메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn , Issue 1, 1996, Pages 1-48

The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0003176637     PISSN: 00072303     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.2307/2534646     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (572)

References (43)
  • 2
    • 0348125495 scopus 로고
    • Tobin (1972, p. 11); Samuelson and Solow (1960, p. 182); Schultze (1959, p. 134).
    • (1972) , pp. 11
    • Tobin1
  • 3
    • 0347495513 scopus 로고
    • Tobin (1972, p. 11); Samuelson and Solow (1960, p. 182); Schultze (1959, p. 134).
    • (1960) , pp. 182
    • Samuelson1    Solow2
  • 4
    • 0346864953 scopus 로고
    • Tobin (1972, p. 11); Samuelson and Solow (1960, p. 182); Schultze (1959, p. 134).
    • (1959) , pp. 134
    • Schultze1
  • 5
    • 0347495512 scopus 로고
    • Bewley and Brainard (1993); Bewley (1994).
    • (1993)
    • Bewley1    Brainard2
  • 6
    • 0346234573 scopus 로고
    • Bewley and Brainard (1993); Bewley (1994).
    • (1994)
    • Bewley1
  • 7
    • 0346234571 scopus 로고
    • questions 4A and 4B
    • Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1986, p. 731, questions 4A and 4B).
    • (1986) , pp. 731
    • Kahneman1    Knetsch2    Thaler3
  • 10
    • 0346234572 scopus 로고
    • Personal communication from Pierre Fortin, University of Quebec at Montreal, August 13
    • Personal communication from Pierre Fortin, University of Quebec at Montreal, August 13, 1995.
    • (1995)
  • 11
    • 0348125493 scopus 로고
    • Mitchell (1985); O'Brien (1989); Hanes (1993, 1996).
    • (1985)
    • Mitchell1
  • 12
    • 0347495509 scopus 로고
    • Mitchell (1985); O'Brien (1989); Hanes (1993, 1996).
    • (1989)
    • O'Brien1
  • 13
    • 0348125488 scopus 로고
    • Mitchell (1985); O'Brien (1989); Hanes (1993, 1996).
    • (1993)
    • Hanes1
  • 14
    • 0346864948 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Card and Hyslop (1996); Lebow, Stockton, and Wascher (1995); Kahn (1995); McLaughlin (1994).
    • (1996)
    • Card1    Hyslop2
  • 15
    • 0346864949 scopus 로고
    • Card and Hyslop (1996); Lebow, Stockton, and Wascher (1995); Kahn (1995); McLaughlin (1994).
    • (1995)
    • Lebow1    Stockton2    Wascher3
  • 16
    • 0347495508 scopus 로고
    • Card and Hyslop (1996); Lebow, Stockton, and Wascher (1995); Kahn (1995); McLaughlin (1994).
    • (1995)
    • Kahn1
  • 17
    • 0346234566 scopus 로고
    • Card and Hyslop (1996); Lebow, Stockton, and Wascher (1995); Kahn (1995); McLaughlin (1994).
    • (1994)
    • McLaughlin1
  • 18
    • 0346864944 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • McLaughlin presents corrected measures of the standard deviation of wage changes, and then infers the impact of the correction for the frequency of negative wage changes, using the empirical distribution of wage changes in the PSID. However, this is inappropriate if the underlying true distribution is asymmetric, as the distribution of wage changes appears to be. For example, suppose that the true distribution of wage changes contained no negative values. If a normal measurement error was added to the true values, a large number of false negative wage changes would be recorded. Simply reducing the variance of the empirical distribution by a mean-preserving reduction in the spread equal to the variance of the measurement error, as McLaughlin does, will reduce the frequency of false negatives but will not eliminate them. It is impossible to reconstruct the true underlying distribution in this fashion. Kahn recognizes the presence of errors but does not attempt to correct for them because doing so would only strengthen her conclusions about the presence of downward rigidity.
  • 19
    • 0347495500 scopus 로고
    • n. 6
    • Mellow and Sider (1983, p. 335, n. 6) report that "the estimated variance of the difference in log wage is 0.167." Our calculations, based on regression estimates that they present, suggest approximately this figure for the standard deviation.
    • (1983) , pp. 335
    • Mellow1    Sider2
  • 20
    • 0347495501 scopus 로고
    • A validation survey for the PSID shows large errors in reported income, but since the plant chosen for the survey did not pay straight time wages, the accuracy of the PSID question on hourly earnings cannot be assessed (see Duncan and Hill, 1985).
    • (1985)
    • Duncan1    Hill2
  • 21
    • 0347495507 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Shea (1996).
    • (1996)
    • Shea1
  • 22
    • 0346234552 scopus 로고
    • table 2
    • Kahn (1995, table 2, p. 17).
    • (1995) , pp. 17
    • Kahn1
  • 23
    • 0346864941 scopus 로고
    • table 2
