메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 5, Issue 4, 1996, Pages 7-42

American foreign policy and the fungibility of force

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0002500554     PISSN: 09636412     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1080/09636419608429287     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (55)

References (79)
  • 1
    • 85033048381 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • There are many definitions of grand strategy. The one I use here is this: grand strategy posits the foreign policy goals for a state and prescribes how military power can best be used to attain them. As used in this article, grand strategy is therefore about the proper relation of the military instrument to a nation's external goals.
  • 2
    • 26644464459 scopus 로고
    • The Role of Military Power in International Relations
    • ed. B. Thomas Trout and James E. Harf New Brunswick: Transaction
    • I have developed this distinction more fully in Robert J. Art, "The Role of Military Power in International Relations," in National Security Affairs: Theoretical Perspectives and Contemporary Issues, ed. B. Thomas Trout and James E. Harf (New Brunswick: Transaction, 1982), 18-27.
    • (1982) National Security Affairs: Theoretical Perspectives and Contemporary Issues , pp. 18-27
    • Art, R.J.1
  • 3
    • 0004205937 scopus 로고
    • Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company
    • Kenneth N. Waltz, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, 1979), 114. Waltz quotes E. R. Livernash (p. 114) as follows: "The few strikes that take place are in a sense the cost of the strike option which produces settlements in the large mass of negotiations."
    • (1979) Theory of International Politics , pp. 114
    • Waltz, K.N.1
  • 4
    • 0004077660 scopus 로고
    • New York: Augustus M. Kelly, esp. chaps. 5 and 6
    • For further discussion of the effects of catastrophic breakdown in oligopolistic situations, another permissive realm, see William Fellner, Competition Among the Few: Oligopoly and Similar Market Structures (New York: Augustus M. Kelly, 1965), esp. chaps. 5 and 6.
    • (1965) Competition among the Few: Oligopoly and Similar Market Structures
    • Fellner, W.1
  • 9
    • 26644442219 scopus 로고
    • Ph.D. diss., Brandeis University
    • and Christopher T. Kirkey, "The Canadian-American Bargaining Relationship in the North: Explaining Interstate Bargaining Outcomes" (Ph.D. diss., Brandeis University, 1994). In the first study, Keohane accounted for the differences in how the international regimes for trade, finance, and oil changed from 1966-77 by looking at the differences in the specific power assets that the United States wielded in each area. It was the United States that had created and sustained each regime, but as the decline in its power became tangible during the 1966-77 decade, the nature of the rules and behavior of states in each issue area changed. Keohane argues that American power declined at different rates in each area, with different consequences for the international rules and behavior of each regime. In the second study, Keohane and Nye sought to test systematically the situationally specific nature of power by looking at the relations among the United States and its industrial allies during the cold war. Keohane and Nye argued that military power was not used by these governments against one another (since they were allies); therefore, that military power was of minor importance in their relations with each other, and, by implication, that it had little fungibility in this particular case. As a consequence, outcomes in specific issue areas among these states were more a function of the relative distribution of power resources specific to each given issue area. In the third study, Kirkey found that Canadian-American relations on a range of issues were best explained by the domain-specific analysis of power. Although stronger in most domains, the United States chose not to use its strength in those domains to compensate for its weakness in others. The norm of not linking domains obtained in U.S.-Canadian relations thereby made outcomes more domain-specific than they otherwise might have been. Kirkey's analysis suggests that this outcome was a matter of American choice, not necessity.
    • (1994) The Canadian-American Bargaining Relationship in the North: Explaining Interstate Bargaining Outcomes
    • Kirkey, C.T.1
  • 10
    • 0003959434 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 8
    • Two sensible discussions of a state's power assets can be found in Carr, Twenty Years' Crisis, chap. 8;
    • Twenty Years' Crisis
    • Carr1
  • 14
    • 85033044782 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca: Cornell University Press, forthcoming
    • Exactly where this point is, is difficult to define. One could argue that more military power is reasonable up until the point where other states begin to worry and take counteractions. One could argue that more amounts of offensive power will worry other states more quickly than more amounts of defensive power. One could furthermore argue that the point where reasonable becomes unreasonable is more dependent on the perceived intentions of the state than on its military capability. These are all "reasonable" points. In this article, I cannot settle the debate between "aggressive" and "defensive" realists, nor can I show how to distinguish between offense and defense dominant worlds. (On this point, see Stephen Van Evera, The Causes of War, vol. 1 [Ithaca: Cornell University Press, forthcoming].) More military power will buy a state more options if other states either do not counter the powerful state, or are unable to keep up with its pace of arming. Offensive military power is more threatening than defensive military power (if the two can be distinguished) and probably more fungible. Defensive military power therefore has less fungibility than offensive power, unless, of course, a militarily powerful state decides to spread its defensive power over another state. I contest none of these points. What I do maintain, however, is that the military instrument possesses more fungibility for the military powerful state than for the militarily weak one. In this regard, the fungibility of force argument applies most particularly to the great powers and especially to the American superpower.
