메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 38, Issue 4, 1978, Pages 918-937

The Household Balance Sheet and the Great Depression

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0001464773     PISSN: 00220507     EISSN: 14716372     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1017/S0022050700087167     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (167)

References (56)
  • 2
    • 84916018912 scopus 로고
    • A Reappraisal of Some Factors Associated with Fluctuations in the United States in the Interwar Period
    • See, Jan.
    • See Ben Bolch and John Pilgrim, “A Reappraisal of Some Factors Associated with Fluctuations in the United States in the Interwar Period,” Southern Economic Journal, 39 (Jan. 1973), 327-44;
    • (1973) Southern Economic Journal , vol.39 , pp. 327-344
    • Bolch, B.1    Pilgrim, J.2
  • 6
    • 84972169085 scopus 로고
    • The Great Depression: A Structural Analysis
    • Nov.
    • John B. Kirkwood, “The Great Depression: A Structural Analysis,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 4 (Nov. 1972), 811-37.
    • (1972) Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol.4 , pp. 811-837
    • Kirkwood, J.B.1
  • 7
    • 0000107944 scopus 로고
    • The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions
    • Oct., and
    • Both Irving Fisher, “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions,” Econometrica, 1 (Oct. 1933), 337-57, and
    • (1933) Econometrica , vol.1 , pp. 337-357
    • Fisher, B.I.1
  • 8
    • 0003678208 scopus 로고
    • London, promote the view that the deflation did affect aggregate demand and that it is one explanation for the seriousness of the contraction
    • Charles P. Kindleberger, The World in Depression 1929-39 (London, 1973), promote the view that the deflation did affect aggregate demand and that it is one explanation for the seriousness of the contraction.
    • (1973) The World in Depression 1929-39
    • Kindleberger, C.P.1
  • 9
    • 0003118448 scopus 로고
    • The Life-Cycle' Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests
    • Mar., and
    • Albert Ando and Franco Modigliani, “The Life-Cycle' Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests,” American Economic Review, 53 (Mar. 1963), 55-84, and
    • (1963) American Economic Review , vol.53 , pp. 55-84
    • Ando, A.1    Modigliani, F.2
  • 10
    • 0001023688 scopus 로고
    • Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure, and Monetary Policy
    • Sept.
    • Frederic S. Mishkin, “Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure, and Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review, 66 (Sept. 1976), 642-54.
    • (1976) American Economic Review , vol.66 , pp. 642-654
    • Mishkin, F.S.1
  • 12
    • 84974477271 scopus 로고
    • Demand for Consumer Installment Credit and Its Effects on Consumption
    • Models of the demand for household liabilities either are set in a nominal framework, in James Duesenberry, Gary Fromm, Lawrence Klein and Edwin Kuh, eds., New York, or have an adjustment mechanism that views the change in liabilities as a function of real variables
    • Models of the demand for household liabilities either are set in a nominal framework [Michael K. Evans and Avram Kisselgoff, “Demand for Consumer Installment Credit and Its Effects on Consumption,” in James Duesenberry, Gary Fromm, Lawrence Klein and Edwin Kuh, eds., The Brookings Model:. Some Further Results (New York, 1969)] or have an adjustment mechanism that views the change in liabilities as a function of real variables
    • (1969) The Brookings Model:. Some Further Results
    • Evans, M.K.1    Kisselgoff, A.2
  • 13
    • 84916449680 scopus 로고
    • Household Liabilities and the Generalized Stock-Adjustment Model
    • Nov., and
    • [Frederic S. Mishkin, “Household Liabilities and the Generalized Stock-Adjustment Model,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 58 (Nov. 1976), 481-85 and
    • (1976) Review of Economics and Statistics , vol.58 , pp. 481-485
    • Mishkin, F.S.1
  • 14
    • 84914457052 scopus 로고
    • Household Demand for Assets: A Model of Short-Run Adjustments
    • Aug., These models have the characteristics that a severe deflation will cause an increase in the real value of household liabilities in the short run, even if the consumers' desired levels of liabilities in real terms have fallen. The desired drop in real liabilities thus may not occur for several years, as was the case during the Great Depression
    • Brian Motley, “Household Demand for Assets: A Model of Short-Run Adjustments,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 52, (Aug. 1970), 236-41]. These models have the characteristics that a severe deflation will cause an increase in the real value of household liabilities in the short run, even if the consumers' desired levels of liabilities in real terms have fallen. The desired drop in real liabilities thus may not occur for several years, as was the case during the Great Depression.
