메뉴 건너뛰기




Volumn 49, Issue 3, 1997, Pages 371-400

Game theory and the spiral model

(1)  Kydd, Andrew a  

a NONE

Author keywords

[No Author keywords available]

Indexed keywords


EID: 0000457224     PISSN: 00438871     EISSN: None     Source Type: Journal    
DOI: 10.1353/wp.1997.0012     Document Type: Article
Times cited : (124)

References (39)
  • 3
    • 84959610525 scopus 로고
    • Political Consequences of Military Strategy: Expanding and Refining the Spiral and Deterrence Models
    • July
    • Glaser, "Political Consequences of Military Strategy: Expanding and Refining the Spiral and Deterrence Models," World Politics 44 (July 1992).
    • (1992) World Politics , vol.44
    • Glaser1
  • 4
    • 85033305795 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Jervis (fn. 2), 71
    • Jervis (fn. 2), 71.
  • 5
    • 85033284261 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Ibid., chap. 4
    • Ibid., chap. 4.
  • 6
    • 84974201319 scopus 로고
    • Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies
    • October
    • 6 Oye, "Explaining Cooperation under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies," World Politics 38 (October 1985).
    • (1985) World Politics , vol.38
    • Oye1
  • 7
    • 5844421841 scopus 로고
    • New York W. W. Norton
    • Many historians note the aggressive motivations of the continental states before 1914, for instance. In the case of Germany, see Fritz Fischer, Germany's Aims in the First World War (New York W. W. Norton, 1967), esp. 11-20.
    • (1967) Germany's Aims in the First World War , pp. 11-20
    • Fischer, F.1
  • 8
    • 85033312216 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • The information structure thus contains two levels of uncertainty. There is uncertainty over the utility of the other side, as well as uncertainty over their beliefs about your own utility. This somewhat complex information structure is necessitated by the logic of the spiral model, as will become clear below. The types in this model are comparable to those in Glaser (fn. 3).
  • 9
    • 85033317943 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I assume without loss of generality that 1-e>e. If 1-e were less than e, the signal would simply imply the opposite of its value, so that g would indicate a security seeker and s a greedy type. It is further assumed that the draws that produce these messages, as well as those that produce the player's greed, are uncorrelated. The interpretation of the messages as private intelligence gathering is in accord with a lack of correlation. As for the first draws over greed, it is difficult to see why greedy and security-seeking states should rationally infer different probabilities that an opponent is greedy from the same public information, although this kind of divergence may occur for psychological reasons. A final point to emphasize is that these messages are not sent by the other player in any conscious way but simply represent information that the receiving state gathers on its own and that influences its beliefs about the other side's type. Thus they are not "signals" in the sense of consciously manipulated signs. Rather, states signal with their armament choices, as described below.
  • 10
    • 85033321103 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, these beliefs may arise in other ways as well. The intelligence-gathering story is offered as one intuitively plausible way in which such divergent beliefs could arise.
  • 11
    • 85033315877 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • I will sometimes refer to beliefs after Nature's move but before the first round of play as "priors" because they precede any move by the players, but it should be remembered that they are posterior to Nature's move.
  • 12
    • 85033315173 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note that the subscript on the p's is the opposite of that on the γ's. I subscript the p's to reflect the player holding the belief, whereas the γ's are subscripted to reflect the object of the prior probability.
  • 13
    • 85033320828 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This may seem like redundant notation, but it will become convenient later on when these beliefs about the other side's fear are updated and the formulas become much less simple.
  • 14
    • 84936824515 scopus 로고
    • New York: Basic Books
    • Further rounds of play would complicate the model without adding greatly to its capacity to address spiral arguments. Note in particular that unlike many models of international relations, such as the repeated Prisoner's Dilemma and related models of arms races, cooperation here is not a function of the shadow of the future; hence the restriction to a finite number of rounds does not fundamentally change the nature of the game, as it does in the repeated PD. See Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); and George W. Downs and David M. Rocke, Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Control (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990).
    • (1984) The Evolution of Cooperation
    • Axelrod, R.1
  • 15
    • 0003938439 scopus 로고
    • Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press
