 1999), 76-120.
    • (1998) Past and Present , vol.158 , pp. 217
    • Joyce, P.1
  • 29
    • 84924116553 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The constitutionalist revolution: The transformation of political culture in early Stuart England
    • May
    • Referring to the weak impact of the Enlightenment on British culture, Patrick Joyce writes that 'in comparison to much of Europe … Britain's well-developed political institutions meant that historically there was less difficulty in defining "society" in relation to the state (unlike much of Europe, where sociology was born out of social crisis': 'The return of history: postmodernism and the politics of academic history in Britain', Past and Present, CLVIII (February 1998), 217. I would argue that it was the nascent discourse that became political economy that helped teach the English to think (in a particular way) about 'society' and, as I am suggesting here, political economy was born out of an earlier social, economic and political crisis, when the political institutions and culture that Voltaire, for example, so admired were not yet 'well developed'. I am not of course suggesting that the discourse about industry, trade, the state and the common weal (i.e. early political economy) was the only element in the 'field of force': for the revolution in legal discourse, cf. Alan Cromartie, 'The constitutionalist revolution: the transformation of political culture in early Stuart England', Past and Present, CLXIII (May 1999), 76-120.
    • (1999) Past and Present , vol.163 , pp. 76-120
    • Cromartie, A.1
  • 30
    • 85015127626 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Hudson, op. cit., passim
    • Hudson, op. cit., passim.
  • 31
    • 0002263570 scopus 로고
    • Politics and the study of discourse
    • Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller, London
    • Michel Foucault, 'Politics and the study of Discourse' in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality (London, 1991), describes his 'project' as 'neither a formalization nor an exegesis, but an archaeology … as its name indicates only too obviously, the description of an archive'. By 'governmentality', Foucault meant: '1. The ensemble formed by the institutions, procedures, analyses and reflections, the calculations and tactics that allow the exercise of this very specific albeit complex form of power, which has as its target population, as its principal form of knowledge political economy, and as its essential technical means apparatuses of security; 2. The tendency which, over a long period and throughout the West, has steadily led towards the pre-eminence over all other forms (sovereignty, discipline, etc.) of this type of power which may be termed government, resulting, on the one hand, in the formation of a whole series of specific governmental apparatuses, and, on the other, in the development of a whole series of savoirs; 3. The process, or rather the result of the process, through which the state of justice of the Middle Ages, transformed into the administrative state during the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, gradually becomes "governmentalized"': Foucault, ibid., 102-3.
    • (1991) The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality
    • Foucault, M.1
  • 32
    • 0003756219 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • London
    • Michel Foucault, 'Politics and the study of Discourse' in Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller, The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality (London, 1991), describes his 'project' as 'neither a formalization nor an exegesis, but an archaeology … as its name indicates only too obviously, the description of an archive'. By 'governmentality', Foucault meant: '1. The ensemble formed by the institutions, procedures, analyses and reflections, the calculations and tactics that allow the exercise of this very specific albeit complex form of power, which has as its target population, as its principal form of knowledge political economy, and as its essential technical means apparatuses of security; 2. The tendency which, over a long period and throughout the West, has steadily led towards the pre-eminence over all other forms (sovereignty, discipline, etc.) of this type of power which may be termed government, resulting, on the one hand, in the formation of a whole series of specific governmental apparatuses, and, on the other, in the development of a whole series of savoirs; 3. The process, or rather the result of the process, through which the state of justice of the Middle Ages, transformed into the administrative state during the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, gradually becomes "governmentalized"': Foucault, ibid., 102-3.
    • The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality , pp. 102-103
    • Foucault1
  • 35
    • 0041012283 scopus 로고
    • Gloucester, closer examination suggests that even when the larger clothiers lived in parishes situated in market towns, they nearly always lived at mills some distance from the town itself: e.g. Edward Halydaye 'clothmaker' of Rodborough (PCC Ayloffe 20, 1519); Roger Fowler of Bisley (PCC 34, November 1540); Thomas Sewell of Stroud (PCC Spent 23, 1540); Thomas Walworth of Dursley (PCC Fitiplace 17, 1512); Richard Halydaye complains (PRO Early Chancery Proc. 1005, 1540) that 'the hamlet of Rodborough [mainly concerned with clothmaking] is distant from their parish church of Minchinhampton two and a half miles'
    • Calculations derived from John Smyth of Nibley, Men and Armour for Gloucestershire in 1608 (Gloucester, 1980); closer examination suggests that even when the larger clothiers lived in parishes situated in market towns, they nearly always lived at mills some distance from the town itself: e.g. Edward Halydaye 'clothmaker' of Rodborough (PCC Ayloffe 20, 1519); Roger Fowler of Bisley (PCC 34, November 1540); Thomas Sewell of Stroud (PCC Spent 23, 1540); Thomas Walworth of Dursley (PCC Fitiplace 17, 1512); Richard Halydaye complains (PRO Early Chancery Proc. 1005, 1540) that 'the hamlet of Rodborough [mainly concerned with clothmaking] is distant from their parish church of Minchinhampton two and a half miles'.
