메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 9, Issue 1, 1996, Pages 3-53

Free Banking and the Free Bankers

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0008346398     PISSN: 08893047     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1007/bf01101880     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (39)

References (110)
  • 2
    • 53349099458 scopus 로고
    • Banking and Interest Bates in a World Without Money
    • See Fischer BlackBanking and Interest Bates in a World Without Money Journal of Banking Research 1 (1970);
    • (1970) Journal of Banking Research , vol.1
  • 6
    • 53349118299 scopus 로고
    • A Legal Restrictions Theory of the Demand for 'Money' and the Role of Monetary Policy
    • See Neil WallaceA Legal Restrictions Theory of the Demand for 'Money' and the Role of Monetary Policy Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review (1983);
    • (1983) Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review
  • 7
    • 0000665305 scopus 로고
    • The Real-Bills Doctrine versus the Quantity Theory: A Reconsideration
    • Thomas Sargent and Neil WallaceThe Real-Bills Doctrine versus the Quantity Theory: A Reconsideration Journal of Political Economy 90 (1982).
    • (1982) Journal of Political Economy , vol.90
    • Sargent, T.1    Wallace, N.2
  • 8
    • 0007891755 scopus 로고
    • London: Phillip Allan
    • With the exception of Kevin Dowd, see, The State and the Monetary System (London: Phillip Allan, 1989), p. 188;
    • (1989) The State and the Monetary System , pp. 188
  • 9
    • 0010924996 scopus 로고
    • New York: Routledge
    • idem., Laissez-faire Banking New York: Routledge, 1993), pp. 66f;
    • (1993) Laissez-faire Banking
  • 12
    • 34250084122 scopus 로고
    • Aurophobia: Or, Free Banking on What Standard?
    • For a critique of the latter see RothbardAurophobia: or, Free Banking on What Standard? Review of Austrian Economics 6, no. 1 (1992): 97-108.
    • (1992) Review of Austrian Economics , vol.6 , Issue.1 , pp. 97-108
  • 13
    • 0000638011 scopus 로고
    • How Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?
    • George Selgin and Lawrence WhiteHow Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money? Journal of Economic Literature 32 (1994): 1737.
    • (1994) Journal of Economic Literature , vol.32 , pp. 1737
    • Selgin, G.1    White, L.2
  • 14
    • 53349156909 scopus 로고
    • Identifying Money
    • New York: New York University Press
    • See also Lawrence WhiteIdentifying Money in his Competition and Currency (New York: New York University Press, 1989), pp. 206ff.
    • (1989) In His Competition and Currency
    • White, L.1
  • 15
    • 53349118298 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the contrary opinion of White, ibid., pp. 134f.
    • See the contrary opinion of White, ibid., pp. 134f.
  • 16
    • 0010210267 scopus 로고
    • Indianapolis, Ind.: Liberty Classics, 1990; Kevin Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, esp. chap. 10.
    • See, for example, V. C. Smith, The Rationale of Central Banking (1936; Indianapolis, Ind.: Liberty Classics, 1990); Kevin Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, esp. chap. 10.
    • (1936) The Rationale of Central Banking
    • Smith, V.C.1
  • 17
    • 53349118296 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is noteworthy that what is said about banks applies to virtually all financial intermediaries dealing with money substitutes. Money substitutes are not only banknotes and demand deposits but principally all claims that have to be redeemed at par into money whenever the holder of the claim likes to have money substitutes. See in particular Murray N. Rothbard's excellent analysis of money substitutes in the 1920s in America's Great Depression, 4th ed. (New York: Richardson and Snyder, 1983), p. 83.
  • 18
    • 53349089915 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Condy Raguet's discussion "Of Banks of Deposits, Banks of Discount, and Banks of Circulation" in his Treatise on Currency and Banking (New York, 1840), pp. 67ff.
    • See Condy Raguet's discussion "Of Banks of Deposits, Banks of Discount, and Banks of Circulation" in his Treatise on Currency and Banking (New York, 1840), pp. 67ff.