    • (1970) Review of Economics and Statistics , vol.52 , pp. 236-41]
    • Motley, B.1
  • 15
    • 0001820698 scopus 로고
    • What Depressed the Consumer? The Household Balance-Sheet in the 1973-75 Recession
    • The impact of household balance-sheet shifts on aggregate demand during the 1973-1975 recession is analyzed in, Household balance-sheet changes during this period do appear to have been an important factor promoting the severity of the 1973-75 recession, as seems to have been the case during the Great Depression
    • The impact of household balance-sheet shifts on aggregate demand during the 1973-1975 recession is analyzed in Frederic S. Mishkin, “What Depressed the Consumer? The Household Balance-Sheet in the 1973-75 Recession,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1977:1, pp. 123-64. Household balance-sheet changes during this period do appear to have been an important factor promoting the severity of the 1973-75 recession, as seems to have been the case during the Great Depression.
    • (1977) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.1 , pp. 123-164
    • Mishkin, F.S.1
  • 17
    • 84974323105 scopus 로고
    • The life-cycle models estimated in the current version of the MPS model (see, January, mimeo) and in Mishkin, “What Depressed….,” use different sample periods, different definitions of the wealth variable, and, in Mishkin, a different estimation technique. The overall wealth effect is still highly significant and does not deviate more than 10 percent from the.053 value
    • The life-cycle models estimated in the current version of the MPS model (see MIT-PENN-SSRC, Quarterly Econometric Model Equations, January 1975, mimeo) and in Mishkin, “What Depressed….,” use different sample periods, different definitions of the wealth variable, and, in Mishkin, a different estimation technique. The overall wealth effect is still highly significant and does not deviate more than 10 percent from the.053 value.
    • (1975) MIT-PENN-SSRC, Quarterly Econometric Model Equations
  • 18
    • 0001561044 scopus 로고
    • The Stock Market and the Economy
    • See, and Mishkin, “What Depressed….”
    • See Barry Bosworth, “The Stock Market and the Economy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1975:2, pp. 257-90 and Mishkin, “What Depressed….”
    • (1975) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.2 , pp. 257-290
    • Bosworth, B.1
  • 19
    • 84974512388 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • See, for the specifics of the formal analysis from which this discussion is derived. The liquidity-hypothesis model also allows for perceptions of risk-influencing expenditure behavior. This aspect of the hypothesis is not discussed here as it is not crucial to the analysis of this paper
    • See Mishkin, “Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure,…,” for the specifics of the formal analysis from which this discussion is derived. The liquidity-hypothesis model also allows for perceptions of risk-influencing expenditure behavior. This aspect of the hypothesis is not discussed here as it is not crucial to the analysis of this paper.
    • “Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure,…,”
    • Mishkin1
  • 20
    • 84974514005 scopus 로고
    • Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure
    • Ph.D. Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, published as Research Report 61, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, 1977; and
    • Mishkin, “Illiquidity, Consumer Durable Expenditure,” Frederic S. Mishkin, Illiquidity, the Demand for Consumer Durables and Monetary Policy, Ph.D. Thesis, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1976, published as Research Report 61, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, 1977; and
    • (1976) Frederic S. Mishkin, Illiquidity, the Demand for Consumer Durables and Monetary Policy
    • Mishkin1
  • 21
    • 84977318023 scopus 로고
    • Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing, and Monetary Policy
    • Dec.
    • J. R. Kearl and Frederic S. Mishkin, “Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing, and Monetary Policy ” Journal of Finance, 32 (Dec. 1977), 1571-86.
    • (1977) Journal of Finance , vol.32 , pp. 1571-1586
    • Kearl, J.R.1    Mishkin, F.S.2
  • 22
    • 84974513996 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • expenditure model uses houshold liabilities excluding mortgage debt as the DE BT variable because mortgage debt is not expected to influence the consumer's decision to purchase new housing. See Kearl and Mishkin, “Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing…,‘ for a discussion of this point
    • Kearl and Mishkin's expenditure model uses houshold liabilities excluding mortgage debt as the DE BT variable because mortgage debt is not expected to influence the consumer's decision to purchase new housing. See Kearl and Mishkin, “Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing…,‘ for a discussion of this point.