    • The Causes of War , vol.1
    • Van Evera, S.1
  • 15
    • 0004151660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • New York: Blackwell
    • David Baldwin, Paradoxes of Power (New York: Blackwell, 1989), 151-52.
    • (1989) Paradoxes of Power , pp. 151-152
    • Baldwin, D.1
  • 16
    • 84971870851 scopus 로고
    • Power Analysis and World Politics
    • January
    • Baldwin first developed his argument in his "Power Analysis and World Politics," World Politics 31, no. 1 (January 1979): 161-94, which is reprinted in this volume of his previously published essays.
    • (1979) World Politics , vol.31 , Issue.1 , pp. 161-194
    • Baldwin1
  • 17
  • 18
    • 0004151660 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • In fairness to Baldwin, these examples were not fully developed, but consist of only a sentence or two. Nevertheless, they are fair game because Baldwin used them as illustrations of his more general point about the limits to the utility of military power. The fact that he did not develop them further led him astray, in my view. He was trying to show with them that military power is less effective than commonly thought. I reinterpret these examples to show how versatile military power in fact is. Neither Baldwin nor I, however, can put a number on the fungibility of military power, and I certainly agree with him that "no political power resource begins to approach the degree of fungibility of money" (quoted in Baldwin, Paradoxes of Power, 135).
    • Paradoxes of Power , pp. 135
    • Baldwin1
  • 25
    • 67849087465 scopus 로고
    • col. 3
    • Among the things considered to secure the crew's release was the threat of seizing costly fish-processing ships that were being built in the Netherlands for North Korea. See New York Times Index, 1968, 735 (col. 3).
    • (1968) New York Times Index , pp. 735
  • 28
    • 0004193947 scopus 로고
    • Princeton: Princeton University Press
    • Baldwin, of course, agrees with this point. He has written: "Actually, any technique of statecraft works poorly in isolation from the others." See David A. Baldwin, Economic Statecraft (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1985), 143.
    • (1985) Economic Statecraft , pp. 143
    • Baldwin, D.A.1
  • 29
    • 0003534030 scopus 로고
    • Stanford: Stanford University Press
    • I have borrowed this term from Ernst Haas, even though I am using it differently than he does. He used the phrase to describe the effects that cooperation on economic matters among the states of Western Europe could have on their political relations. He argued that cooperation on economic matters would spill over into their political relations, induce greater cooperation there, and lead ultimately to the political integration of Western Europe. See Ernst Haas, Beyond the Nation State: Functionalism and International Organization (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1964), 48.
    • (1964) Beyond the Nation State: Functionalism and International Organization , pp. 48
    • Haas, E.1
  • 30
    • 0003477231 scopus 로고
    • Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California
    • For Haas's later assessment of how effective spill-over effects were, see Ernst Haas, The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory (Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California, 1974).
    • (1974) The Obsolescence of Regional Integration Theory
    • Haas, E.1
  • 31
    • 0003458968 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ithaca: Cornell University Press, esp. chap. 2
    • For a contrary argument, see Jonathan Mercer, Reputation and International Politics (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996), esp. chap. 2. Mercer argues that reputations of states do not carry over from one time to another, or from one set of events to another set.
    • (1996) Reputation and International Politics
    • Mercer, J.1
  • 32
    • 85033040051 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Solvency is to be distinguished from liquidity. A bank can be solvent but not liquid. Liquidity refers to the ability of a bank to meet all its liabilities upon demand. Most banks are not able to do so, however, if all the demands are called at the same time. The reason is that many assets of any given bank are tied up in investments that cannot be called back on short notice, but take time to convert into cash. The function of a central bank is to solve the liquidity problem of a nation's banking system by providing the liquidity in the short term in order to prevent runs on a bank.
  • 33
    • 38049025479 scopus 로고
    • A Defensible Defense: America's Grand Strategy after the Cold War
    • spring
    • I have shamelessly borrowed the next few pages from Robert J. Art, "A Defensible Defense: America's Grand Strategy After the Cold War," International Security 15, no. 4 (spring 1991): 33-35.