    • Kahn (1995, table 2, p. 17).
    • (1995) , pp. 17
    • Kahn1
  • 24
    • 0346864933 scopus 로고
    • Michigan State University, East Lansing, Mich., April 20, and Holzer
    • Personal communication from Harry J. Holzer, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Mich., April 20, 1995, and Holzer (1996).
    • (1995)
    • Holzer, H.J.1
  • 25
    • 0346234486 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • This is the fraction of job stayers with one to two years of tenure that reports lower wages in 1992 than in 1991
    • This is the fraction of job stayers with one to two years of tenure that reports lower wages in 1992 than in 1991.
  • 26
    • 0347495502 scopus 로고
    • Hall (1988); Bils (1987).
    • (1988)
    • Hall1
  • 27
    • 0348125483 scopus 로고
    • Hall (1988); Bils (1987).
    • (1987)
    • Bils1
  • 28
    • 0347495499 scopus 로고
    • Leonard (1987); Davis, Haltiwanger, and Schuh (1996).
    • (1987)
    • Leonard1
  • 30
    • 0346864942 scopus 로고
    • McLaughlin (1994) presents several estimates of the standard deviation of percentage real wage growth across individuals who stay on the same job. These estimates are corrected for measurement error, and none is less than 9.5 percentage points.
    • (1994)
    • McLaughlin1
  • 31
    • 0348125484 scopus 로고
    • See Dickens (1994) for a discussion of the theoretical and empirical evidence on whether labor demand responds to negotiated changes in wages; and Dickens (1986) for a discussion of the employment effects of wage changes in firms where bargaining is implicit or the threat of collective action forces them to pay higher wages.
    • (1994)
    • Dickens1
  • 32
    • 0347495498 scopus 로고
    • See Dickens (1994) for a discussion of the theoretical and empirical evidence on whether labor demand responds to negotiated changes in wages; and Dickens (1986) for a discussion of the employment effects of wage changes in firms where bargaining is implicit or the threat of collective action forces them to pay higher wages.
    • (1986)
    • Dickens1
  • 33
    • 0347495493 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • t, and that s, the value of leisure, is also proportional to labor productivity.
  • 34
    • 0346234557 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • w - the wage will be given by the bargaining equation (equation 3).
  • 35
    • 0346864935 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We assume that s and profits rise with productivity, and therefore, productivity affects the notional real wage in a multiplicative fashion.
  • 36
    • 0347495405 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As long as s, the value of leisure, is less than the real wage, (β - 1)/β, SS will slope upward
    • As long as s, the value of leisure, is less than the real wage, (β - 1)/β, SS will slope upward.
  • 37
    • 0347495487 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The churning of employment between firms is a mechanism by which nominal rigidity is overcome in the economy, and by embodying this feature we capture this mechanism in the simulation. Constrained firms will tend to shrink, and workers who lose employment at high wage constrained firms may find reemployment at low wage unconstrained firms.
  • 38
    • 0346864934 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • We checked a number of these cases to be sure that the failure to find acceptable parameter values for so many cases is due to their nonexistence and does not represent a failure of our search algorithm. Doing a grid search by hand, we were unable to find values of our instrumental parameters that allowed our simulation to hit the three calibration targets. The failure is due to the wide range of values that we allow the randomly chosen parameters to take. In experiments where the ranges are sharply restricted, the search algorithm is able to calibrate the simulation in the majority of cases.
  • 39
    • 0346234556 scopus 로고
    • Gordon (1994).
    • (1994)
    • Gordon1
  • 40
    • 0347495492 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Our treatment of productivity growth, oil shocks, and wage and price controls is explained in appendix A.
  • 41
    • 0346234555 scopus 로고
    • Schultze (1981); Gordon (1981).
    • (1981)
    • Schultze1
  • 42
    • 0347495491 scopus 로고
    • Schultze (1981); Gordon (1981).
    • (1981)
    • Gordon1
  • 43
    • 0348125480 scopus 로고
    • series
    • U.S. Department of Commerce (1966, series B72, pp. 202-03, and series A164, pp. 190-91).
    • (1966) , vol.B72 , pp. 202-203


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.