  • 19
    • 53349091971 scopus 로고
    • How is Fiat Money Possible
    • See, Hans-Hermann HoppeHow is Fiat Money Possible Review of Austrian Economics 7, no. 2 (1995): 57.
    • (1995) Review of Austrian Economics , vol.7 , Issue.2 , pp. 57
    • Hoppe, H.-H.1
  • 20
    • 53349145973 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This argument was used by Condillac in order to claim that not only the quantity of money is rather irrelevant but that, on the contrary, it would be advantageous if it were smaller ("On voit donc qu'il est assez indifférent qu'il y ait beaucomp d'argent, et qu'il serait même avantageux qu'il y en eut moins. En effet, le commerce se ferait plus commodément. Quel embarras ne serait-ce pas si l'argent était aussi commun que le fer?" Le Commerce et le gouvernement (Paris, 1795), p. 87).
  • 22
    • 0004054113 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.O.: Cato Institute
    • George Selgin, The Theory of Free Banking (Washington, D.O.: Cato Institute, 1988), p. 53.
    • (1988) The Theory of Free Banking , pp. 53
    • Selgin, G.1
  • 23
    • 53349153509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Larry Sechrest, Free Banking: Theory, History, and a Laissez-faire Model (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1993), p, 66.
    • Larry Sechrest, Free Banking: Theory, History, and a Laissez-faire Model (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1993), p, 66.
  • 27
    • 53349145966 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Transfer credit is "credit granted by banks in recognition of people's desire to abstain from spending by holding balances of inside money" (p. 60). This of course, is no definition. Every use of money implies the holding of it.
    • See Selgin, The Theory of Free Banking, pp. 60ff. Transfer credit is "credit granted by banks in recognition of people's desire to abstain from spending by holding balances of inside money" (p. 60). This of course, is no definition. Every use of money implies the holding of it.
    • The Theory of Free Banking
  • 29
    • 0040689111 scopus 로고
    • Indianapolis: Liberty Press
    • See the following, for example, W. H. Hutt, The Keynesian Episode (Indianapolis: Liberty Press, 1979), pp. 51ff.
    • (1979) The Keynesian Episode
    • Hutt, W.H.1
  • 30
    • 53349101562 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See the analoguous remarks of Mises concerning the possibility of stabilizing the value of money in his Theory of Money and Credit (Irvington-on-Hudson, N.Y.: Foundation for Economic Education, 1971), pp. 123-31.
    • See the analoguous remarks of Mises concerning the possibility of stabilizing the value of money in his Theory of Money and Credit (Irvington-on-Hudson, N.Y.: Foundation for Economic Education, 1971), pp. 123-31.
  • 31
    • 53349171683 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Works 3 (London: John Murray, 1811)
    • For example David Ricardo, The High Price of Bullion, Works 3 (London: John Murray, 1811), p. 73
    • The High Price of Bullion , pp. 73
  • 32
    • 53349160525 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Evolution of a Free Banking System
    • chap. 2, and in White, Competition and Currency, chap. 12; also Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, pp. 26-33, 59-68.
    • G. Selgin and L. H, WhiteThe Evolution of a Free Banking System in Selgin, The Theory of Free Banking, chap. 2, and in White, Competition and Currency, chap. 12; also Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, pp. 26-33, 59-68.
    • In Selgin, the Theory of Free Banking
  • 33
    • 53349177117 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1949), pp. 571ff; and Murray N. Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State (Los Angeles: Nash, 1962), pp. 850ff.
    • See Ludwig von Mises, Human Action (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1949), pp. 571ff; and Murray N. Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State (Los Angeles: Nash, 1962), pp. 850ff.