    • (1980) Men and Armour for Gloucestershire in 1608
    • Smyth, J.1
  • 37
    • 0003961979 scopus 로고
    • Manchester
    • 'All the outlying villages of the great parish of Manchester were given over to linen weaving. Fustians took hold first in the hilly country between Bolton and Blackburn; by 1630 they had also become firmly established in … the present Oldham area': Alfred P. Wadsworth and Julia De Lacy Mann, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire (Manchester, 1931), 25. The town of Stroud, in Gloucestershire, is somewhat exceptional in being pretty much a commercial and industrial centre from its formation in the thirteenth to fifteenth centuries: its story is told in N. M. Herbert, 'Stroud' in Herbert (ed.), VCH Gloucestershire, XI, 4-41, 99-144.
    • (1931) The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire , pp. 25
    • Wadsworth, A.P.1    De Lacy Mann, J.2
  • 38
    • 0043193287 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Stroud
    • Herbert (ed.)
    • 'All the outlying villages of the great parish of Manchester were given over to linen weaving. Fustians took hold first in the hilly country between Bolton and Blackburn; by 1630 they had also become firmly established in … the present Oldham area': Alfred P. Wadsworth and Julia De Lacy Mann, The Cotton Trade and Industrial Lancashire (Manchester, 1931), 25. The town of Stroud, in Gloucestershire, is somewhat exceptional in being pretty much a commercial and industrial centre from its formation in the thirteenth to fifteenth centuries: its story is told in N. M. Herbert, 'Stroud' in Herbert (ed.), VCH Gloucestershire, XI, 4-41, 99-144.
    • VCH Gloucestershire , vol.11 , pp. 4-41
    • Herbert, N.M.1
  • 40
    • 0003736584 scopus 로고
    • The structures of everyday life
    • New York
    • th Century (New York, 1979); The Wheels of Commerce, Vol. 2 (1982); The Perspective of the World, Vol. 3 (1984).
    • (1979) th Century , vol.1
    • Braudel, F.1
  • 41
    • 85015123365 scopus 로고
    • th Century (New York, 1979); The Wheels of Commerce, Vol. 2 (1982); The Perspective of the World, Vol. 3 (1984).
    • (1982) The Wheels of Commerce , vol.2
  • 42
    • 85015109120 scopus 로고
    • th Century (New York, 1979); The Wheels of Commerce, Vol. 2 (1982); The Perspective of the World, Vol. 3 (1984).
    • (1984) The Perspective of the World , vol.3
  • 43
    • 0042191032 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Growth and recession in the fifteenth-century economy: The Wiltshire textile industry and the countryside
    • J. N. Hare, 'Growth and recession in the fifteenth-century economy: the Wiltshire textile industry and the countryside', Economic History Review, LI (1998), shows that the industrial archipelagos invariably enriched their agricultural hinterlands, adding another reason why 'industries in the countryside' must not be studied in isolation, but always in relation to their specific wider social and economic contexts.
    • (1998) Economic History Review , vol.51
    • Hare, J.N.1
  • 45
    • 85015123627 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Elizabeth CXIV no. 5: in R. H. Tawney and E. Power, Tudor Economic Documents (London, 1924) (TED), vol. I, 176-7.
    • SPD Elizabeth , vol.114 , Issue.5
  • 47
    • 4243816585 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Hen VIII vol. 151, ff. 128-31: ibid., 177.
    • SPD Hen , vol.8-151 , pp. 128-131
  • 48
    • 85015126274 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Hen VIII vol. 151, ff. 128-31: ibid., 177.
    • SPD Hen , pp. 177
  • 52
    • 85015111270 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SP Ireland XXXV, no. 149: TED, vol. I, 189.