    • Kearl1    Mishkin's2
  • 24
    • 84974283509 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • “Illiquidity….”contain more detailed discussion of the estimated models above. The consumer expenditure model given here does not allow for a distributed lag on stock market asset holdings in the determination of the desired consumer durables stock, a feature of some of the estimated models in Mishkin, “Illiquidity….” The expenditure model given here is more useful than models with these lags for the calculations in the next section, as it has less complicated dynamic short-run balance-sheet effects
    • Mishkin, “Illiquidity….”contain more detailed discussion of the estimated models above. The consumer expenditure model given here does not allow for a distributed lag on stock market asset holdings in the determination of the desired consumer durables stock, a feature of some of the estimated models in Mishkin, “Illiquidity….” The expenditure model given here is more useful than models with these lags for the calculations in the next section, as it has less complicated dynamic short-run balance-sheet effects.
    • Mishkin1
  • 25
    • 84974266349 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • indicate that liquidity considerations might be important to consumers' desires for leased assets, such as multi-family housing, and find significant balance-sheet coefficients in multi-family housing equations. These coefficients, however, are not that robust when credit rationing variables are added as explanatory variables, and post-sample tracking of a multi-family housing equation with balance-sheet effects in Mishkin, “What Depressed…,” casts doubt on the existence of these effects for multi-family housing. Therefore, the multi-family housing equation with balance-sheet effects is not used for the analysis of the following section and is not reported on here
    • Kearl and Mishkin, “Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing…,” indicate that liquidity considerations might be important to consumers' desires for leased assets, such as multi-family housing, and find significant balance-sheet coefficients in multi-family housing equations. These coefficients, however, are not that robust when credit rationing variables are added as explanatory variables, and post-sample tracking of a multi-family housing equation with balance-sheet effects in Mishkin, “What Depressed…,” casts doubt on the existence of these effects for multi-family housing. Therefore, the multi-family housing equation with balance-sheet effects is not used for the analysis of the following section and is not reported on here.
    • “Illiquidity, the Demand for Residential Housing…,”
    • Kearl1    Mishkin2
  • 27
    • 84974333041 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Analyzing the impact of household balance-sheet changes on the business cycle by using the desirable methodology of dynamic simulation experiments with a macroeconomic model of the U.S. economy is possible with postwar, quarterly data
    • Analyzing the impact of household balance-sheet changes on the business cycle by using the desirable methodology of dynamic simulation experiments with a macroeconomic model of the U.S. economy is possible with postwar, quarterly data. Mishkin, “What Depressed has carried out this exercise”.
    • “What Depressed has carried out this exercise”
    • Mishkin1
  • 28
    • 84974342661 scopus 로고
    • Clearly, at least one group of consumers, the farm population, suffered severe financial distress during the Great Depression, Mar., Agricultural Economics Department, South Dakota State College, estimates that 29 percent of all farms in the United States underwent forced sales (foreclosures) in the decade 1930-1939
    • Clearly, at least one group of consumers, the farm population, suffered severe financial distress during the Great Depression. J. Munger, A Preliminary Study of Farmer Bankruptcy Experiences in the Dakotas 1928-1952, Agricultural Economics Pamphlet (Mar. 1955), Agricultural Economics Department, South Dakota State College, estimates that 29 percent of all farms in the United States underwent forced sales (foreclosures) in the decade 1930-1939.
    • (1955) A Preliminary Study of Farmer Bankruptcy Experiences in the Dakotas 1928-1952, Agricultural Economics Pamphlet
    • Munger, J.1
  • 29
    • 0007834638 scopus 로고
    • Housing Surplus in the 1920's?