    • (1991) International Security , vol.15 , Issue.4 , pp. 33-35
    • Art, R.J.1
  • 35
    • 0003721977 scopus 로고
    • The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations
    • ed. Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye Jr. Cambridge: Harvard University Press
    • Also see Robert Gilpin, "The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations," in Transnational Relations and World Politics, ed. Robert O. Keohane and Joseph S. Nye Jr. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1972), 48-69;
    • (1972) Transnational Relations and World Politics , pp. 48-69
    • Gilpin, R.1
  • 36
    • 0001943603 scopus 로고
    • Back to the Future: Instability in Europe after the Cold War
    • summer
    • and John J. Mearsheimer, "Back to the Future: Instability in Europe After the Cold War," International Security 15, no. 1 (summer 1991): 42-48.
    • (1991) International Security , vol.15 , Issue.1 , pp. 42-48
    • Mearsheimer, J.J.1
  • 37
    • 84935322435 scopus 로고
    • Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade
    • December
    • For arguments that a bipolar international system is more conducive to fostering freer trade among states than a multipolar one, see Joanne Gowa, "Bipolarity, Multipolarity, and Free Trade," American Political Science Review 83, no. 4 (December 1989): 1245-57;
    • (1989) American Political Science Review , vol.83 , Issue.4 , pp. 1245-1257
    • Gowa, J.1
  • 39
    • 0001697225 scopus 로고
    • Global Transactions and the Consolidation of Sovereignty
    • ed. Ernst-Otto Czempiel and James N. Rosenau Lexington: Lexington
    • Stephen Krasner and Janice Thompson argue that "the more stable the pattern of property rights the higher the level of economic transactions." See Stephen D. Krasner and Janice E. Thomson, "Global Transactions and the Consolidation of Sovereignty," in Global Changes and Theoretical Challenge, ed. Ernst-Otto Czempiel and James N. Rosenau (Lexington: Lexington, 1989), 198.
    • (1989) Global Changes and Theoretical Challenge , pp. 198
    • Krasner, S.D.1    Thomson, J.E.2
  • 40
    • 0007672415 scopus 로고
    • Chicago: University of Chicago Press, chap. 2
    • As Robert Osgood was among the first to point out that in its initial phase, before the Korean War brought a large contingent of American troops to Europe, the function of NATO was broadly psychological, not strictly military. The goal was not to balance the Soviets military power on the continent, but to convince the Europeans that the Americans would not abandon them. For this task, the signing of a military alliance alone would be sufficient. See Robert E. Osgood, NATO - The Entangling Alliance (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962), chap. 2.
    • (1962) NATO - The Entangling Alliance
    • Osgood, R.E.1
  • 41
    • 0040172812 scopus 로고
    • Westport Greenwood
    • These concerns were never far below the surface. For how they affected the very form NATO took, see Timothy P. Ireland, Creating the Entangling Alliance (Westport Greenwood, 1981).
    • (1981) Creating the Entangling Alliance
    • Ireland, T.P.1
  • 42
    • 84906594639 scopus 로고
    • Europe's American Pacifier
    • spring
    • For more on the dual function that NATO has served - to deter the Soviets and to sit on the Germans, See Josef Joffe, "Europe's American Pacifier," Foreign Policy, no. 54 (spring 1984): 64-82.
    • (1984) Foreign Policy , Issue.54 , pp. 64-82
    • Joffe, J.1
  • 44
    • 0000805672 scopus 로고
    • Guns, Butter, and Anarchy
    • March
    • See also Robert Powell, "Guns, Butter, and Anarchy," American Political Science Review 87, no. 1 (March 1993): 115-32;
    • (1993) American Political Science Review , vol.87 , Issue.1 , pp. 115-132
    • Powell, R.1
  • 45
    • 0040559435 scopus 로고
    • Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation
    • fall
    • and Joseph Grieco, "Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation," International Organization 42, no. 3 (fall 1988): 167-88.
    • (1988) International Organization , vol.42 , Issue.3 , pp. 167-188
    • Grieco, J.1
  • 46
    • 0004130918 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Robert Keohane puts it: "...functional linkages exist between issue areas, and bargaining linkages are often drawn by policymakers between issue areas that are not functionally linked." See Keohane, International Institutions and State Power, 95.