    • SP Ireland , vol.35 , Issue.149
  • 53
    • 85015111597 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SP Ireland XXXV, no. 149: TED, vol. I, 189.
    • TED , vol.1 , pp. 189
  • 54
    • 85015113753 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Elizabeth CXIV no. 32: ibid., 191.
    • SPD Elizabeth , vol.114 , Issue.32
  • 55
    • 85015121625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Elizabeth CXIV no. 32: ibid., 191.
    • SPD Elizabeth , pp. 191
  • 56
    • 85015126365 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Elizabeth CLVII no. 5: ibid., 191.
    • SPD Elizabeth , vol.157 , Issue.5
  • 57
    • 85015121625 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • SPD Elizabeth CLVII no. 5: ibid., 191.
    • SPD Elizabeth , pp. 191
  • 59
    • 0042692222 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Wadsworth and Mann, op. cit., 7, where they add that 'the long controversy over the prohibition of middlemen dealers in wool … suggests that the transition to capitalist control was well under way, and that already the large scale entrepreneur had more influence than the petitioners cared (or were tree?) to admit'.
    • SPD Elizabeth , pp. 7
    • Wadsworth1    Mann2
  • 63
    • 0041690350 scopus 로고
    • On seditions and troubles
    • London
    • Francis Bacon, 'On Seditions and Troubles', Essays (London, 1906), 44-5; but cf. also the pamphlet 'Howe to reforme the realme in settyng them to werke and to restore tillage' (c. 1535-6), in TED vol. III, 117: 'Wheras now so grete nombre of idull people ar in Englonde besyde all such that workith husbandry … havyng lyff in theym must needs have living. Ergo, yf they [by] workes of artificialitie gete no money … muste nedes bege or stele their lyvinge from them that werkith husbandrie, or otherwise by craftie meanes of beying and sellyng, or by policy to stody howe of plentie to make scarcitie, for their singulare weale to distroye the comon weale: that is the wisdome of this worlde' (emphasis added).
    • (1906) Essays , pp. 44-45
    • Bacon, F.1
  • 64
    • 0041690353 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Francis Bacon, 'On Seditions and Troubles', Essays (London, 1906), 44-5; but cf. also the pamphlet 'Howe to reforme the realme in settyng them to werke and to restore tillage' (c. 1535-6), in TED vol. III, 117: 'Wheras now so grete nombre of idull people ar in Englonde besyde all such that workith husbandry … havyng lyff in theym must needs have living. Ergo, yf they [by] workes of artificialitie gete no money … muste nedes bege or stele their lyvinge from them that werkith husbandrie, or otherwise by craftie meanes of beying and sellyng, or by policy to stody howe of plentie to make scarcitie, for their singulare weale to distroye the comon weale: that is the wisdome of this worlde' (emphasis added).
    • TED , vol.3 , pp. 117
  • 65
    • 0042692214 scopus 로고
    • Of the internal causes tending to the dissolution of government
    • chap. XII of Bernard Gert (ed.), Indianapolis
    • Thomas Hobbes, 'Of the internal causes tending to the dissolution of government', chap. XII of Bernard Gert (ed.), The Citizen; Philosophical Rudiments Concerning Government and Society (Indianapolis, 1991), 251-2.
    • (1991) The Citizen; Philosophical Rudiments Concerning Government and Society , pp. 251-252
    • Hobbes, T.1
  • 68
    • 0041182050 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley
    • Neal Wood, Foundations of Political Economy: Some Early Tudor Views on State and Society (Berkeley, 1994); Wood, 'Foundations of political economy: the new moral philosophy of Sir Thomas Smith' in Paul A. Fideler and T. F. Mayer (eds), Political Thought and the Tudor Commonwealth: Deep Structure, Discourse and Disguise (Cambridge, 1997); Keith Wrightson, Earthly Necessities: Economic Lives in Early Modern Britain (New Haven and London, 2000), 154-6.
    • (1994) Foundations of Political Economy: Some Early Tudor Views on State and Society
    • Wood, N.1
  • 69
    • 0039416847 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Foundations of political economy: The new moral philosophy of Sir Thomas Smith
    • Paul A. Fideler and T. F. Mayer (eds), Cambridge
    • Neal Wood, Foundations of Political Economy: Some Early Tudor Views on State and Society (Berkeley, 1994); Wood, 'Foundations of political economy: the new moral philosophy of Sir Thomas Smith' in Paul A. Fideler and T. F. Mayer (eds), Political Thought and the Tudor Commonwealth: Deep Structure, Discourse and Disguise (Cambridge, 1997); Keith Wrightson, Earthly Necessities: Economic Lives in Early Modern Britain (New Haven and London, 2000), 154-6.