    • See, Spring, Bolch and Pilgrim, “A Reappraisal…”; and
    • See Ben Bolch, Rendigs Fels and Marshall McMahon, “Housing Surplus in the 1920's?” Explorations in Economic History, 8 (Spring 1971), 259-83; Bolch and Pilgrim, “A Reappraisal…”; and
    • (1971) Explorations in Economic History , vol.8 , pp. 259-283
    • Ben Bolch, R.F.1    McMahon, M.2
  • 32
    • 49649155533 scopus 로고
    • Alternative Interpretations of Market Saturation: Evaluation for the Automobile Market in the Late Twenties
    • See, Spring
    • See Lloyd J. Mercer and W. Douglas Morgan, “Alternative Interpretations of Market Saturation: Evaluation for the Automobile Market in the Late Twenties,” Explorations in Economic History, 9 (Spring 1972), 269-90.
    • (1972) Explorations in Economic History , vol.9 , pp. 269-290
    • Mercer, L.J.1    Douglas Morgan, W.2
  • 34
    • 0012618168 scopus 로고
    • Fiscal Policies in the Thirties: A Reappraisal
    • The work of, Dec., indicates that government fiscal policy was not a primary factor in the collapse of aggregate demand during the Great Depression period, and thus fiscal policy is not cited as an important cause of the Depression
    • The work of E. Cary Brown, “Fiscal Policies in the Thirties: A Reappraisal,” American Economic Review, 46 (Dec. 1956), 857-79, indicates that government fiscal policy was not a primary factor in the collapse of aggregate demand during the Great Depression period, and thus fiscal policy is not cited as an important cause of the Depression.
    • (1956) American Economic Review , vol.46 , pp. 857-879
    • Cary Brown, E.1
  • 36
    • 84974357648 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • A Monetary History, mention the large decline in velocity in 1930, but are unclear as to its cause. There is also a problem of causality in the Friedman and Schwartz argument. See Temin, Did Monetary Forces…, for a discussion of this point
    • Friedman and Schwartz, A Monetary History, mention the large decline in velocity in 1930, but are unclear as to its cause. There is also a problem of causality in the Friedman and Schwartz argument. See Temin, Did Monetary Forces…, for a discussion of this point.
    • Friedman1    Schwartz2
  • 37
    • 84974333021 scopus 로고
    • What Caused the Great Depression?
    • See, Feb., 204, 206, and 209-11
    • See Gilbert Burck and Charles Silberman, “What Caused the Great Depression?” Fortune, 51 (Feb. 1955), 94-99, 204, 206, and 209-11.
    • (1955) Fortune , vol.51 , pp. 94-99
    • Burck, G.1    Silberman, C.2
  • 38
    • 0009238227 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • pursues an econometric analysis of the Depression that attributes the decline in aggregate demand to the stock market crash, yet his explanation for the stock market impact is essentially that discussed above
    • Kirkwood, “The Great Depression…,” pursues an econometric analysis of the Depression that attributes the decline in aggregate demand to the stock market crash, yet his explanation for the stock market impact is essentially that discussed above.
    • “The Great Depression…,”
    • Kirkwood1
  • 40
    • 0004320711 scopus 로고
    • London, is one exception. For a typical reaction of economists to the stock market view of the Depression, see Green, “The Economic Impact…,” and the comments on his article. The discussion so far also has ignored the view that economic events outside the United States were important in causing the Depression. See Kindleberger, The World in Depression, for example. Although it is entirely possible and probable that the collapse of the European economies increased the severity of the downturn in the United States, causality seemed to flow from the U.S. economic collapse to Europe and not the other way around
    • J. K. Galbraith, The Great Crash, 1929 (London, 1955) is one exception. For a typical reaction of economists to the stock market view of the Depression, see Green, “The Economic Impact…,” and the comments on his article. The discussion so far also has ignored the view that economic events outside the United States were important in causing the Depression. See Kindleberger, The World in Depression, for example. Although it is entirely possible and probable that the collapse of the European economies increased the severity of the downturn in the United States, causality seemed to flow from the U.S. economic collapse to Europe and not the other way around.
    • (1955) The Great Crash, 1929
    • Galbraith, J.K.1
  • 43
    • 0039867027 scopus 로고
    • Longer Waves in Financial Relations: Financial Factors in the More Severe Depressions
    • May
    • H. P. Minsky, “Longer Waves in Financial Relations: Financial Factors in the More Severe Depressions,” American Economic Review, 54 (May 1964), 324-35.