    • International Institutions and State Power , pp. 95
    • Keohane1
  • 49
    • 0004311447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Boston: Little, Brown, chaps. 16, 19, and 20
    • Henry Kissinger, Years of Upheaval (Boston: Little, Brown, 1982), chaps. 16, 19, and 20;
    • (1982) Years of Upheaval
    • Kissinger, H.1
  • 58
    • 0004311447 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Nixon also expressed these views publicly about a month later at a question-and-answer session at the Executives' Club of Chicago. There on 15 March he said: "Now the Europeans cannot have it both ways. They cannot have the United States participation and cooperation on the security front and then proceed to have confrontation and even hostility on the economic and political front" Quoted in Kissinger, Years of Upheaval, ibid., 932.
    • Years of Upheaval , pp. 932
    • Kissinger1
  • 62
    • 0004027370 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Robert Keohane argues that the IEA achieved some success in coping with the October 1980 oil price rise that was induced by the Iran-Iraq War. I find his evidence thin and think most of the subsequent decline in prices can easily be accounted for by three other factors he mentions: "high levels of stocks [of oil], general weakness in demand, and the willingness of Saudi Arabia to increase production..." (See Keohane, After Hegemony, 231-37.) If we look at the record of oil prices from early 1981 until late 1990, the importance of these factors becomes even more apparent. Oil prices initially fell in the 1980s as a consequence of a global recession, greater energy efficiency by the major oil consumers induced by higher costs for oil, and by the bringing on line of large, more costly-to-produce, non-OPEC supplies that the 1970s price rises made feasible. The experience of the 1980s reinforces the conclusion about October 1980: it was the supply/demand balance (or imbalance), the availability of non-OPEC oil, and the willingness of Saudi Arabia to serve as the swing producer of last resort (increasing or cutting its oil production in order to even out the market swings in pricing) that dominate any putative oil consumer cooperation in the IAE. Such cooperation may have taken place, but it was of marginal importance.
    • After Hegemony , pp. 231-237
    • Keohane1
  • 63
    • 0002445518 scopus 로고
    • OPEC as a Cartel
    • ed. James M. Griffin and David J. Teece London: Allen & Unwin
    • For a useful survey of OPEC, see M. A. Adelman, "OPEC as a Cartel," in OPEC Behavior and World Oil Prices, ed. James M. Griffin and David J. Teece (London: Allen & Unwin, 1982), 37-63.
    • (1982) OPEC Behavior and World Oil Prices , pp. 37-63
    • Adelman, M.A.1
  • 66
    • 0003683129 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • As Gilpin put it: "Partially for economic reasons, but more importantly for political and strategic ones, Western Europe (primarily West Germany) and Japan agreed to finance the American balance of payments deficit." See Gilpin, U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation, 154.
    • U.S. Power and the Multinational Corporation , pp. 154
    • Gilpin1
  • 67
    • 85033059267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chap. 4
    • For this example, I have relied exclusively on David Spiro's original and thorough research. See Spiro, Hegemony Unbound, chap. 4.
    • Hegemony Unbound
    • Spiro1
  • 68
    • 85033059267 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • The quote is from an interview conducted by Spiro in Boston in 1984 with a former American ambassador to the Middle East. See Spiro, Hegemony Unbound, 271. (All page references are for the manuscript version.)
    • Hegemony Unbound , pp. 271
    • Spiro1
  • 76
    • 0003911010 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • chaps. 4 and 11
    • For a comprehensive assessment of the political use of American military power in 215 incidents between 1946 and 1975, see Blechman and Kaplan, Force Without War, chaps. 4 and 11.
    • Force Without War
    • Blechman1    Kaplan2
  • 78
    • 85033064541 scopus 로고
    • Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics
    • In the most exhaustive study of economic sanctions done to date, for example, Haufbauer, Schott, and Elliott found that when the goal of sanctions was to destabilize a government, "...economic sanctions unassisted by companion measures [such as covert actions and quasi-military operations] seldom achieve destabilization." See Gary Clyde Hufbauer, Jeffrey J. Schott, and Kimberly Ann Elliott, Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd ed. (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1990), vol. 1, 51.
    • (1990) Economic Sanctions Reconsidered: History and Current Policy, 2nd Ed. , vol.1 , pp. 51
    • Hufbauer, G.C.1    Schott, J.J.2    Elliott, K.A.3
  • 79
    • 85029988565 scopus 로고
    • Japan Tells U.S. It Will Not Join Embargo on Iran
    • 10 June
    • David E. Sanger, "Japan Tells U.S. It Will Not Join Embargo On Iran," New York Times, 10 June 1995, A4.
    • (1995) New York Times
    • Sanger, D.E.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.