    • (1997) Political Thought and the Tudor Commonwealth: Deep Structure, Discourse and Disguise
    • Wood1
  • 70
    • 0003424314 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New Haven and London
    • Neal Wood, Foundations of Political Economy: Some Early Tudor Views on State and Society (Berkeley, 1994); Wood, 'Foundations of political economy: the new moral philosophy of Sir Thomas Smith' in Paul A. Fideler and T. F. Mayer (eds), Political Thought and the Tudor Commonwealth: Deep Structure, Discourse and Disguise (Cambridge, 1997); Keith Wrightson, Earthly Necessities: Economic Lives in Early Modern Britain (New Haven and London, 2000), 154-6.
    • (2000) Earthly Necessities: Economic Lives in Early Modern Britain , pp. 154-156
    • Wrightson, K.1
  • 73
    • 78649440805 scopus 로고
    • De republica anglorum
    • William Huse Dunham and Stanley Pargellis (eds), New York
    • The cloth industry was thought to provide employment for 'the fourth sort of men which do not rule … day labourers, poor husbandmen, yea merchants or retailers which have no free land, copyholders, and all artificers … (who) have no authority in our commonwealth': Sir Thomas Smith, De Republica Anglorum (written before 1565), William Huse Dunham and Stanley Pargellis (eds), Complaint and Reform in England, 1436-1714 (New York, 1968), 212.
    • (1968) Complaint and Reform in England, 1436-1714 , pp. 212
    • Smith, T.1
  • 75
    • 0043193247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • op. cit
    • 'In France they have divers bands of men of arms in divers places to repress such tumults quickly if any should arise. If we had the like here, we might be bold to have as many artificers as they have': the Knight, in A Discourse of the Commonweal, op. cit., 92.
    • A Discourse of the Commonweal , pp. 92
  • 76
    • 0042191067 scopus 로고
    • Reprints of Economic Classics: New York
    • John Smith, Memoirs of Wool, 1747 (Reprints of Economic Classics: New York, 1969), vol. I, 98-101.
    • (1747) Memoirs of Wool , vol.1 , pp. 98-101
    • Smith, J.1
  • 78
    • 0007295029 scopus 로고
    • facsimiles of 1589 edition, eds David Beers Quinn and Raleigh Ashlin Skelton Cambridge
    • Richard Hakluyt the younger printed seven of the elder Hakluyt's memoranda in his Principal Navigations, Voyages and Discoveries of the English Nation, facsimiles of 1589 edition, eds David Beers Quinn and Raleigh Ashlin Skelton (Cambridge, 1965); cf. especially 'Inducements to the liking of the voyage intended towards Virginia' (1582) in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts (Hakluyt Society, London, 1935), 'Which way the Savage may be able to purchase our cloth' in 'Notes in writing by M. Richard Hakluyt Esquire … To M. Arthur Pet, and to M. Charles Jackman … for the discoverie of the Northeast straight', ibid., 460ff., and 'Remembrance … for a principall English factor at Constantinople', ibid., 161ff.
    • (1965) Principal Navigations, Voyages and Discoveries of the English Nation
    • Hakluyt, R.1
  • 79
    • 0042191065 scopus 로고
    • Inducements to the liking of the voyage intended towards Virginia
    • Hakluyt Society, London
    • Richard Hakluyt the younger printed seven of the elder Hakluyt's memoranda in his Principal Navigations, Voyages and Discoveries of the English Nation, facsimiles of 1589 edition, eds David Beers Quinn and Raleigh Ashlin Skelton (Cambridge, 1965); cf. especially 'Inducements to the liking of the voyage intended towards Virginia' (1582) in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts (Hakluyt Society, London, 1935), 'Which way the Savage may be able to purchase our cloth' in 'Notes in writing by M. Richard Hakluyt Esquire … To M. Arthur Pet, and to M. Charles Jackman … for the discoverie of the Northeast straight', ibid., 460ff., and 'Remembrance … for a principall English factor at Constantinople', ibid., 161ff.