    • Further rounds of play would complicate the model without adding greatly to its capacity to address spiral arguments. Note in particular that unlike many models of international relations, such as the repeated Prisoner's Dilemma and related models of arms races, cooperation here is not a function of the shadow of the future; hence the restriction to a finite number of rounds does not fundamentally change the nature of the game, as it does in the repeated PD. See Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984); and George W. Downs and David M. Rocke, Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Control (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990).
    • (1990) Tacit Bargaining, Arms Races, and Arms Control
    • Downs, G.W.1    Rocke, D.M.2
  • 16
    • 85033312229 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 15 No building choice is included in the second round because building is only worthwhile if there is a subsequent war, but in this final round of the game there are no subsequent possibilities for attack. Hence no player would build, regardless of type; including the choice would therefore complicate the description of the game to no purpose.
  • 17
    • 85033297110 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 16 Discounting would not affect the results in any significant way and would further complicate an already complex model.
  • 18
    • 85033298214 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • 17 A first-strike advantage is necessary for there to be a danger of war between security seekers, a key subject of concern in the spiral model.
  • 20
    • 85033310835 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Differences between family members are primarily off the equilibrium path and in the second round, after learning has taken place. A more complete description of the equilibria in the model is available from the author upon request.
  • 21
    • 85033281904 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Thus, within this upward spiral equilibrium, a downward spiral is also possible, because the ST type signals its type by not building. The next equilibrium will focus on when the SF type can also refrain from building.
  • 22
    • 85033302208 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Note again, the subscript refers to the holder of the belief, not the object of the belief, so a GF type's level of fear is pif and its belief that the other side is fearful is qig.
  • 23
    • 85033306271 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • This dependence of spiraling on the distinction between trusting and fearful states is what necessitates the incorporation of the second level of uncertainty in the model (fn. 8).
  • 24
    • 85033319273 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Glaser (fn. 3)
    • Glaser (fn. 3).
  • 25
    • 5844349056 scopus 로고
    • Woodward (fn. 1), 11; Miami, Fla.: University of Miami Press
    • 24 Woodward (fn. 1), 11; Gerhard Ritter, The Sword and the Scepter: The Problem of Militarism in Germany (Miami, Fla.: University of Miami Press, 1970), 145; Paul Kennedy, Strategy and Diplomacy, 1870-1945 (London: Fontanna Press, 1983), chap. 5; Fritz Fischer, War of Illusions (New York: W. W. Norton, 1975), chap. 7.
    • (1970) The Sword and the Scepter: The Problem of Militarism in Germany , pp. 145
    • Ritter, G.1
  • 26
    • 0003486048 scopus 로고
    • London: Fontanna Press, chap. 5
    • 24 Woodward (fn. 1), 11; Gerhard Ritter, The Sword and the Scepter: The Problem of Militarism in Germany (Miami, Fla.: University of Miami Press, 1970), 145; Paul Kennedy, Strategy and Diplomacy, 1870-1945 (London: Fontanna Press, 1983), chap. 5; Fritz Fischer, War of Illusions (New York: W. W. Norton, 1975), chap. 7.
    • (1983) Strategy and Diplomacy, 1870-1945
    • Kennedy, P.1
  • 27
    • 0004723467 scopus 로고
    • New York: W. W. Norton, chap. 7
    • 24 Woodward (fn. 1), 11; Gerhard Ritter, The Sword and the Scepter: The Problem of Militarism in Germany (Miami, Fla.: University of Miami Press, 1970), 145; Paul Kennedy, Strategy and Diplomacy, 1870-1945 (London: Fontanna Press, 1983), chap. 5; Fritz Fischer, War of Illusions (New York: W. W. Norton, 1975), chap. 7.
    • (1975) War of Illusions
    • Fischer, F.1
  • 28
    • 5844321141 scopus 로고
    • London: Hart-Davis
    • In 1907 the kaiser granted an interview with a reporter from the Daily Telegraph, in which he claimed to have given the British the winning strategy in the Boer War and also that the German navy was being built against the Japanese. These preposterous claims only worsened Anglo-German relations and led to a serious political crisis in Germany. See Peter Padfield, The Great Naval Race (London: Hart-Davis, 1974), 223-24; and Robert K. Massie, Dreadnought: Britain, Germany and the Coming of the Great War (New York Random House, 1991), chap. 37.
    • (1974) The Great Naval Race , pp. 223-224
    • Padfield, P.1
  • 29
    • 0004164505 scopus 로고
    • New York Random House, chap. 37
    • In 1907 the kaiser granted an interview with a reporter from the Daily Telegraph, in which he claimed to have given the British the winning strategy in the Boer War and also that the German navy was being built against the Japanese. These preposterous claims only worsened Anglo-German relations and led to a serious political crisis in Germany. See Peter Padfield, The Great Naval Race (London: Hart-Davis, 1974), 223-24; and Robert K. Massie, Dreadnought: Britain, Germany and the Coming of the Great War (New York Random House, 1991), chap. 37.
    • (1991) Dreadnought: Britain, Germany and the Coming of the Great War