  • 34
    • 53349151327 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • By the way, it is not true that a reduction of the inflated money stock is the cause of crises. It is already the widespread injection of additional money via the credit system which implies that money calculation has to fail on a wide scale. Once the failure becomes obvious in the form of a crisis, a reduction of the money stock has the effect of accelerating recovery. Hence, one cannot claim that "Austrian economists such as Rothbard add that it was the Ped's expansionary policies during the 1920s that precipitated the crisis, which was exacerbated by the Ped's later inaction" Steven Horwitz, Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 182 [emph. added]. This claim presupposes that monetary expansion is but a detail in the picture of business cycles and that Rothbard shared the view that it is the drop of the money stock which creates crisis. Neither is true.
  • 35
    • 53349141539 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a vain attempt to prove the contrary, see, Dowd, The State and the Monetary System, p. 60ff.
    • For a vain attempt to prove the contrary, see, Dowd, The State and the Monetary System, p. 60ff.
  • 36
    • 53349127798 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a brilliant analysis Fritz Machlup demonstrated that the time horizon for which a credit is given has nothing to do with the time horizon of its employment. It is thus illusory to believe that fiduciary issues would only finance transfers (Börsenkredit, Industriekredit und Kapitalbildung [Vienna, 1931], pp. 139,179ff).
  • 41
    • 53349175063 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • White, Competition and Currency, p. 158.
    • White, Competition and Currency, p. 158.
  • 43
    • 53349141540 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This means the quantity of money (money in the narrower sense) plus the quantity of fiduciary money substitutes. The latter always equals zero in a 100 percent reserve system. The money supply in the larger sense, then, always equals the money supply in the narrower sense. Only in a system of fractional reserves can these two aggregates deviate from one another.
  • 44
    • 53349160526 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Consequently, it is not surprising that some advocate the absurd idea that the crisis of the thirties had been the outcome of heavy variations of the value of gold (Glasner, Free Banking and Money Reform, p. 222ff). For a critique see the articles by Wiegand, Kemmerer, and North in Gold Is Money, Hans Sennholz, ed. (Westport, Conn.: Greenwood Press, 1975). Cause and effect are confused. The value of gold changed heavily because of big variations of the quantity of its substitutes. The same confusion prevails about the variations of the gold price of the 1980s. Gold went up because many market participants expected it to soon become money again. It went down when it became obvious that these expectations were premature. This was partly due to the views of experts who considered it as "a commodity whose purchasing power is subject to violent and erratic fluctation" (White, Competition and Currency, p. 131).
  • 45
    • 53349097291 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • "[I]t takes time for changes in spending to influence prices in a general way" Selgin, The Theory of Free Banking, pp. 53f.
    • "[I]t takes time for changes in spending to influence prices in a general way" Selgin, The Theory of Free Banking, pp. 53f.
  • 46
    • 53349145967 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Convertibility taken fallaciously in its larger, meaningless sense. See the section entitled "Money and Substitutes for Money" in a previous section in this article.
    • Convertibility taken fallaciously in its larger, meaningless sense. See the section entitled "Money and Substitutes for Money" in a previous section in this article.
  • 50
    • 0004168866 scopus 로고
    • London: Longmans, Green
    • Unfortunately, such conceptual confusion prevails also in one of the most brilliant expositions of the problems of fractional reserve banking, see, F. A. Hayek, Monetary Nationalism and International Stability (London: Longmans, Green, 1937).
    • (1937) Monetary Nationalism and International Stability
    • Hayek, F.A.1
  • 53
    • 53349089919 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that its application in the context of savings-investment is incompatible with its application to justify the "anchor theory." However, as both are fallacious we do not have to dwell on inconsistencies between the tenets of the free bankers.
  • 56
    • 0008312191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar
    • Leland B. Yeager, ed. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, Reprinted in book form by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama in 1991.
    • Murray RothbardThe Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar in In Search of A Monetary Constitution, Leland B. Yeager, ed. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1962), pp. 115-6. Reprinted in book form by the Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama in 1991.