    • (1582) The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts
    • Taylor, E.G.R.1
  • 80
    • 10444253799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Notes in writing by M. Richard Hakluyt Esquire … To M. Arthur Pet, and to M. Charles Jackman … for the discoverie of the Northeast straight 460ff
    • Richard Hakluyt the younger printed seven of the elder Hakluyt's memoranda in his Principal Navigations, Voyages and Discoveries of the English Nation, facsimiles of 1589 edition, eds David Beers Quinn and Raleigh Ashlin Skelton (Cambridge, 1965); cf. especially 'Inducements to the liking of the voyage intended towards Virginia' (1582) in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts (Hakluyt Society, London, 1935), 'Which way the Savage may be able to purchase our cloth' in 'Notes in writing by M. Richard Hakluyt Esquire … To M. Arthur Pet, and to M. Charles Jackman … for the discoverie of the Northeast straight', ibid., 460ff., and 'Remembrance … for a principall English factor at Constantinople', ibid., 161ff.
    • The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts
  • 81
    • 85015121825 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Remembrance … For a principall English factor at Constantinople
    • 161ff
    • Richard Hakluyt the younger printed seven of the elder Hakluyt's memoranda in his Principal Navigations, Voyages and Discoveries of the English Nation, facsimiles of 1589 edition, eds David Beers Quinn and Raleigh Ashlin Skelton (Cambridge, 1965); cf. especially 'Inducements to the liking of the voyage intended towards Virginia' (1582) in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts (Hakluyt Society, London, 1935), 'Which way the Savage may be able to purchase our cloth' in 'Notes in writing by M. Richard Hakluyt Esquire … To M. Arthur Pet, and to M. Charles Jackman … for the discoverie of the Northeast straight', ibid., 460ff., and 'Remembrance … for a principall English factor at Constantinople', ibid., 161ff.
    • The Original Writings and Correspondence of the Two Richard Hakluyts
  • 82
    • 0042692181 scopus 로고
    • The dynamics of commercial development, 1550-1640: A reinterpretation
    • chap. I Cambridge
    • For a discussion of the historiography of the crisis, and a new reading of its significance, cf. Robert Brenner, 'The dynamics of commercial development, 1550-1640: a reinterpretation', chap. I of Brenner, Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550-1653 (Cambridge, 1993). I think Brenner overstates the overall importance in the emerging field-of-force, of the company merchants, and that his interpretation is, as a result, too London-centred. In my interpretation the innovative force comes from the 'peripheries', i.e. the provincial industries.
    • (1993) Merchants and Revolution: Commercial Change, Political Conflict, and London's Overseas Traders, 1550-1653
    • Brenner, R.1
  • 84
    • 0043193247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'I take not (enclosures) to be the only cause of this dearth [dearness] at this time, but this I think in my mind that if that kind of enclosure do as much increase in twenty years to come as it has done twenty years past, it comes to the great desolation and weakening of the King's strength of this realm which is more to be feared than dearth': ibid., 49 (emphasis added).
    • A Discourse of the Commonweal , pp. 49
  • 85
  • 86
    • 0042692180 scopus 로고
    • William Huse Dunham and Stanley Pargellis (eds), New York
    • Richard Hakluyt, A Particular Discourse Concerning the great necessity and manifold commodities that are like to grow … by the western discoveries … in William Huse Dunham and Stanley Pargellis (eds), Complaint and Reform in England, 1436-1714 (New York, 1968), 312.
    • (1968) Complaint and Reform in England, 1436-1714 , pp. 312
    • Hakluyt, R.1
  • 88
    • 0043193251 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Preacher
    • repr. op. cit
    • Richard Hakluyt the Elder, Inducements to the Liking of the Voyage Intended Towards Virginia (c. 1585), repr. in Richard Hakluyt 'Preacher', Voyages and Discoveries …, op. cit.
    • Voyages and Discoveries …
    • Hakluyt, R.1
  • 90
    • 28244479204 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Notes in writing … given by Richard Hakluyt, of Eiton in the Countie of Hereford, Anno 1580, to M. Arthur Pet and M. Charles Jackman … merchants of the Muscovy Company' op. cit
    • 'Notes in writing … given by Richard Hakluyt, of Eiton in the Countie of Hereford, Anno 1580, to M. Arthur Pet and M. Charles Jackman … merchants of the Muscovy Company' in Hakluyt the Preacher, Voyages and Discoveries … op. cit., 461.