    • (1964) American Economic Review , vol.54 , pp. 324-335
    • Minsky, H.P.1
  • 44
    • 84875730943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Many economists, for example) object to an important stock market role in business cycle fluctuations during the Great Depression because stock market assets were highly concentrated in the hands of a small segment of the U.S. population. The highly skewed distribution of stock market assets does not invalidate the argument contained here which cites the importance of stock market effects. The calculations of balance-sheet effects found in Table 4 use coefficient estimates that already reflect the skewed distribution of stock market wealth. In addition, some recent cross-section work by
    • Many economists (Green, “The Economic Impact…,” for example) object to an important stock market role in business cycle fluctuations during the Great Depression because stock market assets were highly concentrated in the hands of a small segment of the U.S. population. The highly skewed distribution of stock market assets does not invalidate the argument contained here which cites the importance of stock market effects. The calculations of balance-sheet effects found in Table 4 use coefficient estimates that already reflect the skewed distribution of stock market wealth. In addition, some recent cross-section work by
    • “The Economic Impact…,”
    • Green1
  • 45
    • 0005447401 scopus 로고
    • Short-Run Asset Effects on Household Saving and Consumption: The CrossSection Evidence
    • September, indicates that the skewed distribution of stock market holdings would not greatly diminish the aggregate stock market impact, as has often been thought to be the case. The analysis of the stock market role in the Great Depression presented here is quite different from the expectations view of stock market effects. The liquidity and life-cycle hypotheses imply that even if the consumer's mood did not change as a result of the stock market crash, he still would have cut back on his expenditures because of the deterioration of his balance sheet. Certainly, to the extent that pessimism was bred by the stock market decline, the economy was affected. The approach here also differs from other discussions of stock market effects on the economy, such as
    • Irwin Friend and Charles Lieberman, “Short-Run Asset Effects on Household Saving and Consumption: The CrossSection Evidence,” American Economic Review, 65 (September 1975) 624-33, indicates that the skewed distribution of stock market holdings would not greatly diminish the aggregate stock market impact, as has often been thought to be the case. The analysis of the stock market role in the Great Depression presented here is quite different from the expectations view of stock market effects. The liquidity and life-cycle hypotheses imply that even if the consumer's mood did not change as a result of the stock market crash, he still would have cut back on his expenditures because of the deterioration of his balance sheet. Certainly, to the extent that pessimism was bred by the stock market decline, the economy was affected. The approach here also differs from other discussions of stock market effects on the economy, such as
    • (1975) American Economic Review , vol.65 , pp. 624-633
    • Friend, I.1    Lieberman, C.2
  • 46
    • 77954262322 scopus 로고
    • Monetary Policy in 1974 and Beyond
    • in that it focuses on the consumer rather than on the firm
    • James Tobin, “Monetary Policy in 1974 and Beyond,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1974:1, 219-32, in that it focuses on the consumer rather than on the firm.
    • (1974) Brookings Papers on Economic Activity , vol.1 , pp. 219-232
    • Tobin, J.1
  • 47
    • 0002661755 scopus 로고
    • A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory
    • See, Feb.
    • See: James Tobin, “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 1 (Feb. 1969), 15-29;
    • (1969) Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , vol.1 , pp. 15-29
    • Tobin, J.1
  • 50
    • 84896415105 scopus 로고
    • Efficient Capital Markets and the Quantity Theory of Money
    • June
    • Richard V. L. Cooper, “Efficient Capital Markets and the Quantity Theory of Money” Journal of Finance, 29 (June 1974), 887-908.
    • (1974) Journal of Finance , vol.29 , pp. 887-908
    • Cooper, R.V.L.1
  • 53
    • 0001251352 scopus 로고
    • Best Linear Unbiased Interpolation, Distribution, and Extrapolation of Time Series by Related Series
    • Nov.
    • Gregory Chow and A. Lin, “Best Linear Unbiased Interpolation, Distribution, and Extrapolation of Time Series by Related Series,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 4 (Nov. 1971), 372-75.
    • (1971) Review of Economics and Statistics , vol.4 , pp. 372-375
    • Chow, G.1    Lin, A.2


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.