    • (1962) In in Search of A Monetary Constitution , pp. 115-116
    • Rothbard, M.1
  • 60
    • 53349171686 scopus 로고
    • Forrest Capie and Geoffrey Wood, eds. London and New York: St. Martins Press
    • Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, p. 48. This is precisely the argument of the central bankers. Goodhart, for example, claims that central banks are necessary "to support the residual, risky, 'true', banking institutions, which were undertaking the necessary function of making loans to borrowers who could not otherwise sell their own equity and debt in extant financial markets" ("Are Central Banks Necessary? Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order?, Forrest Capie and Geoffrey Wood, eds. (London and New York: St. Martins Press, 1989), p. 18.
    • (1989) Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order? , pp. 18
  • 61
    • 0003801335 scopus 로고
    • Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel
    • Murray N. Rothbard, Power and Market, 2nd ed. (Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel, 1977), p. 186.
    • (1977) Power and Market, 2nd Ed. , pp. 186
    • Rothbard, M.N.1
  • 63
    • 0008346402 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • 56Ibid., p. 157. 57Ibid., p. 156.
    • White, Competition and Currency, p. 156. 56Ibid., p. 157. 57Ibid., p. 156.
    • Competition and Currency , pp. 156
    • White1
  • 66
    • 53349145971 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It seems to be the intention of discussing Simmel's work at length to prepare the ground for a communication theory of money (ibid., pp. 9 Iff). The same reproach must be made for citing Mises's ideas on the importance of language from his Nation, State, and Economy (New York: New York University Press, 1983). Indeed, these belong to the few ideas Mises considerably revised later on (Omnipotent Government [New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1944]). It is impossible to claim his authority in support of the tenet that "ideas do not exist extralinguistically" (Horwitz, Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 186).
  • 67
    • 84928448666 scopus 로고
    • The Resource Cost of Irredeemable Paper Money
    • See Maehlup, Börsenkredit, Industriekredit und Kapitalbildung, pp. 143ff. Horwitz, Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 146 n. 46. TVHlton FriedmanThe Resource Cost of Irredeemable Paper Money Journal of Political Economy (1986).
    • (1986) Journal of Political Economy
  • 68
    • 53349160530 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Rechte und Verhaeltnisse vom gueterwirtschaftlichen Standpunkt
    • note
    • Here my opinion deviates from that of Rothbard. He says: "A man may allocate his money to consumption, investment, or addition to his cash balance." (Man, Economy, and State, p. 678, see also pp. 179f), thus suggesting that holding a cash balance is something different from savings-investment. Hans-Hermann Hoppe has given another expression to this view in claiming that time-preference and the utility of money are "two distinct and praxeologically unrelated factors" (The Economics and Ethics of Private Property [Boston: Kluwer, 1993], p. 119). To be sure, there is no causal connection between the demand for money and the interest rate. Increasing the quantity of money cannot reduce the interest rate because money's real value, its purchasing power, would be reduced accordingly. Yet this is no reason to overlook the unity in all acts, viz., in all valuation. Value is the preference accorded to an effect, and at least in the realm of action this can mean nothing but that the preferred effect should be achieved before alternative but less urgent effects. As action-and all other means-are always employed in the pursuit of some ends or effects acting man necessarily has to value (i.e., select) his means according to the urgency of the ends they are supposed to achieve. Thus, time-valuation is present in all actions. Actions with money can be no exception. However, it should be noted that it is the holding of money which constitutes savings-investment. The holding of money substitutes, on the other hand, does not constitute savings-investment but claims on savings-investment in the form of money. It cannot give disposition of more than the existing stock of money-even if the owners of fiduciary money substitutes believe the contrary to be the case. See Böhm-BawerkRechte und Verhaeltnisse vom gueterwirtschaftlichen Standpunkt in Gesammelte Schriften (Frankfurt/M.: Sauer & Auvermann, 1968).
    • In Gesammelte Schriften (Frankfurt/M.: Sauer & Auvermann, 1968).