    • Voyages and Discoveries … , pp. 461
    • Hakluyt1
  • 91
    • 85015113803 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 'Remembrance for Master S to give him the better occasion to inform himself of some things in England, and after of some other things in Turkie, to the greate profite of the common weale of this country, written … for a principall English factor at Constantinople, 1582' in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), op. cit., 161ff
    • 'Remembrance for Master S to give him the better occasion to inform himself of some things in England, and after of some other things in Turkie, to the greate profite of the common weale of this country, written … for a principall English factor at Constantinople, 1582' in E. G. R. Taylor (ed.), op. cit., 161ff.
  • 92
    • 53249114141 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Brenner's argument (op. cit., e.g. 5, n. 6) that 'imports powered commercial expansion' is fine as far as it goes, but chronologically, in my view, it puts the cart before the horse. I argue that the developing groundswell represented by what I am calling 'the discourse of industry' (and, in turn, its causes) was a precondition for the eventual victory of the merchants' political economy, which was to achieve its most abstract rhetorical form in Misselden's Circle of Commerce. What we call 'industry', the production of commodities, Misselden called 'Projects', which, 'though they promise much, yet the utility is commonly Contingent, which may be, or may not be'. Against the arguments of the clothiers, who wanted the merchant monopolies abolished, Misselden argued that 'industry' was contingent upon Trade. Thus 'in the mutation of the naturall course of Trade, there ought to be Perspicuity and apparency of evident utility: Else a Breach may be sooner made in Trade then can be repaired: and the Current once diverted, will hardly bee revolved, into it genuine Source and Course againe.' Wise governments tinkered with trade at their own peril. Industry needed governing. The great merchants knew best the crafts and mysteries of trade: Edward Misselden, op. cit.
    • Circle of Commerce
    • Misselden1
  • 93
    • 85015125702 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Edward Misselden, op. cit
    • Brenner's argument (op. cit., e.g. 5, n. 6) that 'imports powered commercial expansion' is fine as far as it goes, but chronologically, in my view, it puts the cart before the horse. I argue that the developing groundswell represented by what I am calling 'the discourse of industry' (and, in turn, its causes) was a precondition for the eventual victory of the merchants' political economy, which was to achieve its most abstract rhetorical form in Misselden's Circle of Commerce. What we call 'industry', the production of commodities, Misselden called 'Projects', which, 'though they promise much, yet the utility is commonly Contingent, which may be, or may not be'. Against the arguments of the clothiers, who wanted the merchant monopolies abolished, Misselden argued that 'industry' was contingent upon Trade. Thus 'in the mutation of the naturall course of Trade, there ought to be Perspicuity and apparency of evident utility: Else a Breach may be sooner made in Trade then can be repaired: and the Current once diverted, will hardly bee revolved, into it genuine Source and Course againe.' Wise governments tinkered with trade at their own peril. Industry needed governing. The great merchants knew best the crafts and mysteries of trade: Edward Misselden, op. cit.
  • 94
    • 0043193279 scopus 로고
    • The destabilization of social categories
    • Baltimore, chap. 4
    • Michael McKeon, The Origins of the English Novel 1600-1740 (Baltimore, 1988), chap. 4, 'The destabilization of social categories'; Keith Wrightson traces 'the language of sorts of people [… an essentially dichotomous perception of society …]' to 'the second quarter of the sixteenth century': 'Sorts of people in Tudor and Stuart England' in Jonathan Barry and Christopher Brooks (eds), The Middling Sort of People, Culture Society and Politics in England, 1550-1800 (London, 1994), 33-4.
    • (1988) The Origins of the English Novel 1600-1740
    • McKeon, M.1
  • 95
    • 0042692179 scopus 로고
    • Sorts of people in Tudor and Stuart England
    • Jonathan Barry and Christopher Brooks (eds), London
    • Michael McKeon, The Origins of the English Novel 1600-1740 (Baltimore, 1988), chap. 4, 'The destabilization of social categories'; Keith Wrightson traces 'the language of sorts of people [… an essentially dichotomous perception of society …]' to 'the second quarter of the sixteenth century': 'Sorts of people in Tudor and Stuart England' in Jonathan Barry and Christopher Brooks (eds), The Middling Sort of People, Culture Society and Politics in England, 1550-1800 (London, 1994), 33-4.