    • Massie, R.K.1
  • 31
    • 85033304906 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Fischer (fn. 24), 114
    • Fischer (fn. 24), 114.
  • 32
    • 0003832830 scopus 로고
    • London: Ashfield Press
    • Paul Kennedy, The Rise of the Anglo-German Antagonism, 1860-1914 (London: Ashfield Press, 1980), 443-44. For the showdown within the Liberal Party over naval expenditures during the naval scare of 1909, see also Massie (fn. 25), chap. 33.
    • (1980) The Rise of the Anglo-German Antagonism, 1860-1914 , pp. 443-444
    • Kennedy, P.1
  • 33
    • 85033315461 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • In a variant of the spiral equilibrium in which GF types attack in the first round, the ratio between the posteriors is not preserved. However, this equilibrium does still witness the polarization of beliefs identified below.
  • 34
    • 84959813489 scopus 로고
    • The Emerging Post-Revisionist Synthesis on the Origins of the Cold War
    • Summer
    • For a summary of the debate, see John Lewis Gaddis, "The Emerging Post-Revisionist Synthesis on the Origins of the Cold War," Diplomatic History 7 (Summer 1983).
    • (1983) Diplomatic History , vol.7
    • Gaddis, J.L.1
  • 35
    • 0003537146 scopus 로고
    • Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press
    • See the chapters in George W. Breslauer and Philip E. Tetlock, Learning in U.S. and Soviet Foreign Policy (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1991), for arguments along these lines, especially Philip E. Tetlock, "Learning in U.S. and Soviet Foreign Policy: In Search of an Elusive Concept," and Ernst B. Haas, "Collective Learning: Some Theoretical Speculations."
    • (1991) Learning in U.S. and Soviet Foreign Policy
    • Breslauer, G.W.1    Tetlock, P.E.2
  • 36
    • 85033298191 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • note
    • Of course, the less military importance the concession has, the greater the danger that the aggressive state may try to mimic it, depriving it of its signaling value. If the concession had no military value, then it would simply be cheap talk and the aggressive state would not hesitate to make it too. Thus the signal has to have some middling value of risk in order to be persuasive but not too costly.
  • 37
    • 0003661871 scopus 로고
    • Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley
    • For a discussion of costly signals in deterrence theory, see James Fearon, "Threats to Use Force: Costly Signals and Bargaining in International Crises" (Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1993), chap. 3. For a discussion of the role of signals in building trust, see Charles Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self Help," International Security 19, no. 3 (1995); Andrew Kydd, "Signaling and Structural Realism" (Manuscript, University of California, Riverside, 1996), and Deborah Larson, "Distrust, Missed Opportunities and Unilateral Initiative in Foreign Policy" (Manuscript, University of California, Los Angles, 1996). Note that these three authors discuss costly signals in a reassurance context but do not formally demonstrate their possibility, as is done here.
    • (1993) Threats to Use Force: Costly Signals and Bargaining in International Crises
    • Fearon, J.1
  • 38
    • 80052780189 scopus 로고
    • Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self Help
    • For a discussion of costly signals in deterrence theory, see James Fearon, "Threats to Use Force: Costly Signals and Bargaining in International Crises" (Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1993), chap. 3. For a discussion of the role of signals in building trust, see Charles Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self Help," International Security 19, no. 3 (1995); Andrew Kydd, "Signaling and Structural Realism" (Manuscript, University of California, Riverside, 1996), and Deborah Larson, "Distrust, Missed Opportunities and Unilateral Initiative in Foreign Policy" (Manuscript, University of California, Los Angles, 1996). Note that these three authors discuss costly signals in a reassurance context but do not formally demonstrate their possibility, as is done here.
    • (1995) International Security , vol.19 , Issue.3
    • Glaser, C.1
  • 39
    • 85033297734 scopus 로고    scopus 로고
    • Manuscript, University of California, Los Angles
    • For a discussion of costly signals in deterrence theory, see James Fearon, "Threats to Use Force: Costly Signals and Bargaining in International Crises" (Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley, 1993), chap. 3. For a discussion of the role of signals in building trust, see Charles Glaser, "Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self Help," International Security 19, no. 3 (1995); Andrew Kydd, "Signaling and Structural Realism" (Manuscript, University of California, Riverside, 1996), and Deborah Larson, "Distrust, Missed Opportunities and Unilateral Initiative in Foreign Policy" (Manuscript, University of California, Los Angles, 1996). Note that these three authors discuss costly signals in a reassurance context but do not formally demonstrate their possibility, as is done here.
    • (1996) Signaling and Structural Realism" (Manuscript, University of California, Riverside, 1996), and Deborah Larson, "Distrust, Missed Opportunities and Unilateral Initiative in Foreign Policy
    • Kydd, A.1


* 이 정보는 Elsevier사의 SCOPUS DB에서 KISTI가 분석하여 추출한 것입니다.