  • 72
    • 53349091968 scopus 로고
    • Bank Runs in the Free Banking Period
    • Or, in the terms of A. J. Rolnick and W. E. Weber: "free bank failures were not caused by individuals establishing free banks with the same intention of having them fail. Rather, free banks failed when economic times turned bad and the value of their portfolio declined. Thus, the problems of banks during this period do not appear to have been different from those encountered by banks in other periods or by other types of industries" ("The Causes of Free Bank Failures,*Journal of Monetary Economics 14 (1984): p. 290. See also Glasner, Free Banking and Monetary Reform, p. 203; Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, pp. 218f; Horwitz, Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 152ff).
    • Hasan Ifedhar and Gerald P. Dwyer Jr.Bank Runs in the Free Banking Period Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 26 (1994): 284. Or, in the terms of A. J. Rolnick and W. E. Weber: "free bank failures were not caused by individuals establishing free banks with the same intention of having them fail. Rather, free banks failed when economic times turned bad and the value of their portfolio declined. Thus, the problems of banks during this period do not appear to have been different from those encountered by banks in other periods or by other types of industries" ("The Causes of Free Bank Failures,*Journal of Monetary Economics 14 (1984): p. 290. See also Glasner, Free Banking and Monetary Reform, p. 203; Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, pp. 218f; Horwitz, Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 152ff).
    • (1994) Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking , vol.26 , pp. 284
    • Ifedhar, H.1    Dwyer Jr., G.P.2
  • 74
    • 53349101565 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Dowd, The State and the Monetary System, p. 62. See also the references given above in the section entitled "Does Fractional Reserve Banking Lead to Monetary Equilibrium."
  • 77
    • 53349173760 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is unlimited without regard to the prevailing money prices on the market. The latter, however, rise every time the quantity of fiduciary money substitutes is enhanced. They must necessarily be higher than they otherwise would have been. The circumstance, too, leads to higher demands for holding money.
  • 80
    • 53349141538 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., p. 1726. They note that only three out of six major panics in the National Banking era involved suspensions of payments.
    • Ibid., p. 1726. They note that only three out of six major panics in the National Banking era involved suspensions of payments.
  • 81
    • 0008390939 scopus 로고
    • The Myth of Free Banking in Scotland
    • See Murray N. RothbardThe Myth of Free Banking in Scotland Review of Austrian Economics 2 (1987): 229-45,
    • (1987) Review of Austrian Economics , vol.2 , pp. 229-245
    • Rothbard, M.N.1
  • 87
    • 53349145968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, p. 48.
    • Cf. Dowd, Laissez-faire Banking, p. 48.
  • 89
    • 53349099454 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For a refutation of this claim of the free bankers see Hans-Hermann HoppeHow is Fiat Money Possible?": 70f.
    • For a refutation of this claim of the free bankers see Hans-Hermann HoppeHow is Fiat Money Possible?": 70f.
  • 91
    • 53349120551 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • On this point see Hoppe, The Economics and Ethics of Private Property, p. 14.
    • On this point see Hoppe, The Economics and Ethics of Private Property, p. 14.
  • 92
    • 53349160529 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Selgin and WhiteHow Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?": 1732f.
    • Cf. Selgin and WhiteHow Would the Invisible Hand Handle Money?": 1732f.
  • 93
    • 53349156911 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the following see the third part of my Logik der Währungskonkurrenz, forthcoming from Frankfurt/M: R. G. Fischer, 1996.
    • For the following see the third part of my Logik der Währungskonkurrenz, forthcoming from Frankfurt/M: R. G. Fischer, 1996.
  • 94
    • 53349151328 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See Ludwig von Mises, Theorie des Geldes und der Urnlaufsrnittel, 2nd ed. (Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1924), pp. 85ff
    • See Ludwig von Mises, Theorie des Geldes und der Urnlaufsrnittel, 2nd ed. (Munich and Leipzig: Duncker & Humblot, 1924), pp. 85ff,
  • 95
    • 53349175062 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • also published in English as The Theory of Money and Credit, H. E. Batson, trans. (London: Jonathan Cape, 1934); idem, Human Action, pp. 408ff.