    • (1994) The Middling Sort of People, Culture Society and Politics in England, 1550-1800 , pp. 33-34
    • Wrightson, K.1
  • 98
    • 0003416548 scopus 로고
    • trans. R. J. Hollingdale Harmondsworth
    • 'We enjoy (Shakespeare) as an artistic refinement reserved precisely for us and allow ourselves to be as little disturbed by the repellent fumes and the proximity of the English rabble in which Shakespeare's art and taste live as we do on the Chiaja of Naples, where we go our way enchanted and willing with all our senses alert, however much the sewers of the plebeian quarters may fill the air': Nietzsche, Beyond Good and Evil, trans. R. J. Hollingdale (Harmondsworth, 1973), 134-5.
    • (1973) Beyond Good and Evil , pp. 134-135
    • Nietzsche1
  • 99
    • 83755174855 scopus 로고
    • trans. James S. Holmes and Hans van Marie New York
    • Deloney exemplifies a theory of 'plebeian realism' developed from two of the essays in Johan Huizinga, Men and Ideas, trans. James S. Holmes and Hans van Marie (New York, 1959). In 'Renaissance and realism', Huizinga defines 'realism' as 'a need to depict reality accurately' (ibid., 308); in 'The task of cultural history', he writes that 'if one removes the sting of disdain from the word "plebeian", the term "democratic" can be reserved for political and social fields, and the concept plebeian can be placed in antithesis to aristocratic in the field of culture' (ibid., 47).
    • (1959) Men and Ideas
    • Huizinga, J.1
  • 100
    • 0042191054 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Renaissance and realism
    • Deloney exemplifies a theory of 'plebeian realism' developed from two of the essays in Johan Huizinga, Men and Ideas, trans. James S. Holmes and Hans van Marie (New York, 1959). In 'Renaissance and realism', Huizinga defines 'realism' as 'a need to depict reality accurately' (ibid., 308); in 'The task of cultural history', he writes that 'if one removes the sting of disdain from the word "plebeian", the term "democratic" can be reserved for political and social fields, and the concept plebeian can be placed in antithesis to aristocratic in the field of culture' (ibid., 47).
    • Men and Ideas , pp. 308
    • Huizinga1
  • 101
    • 0041690345 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The task of cultural history
    • Deloney exemplifies a theory of 'plebeian realism' developed from two of the essays in Johan Huizinga, Men and Ideas, trans. James S. Holmes and Hans van Marie (New York, 1959). In 'Renaissance and realism', Huizinga defines 'realism' as 'a need to depict reality accurately' (ibid., 308); in 'The task of cultural history', he writes that 'if one removes the sting of disdain from the word "plebeian", the term "democratic" can be reserved for political and social fields, and the concept plebeian can be placed in antithesis to aristocratic in the field of culture' (ibid., 47).
    • Men and Ideas , pp. 47
  • 102
    • 0042692216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Mann (ed.), op. cit., xiii, citing Skialetheia or the Shadow of the Truth (1598)
    • Men and Ideas , pp. xiii
    • Mann1
  • 104
    • 0043193247 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • op. cit
    • 'They have in France more handicrafts occupied and a greater multitude of artificers than we have by a great deal, and for all that they have made many great stirs and commotions there before this. Yet they will not destroy artificers for they knew that the highest princes of them all without such artificers could not maintain their estate'. A Discourse of the Commonweal, op. cit., 89 (emphasis added).
    • A Discourse of the Commonweal , pp. 89
  • 105
    • 0043193249 scopus 로고
    • Cambridge
    • Barry Supple, Commercial Crisis and Change in England, 1600-1642 (Cambridge, 1959), 56-7. Mary Poovey, A History of the Modern Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Sciences of Wealth and Society (Chicago, 1998) sees the conjuncture as being of momentous significance. 'These developments', she writes (71), 'witnessed a realignment of the relations among politics, religion, economic activity, and the production of knowledge. This realignment created the idea that abstract knowledge (theory) [i. e. of society] could be value-free.' Unemployment among the cloth workers of England caused the social science mentality?
    • (1959) Commercial Crisis and Change in England, 1600-1642 , pp. 56-57
    • Supple, B.1
  • 106
    • 0003492971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Chicago
    • Barry Supple, Commercial Crisis and Change in England, 1600-1642 (Cambridge, 1959), 56-7. Mary Poovey, A History of the Modern Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Sciences of Wealth and Society (Chicago, 1998) sees the conjuncture as being of momentous significance. 'These developments', she writes (71), 'witnessed a realignment of the relations among politics, religion, economic activity, and the production of knowledge. This realignment created the idea that abstract knowledge (theory) [i. e. of society] could be value-free.' Unemployment among the cloth workers of England caused the social science mentality?