    • also published in English as The Theory of Money and Credit, H. E. Batson, trans. (London: Jonathan Cape, 1934); idem, Human Action, pp. 408ff.
  • 96
    • 53349089916 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • What Do We Know about Currency Competition?
    • note
    • In his Denationalization of Money, 2nd ed.CLondon: Institute for Economic Affairs, 1978) Hayek simply skips the problem that the Ducates, which he wantsto introduce by a redemption promise, can only become money if this promise is broken. In fact Hayek's Ducates are money substitutes and not money. Otherwise they could never be issued. White holds the same misconception. See also White, Competition and Currency, p. 132. For a critique of Hayek's ideas on the introduction of moneys, see Martin HellwigWhat Do We Know About Currency Competition? in Zeitschrift fur Wirtschafts Sozialwissenschaften, 105, pp. 565ff.
    • In Zeitschrift fur Wirtschafts Sozialwissenschaften, 105, Pp. 565ff.
  • 97
    • 53349145969 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The selection of media of exchange of our hitherto non-monetary commodities. See for this mechanism Carl Menger, Money, in Collected Works, Vol. 4, P. A. Hayek, ed. (1933-36; London: London School of Economics, 1970), esp. chap. 8, sec, 1.
  • 98
    • 84928223179 scopus 로고
    • Spring Mills, Penn.: Libertarian Press
    • Hans F. Sennholz, Money and Freedom (Spring Mills, Penn.: Libertarian Press, 1985), p. 67.
    • (1985) Money and Freedom , pp. 67
    • Sennholz, H.F.1
  • 99
    • 53349101564 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • It is futile to cite the German hyperinflation of 1923 as indicating "that inflation can reach mindboggling proportions before alternative currencies can gain a foothold (White, Competition and Currency, p. 132). For anyone acquainted with theGerman mentality of this time it is rather "mindboggling" that even blind trust in authority and heavy penalties could not prevent the use of all sorts of other moneys.
  • 101
    • 53349127799 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Cf. Dowd, The State and the Monetary System, p. 185ff; White, Competition and Currency, p. 91ff.
    • Cf. Dowd, The State and the Monetary System, p. 185ff; White, Competition and Currency, p. 91ff.
  • 102
    • 53349175060 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For the distinction between economical and political means see Franz Oppenheimer, The State (New York: B. W. Heubsch, 1914), pp. 24ff.
    • For the distinction between economical and political means see Franz Oppenheimer, The State (New York: B. W. Heubsch, 1914), pp. 24ff.
  • 103
    • 53349089917 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • For the same reason there can be made no vital distinction between rules and discretion as principles of the conduct of monetary affairs. Every rule prescribing ex ante how much money has to be issued at what times and in what places and circumstance is discretionary by the very fact that it has to be set up by someone. A rule specifying, e.g., different behaviors of central bank officials according to different circumstances cannot even be said to be more "stabilizing" than any pure discretion on their side. It is therefore that rules vs. discretion is a false dichotomy, not because fractional reserve banking has been overlooked as a third alternative (as suggested by Horwitz, cf. Monetary Evolution, Free Banking, and Economic Order, p. 125f.
  • 104
    • 53349101563 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • "[T]he choice ought not to be foreclosed by anticompetitive policies" (White, Competition and Currency, p. 162). Unfortunately this attitude is not limited to the ranks of the free bankers. See also Sennholz who seeks "merely freedom" (Money and Freedom, p. 77).
  • 109
    • 53349160528 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • For plans to attain free banking on a 100 percent gold standard see Mises
    • For plans to attain free banking on a 100 percent gold standard see Mises, The Theory of Money and Credit, pp. 485ff
    • The Theory of Money and Credit


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.