    • (1998) A History of the Modern Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Sciences of Wealth and Society
    • Poovey, M.1
  • 107
    • 0043193280 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • State papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622
    • 'State Papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622', Transactions of the Bristol and Gloucestershire Archaeological Society, V, 154-62. For earlier sources indicating the same pattern: 'Negotiations between the clothiers and the Merchant Adventurers, 1550', TED, vol. I, 184; 'An agreement between the Western Clothiers and the merchant Adventurers, December 24 1586', ibid., 214-15; Rollison, 'Exploding England: the dialectics of mobility and settlement in early modern England', Social History, XXIV, 1 (January 1999), 11; William Woodall (curate of Stroud 1599-1610), A Sermon on the original and accidental causes of every dearth and famine, and especially of this dearth in England now 1608 and 1609 (London, 1609): Gloucestershire Records Office (Hyett Colln.), Pamphlet 351.
    • Transactions of the Bristol and Gloucestershire Archaeological Society , vol.5 , pp. 154-162
  • 108
    • 0042191055 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Negotiations between the clothiers and the merchant adventurers, 1550
    • 'State Papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622', Transactions of the Bristol and Gloucestershire Archaeological Society, V, 154-62. For earlier sources indicating the same pattern: 'Negotiations between the clothiers and the Merchant Adventurers, 1550', TED, vol. I, 184; 'An agreement between the Western Clothiers and the merchant Adventurers, December 24 1586', ibid., 214-15; Rollison, 'Exploding England: the dialectics of mobility and settlement in early modern England', Social History, XXIV, 1 (January 1999), 11; William Woodall (curate of Stroud 1599-1610), A Sermon on the original and accidental causes of every dearth and famine, and especially of this dearth in England now 1608 and 1609 (London, 1609): Gloucestershire Records Office (Hyett Colln.), Pamphlet 351.
    • TED , vol.1 , pp. 184
  • 109
    • 0042692215 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • An agreement between the western clothiers and the merchant adventurers, December 24 1586
    • 'State Papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622', Transactions of the Bristol and Gloucestershire Archaeological Society, V, 154-62. For earlier sources indicating the same pattern: 'Negotiations between the clothiers and the Merchant Adventurers, 1550', TED, vol. I, 184; 'An agreement between the Western Clothiers and the merchant Adventurers, December 24 1586', ibid., 214-15; Rollison, 'Exploding England: the dialectics of mobility and settlement in early modern England', Social History, XXIV, 1 (January 1999), 11; William Woodall (curate of Stroud 1599-1610), A Sermon on the original and accidental causes of every dearth and famine, and especially of this dearth in England now 1608 and 1609 (London, 1609): Gloucestershire Records Office (Hyett Colln.), Pamphlet 351.
    • TED , pp. 214-215
  • 110
    • 85011186878 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Exploding England: The dialectics of mobility and settlement in early modern England
    • January
    • 'State Papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622', Transactions of the
    • (1999) Social History , vol.24 , Issue.1 , pp. 11
    • Rollison1
  • 111
    • 0043193250 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • (curate of Stroud 1599-1610), London, Gloucestershire Records Office (Hyett Colln.), Pamphlet 351
    • 'State Papers relating to the cloth trade, 1622', Transactions of the Bristol and Gloucestershire Archaeological Society, V, 154-62. For earlier sources indicating the same pattern: 'Negotiations between the clothiers and the Merchant Adventurers, 1550', TED, vol. I, 184; 'An agreement between the Western Clothiers and the merchant Adventurers, December 24 1586', ibid., 214-15; Rollison, 'Exploding England: the dialectics of mobility and settlement in early modern England', Social History, XXIV, 1 (January 1999), 11; William Woodall (curate of Stroud 1599-1610), A Sermon on the original and accidental causes of every dearth and famine, and especially of this dearth in England now 1608 and 1609 (London, 1609): Gloucestershire Records Office (Hyett Colln.), Pamphlet 351.
    • (1609) A Sermon on the Original and Accidental Causes of Every Dearth and Famine, and Especially of This Dearth in England Now 1608 and 1609
    • Woodall, W.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.